5 0 Billion Euros: Europe's Child Labour Footprint in 2019

Page 57

57

2. How could unconditional trade bans and sanctions lower child welfare? The above section has demonstrated that the impact of trade on child labour is multifaceted and may be positive or negative depending on the rules of trade, the time frame considered, the industry, the wealth of the country, and other factors. Many activists, however, implicitly assume that trade with countries, industries, or more certainly firms that use child labour must increase demand for, and therefore use of, child labour. The obvious assumption is that by refusing to purchase the products made with child labour, the use of child labour will also decrease. There are several problems with this line of thought. The weaker argument is the problem of fungibility. Most individual buyers and even most countries are too small to have a noticeable impact on global demand. Someone else will buy these goods, goes the argument, and therefore the sanctioned party is made worse off for no material gain. In the context of the European Union, however, it is much more likely that trade bans and sanctions will, in fact, have a noticeable effect on demand for these goods. Lower demand for these goods will likely lower global prices and profits for those who use child labour, ultimately decreasing demand for child labour. This is where a second, stronger argument comes into play. Consider again the above Figure 19 depicting the downward sloping child labour supply curve. If trade sanctions successfully decrease demand for child labour, this will tend to lower the wages of child workers, increasing the quantity supplied. This perverse effect lowers child welfare, first by making those children who are already working worse off as their families have lower incomes to purchase necessities, and second by inducing more children to spend additional time in labour rather than education. A third concern is that even if bans are successful in reducing child labour, that does not immediately imply that these children are then better off. Because of the indigent circumstances of the families sending children to work, the loss of the child’s income likely means employment in a different, worse job rather than increased opportunities for education and success in life. A fourth concern worth brief mention is that most developing countries are suspicious of bans based on child labour, suspecting that they actually constitute protectionism disguised as charity, making them less likely to cooperate. Moving from the theoretical to the empirical, in 1992 Senator Harkin of the United States proposed the Child Labor Deterrence Act (aka Harkin Bill), “with the laudable aim of prohibiting the import of products made by children under 15” (UNICEF, 1997, p. 23). This legislative initiative came on the heels of a 1991 ILO prognosis that “half of the 50,000 children working as bonded labor in Pakistan's carpet-weaving industry would never reach the age of twelve – victims of disease and malnutrition” (Kelleher, 1994, p. 161). With the prospect of a bill, needless to say, Senator Harkin had the attention of the Bangladesh export garment industry, “and whose products – some $900 million in value – were exported to the US in 1994” (UNICEF, 1997, p. 23). A Memorandum of Understanding was signed in 1995 wherein the garment industry agreed to phase out all child labourers


Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook

Articles inside

Annex III – Examples of TSD Chapters

4min
pages 150-152

Bibliography

38min
pages 153-181

XI. About Development International e.V

1min
page 143

X. About the Authors

1min
page 142

3. Child Labour Monitoring Systems

1min
page 110

2. IPEC

3min
pages 108-109

6. Suggested carrots and sticks

14min
pages 127-132

2. Switzerland

2min
page 119

2. The Netherlands

8min
pages 114-116

C. EU Investment Protection Agreements

2min
page 121

B. Mandatory corporate due diligence legislation

7min
pages 133-135

5. Use of other measures to justify exceptions

2min
page 126

D. U.S. support for trade partners

2min
page 104

Instrument

7min
pages 101-103

3. List of Goods, coordination of enforcement

10min
pages 89-92

4. U.S. Trade Policy

5min
pages 93-95

2. Support through dialogue and cooperation platforms

6min
pages 98-100

1. DHS mechanism

18min
pages 80-86

2. EO mechanisms

5min
pages 87-88

B. U.S. trade policy enforcement vis-à-vis child labour

2min
page 79

6. EU trade sanction instruments

3min
page 78

5. EU “essential elements” human rights clause

2min
page 77

4. EU-UK Free Trade Agreement

2min
page 76

1. Morbidity and mortality of hazardous labour

2min
page 59

2. Stringency of child labour provisions

5min
pages 73-74

Dimension 2: Quality of the education system

5min
pages 63-65

3. Local impact dimension of TSD chapters

2min
page 75

Dimension 3: Government capacity

5min
pages 66-67

2. How could unconditional trade bans and sanctions lower child welfare?

2min
page 57

G. Laissez-faire vs. intervention

2min
page 58

4. Forced/indentured child labour findings

5min
pages 45-50

E. Factors of child labour

8min
pages 51-53

3. Child labour footprint findings

9min
pages 36-44

2. USDOL’s “List of Products Produced by Forced or Indentured Child Labor”

2min
page 27

C. Sectors and geographies with child labour practices

2min
pages 28-29

I. Introduction

5min
pages 20-22

2. Example child labour commodities

6min
pages 33-35

Executive Summary

17min
pages 4-13

Acronyms

3min
pages 14-16

II. Research Objectives

4min
pages 23-24

Foreword by Saskia Bricmont

6min
pages 17-19
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.
5 0 Billion Euros: Europe's Child Labour Footprint in 2019 by SaskiaBricmont - Issuu