The Role of Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers in Improving Education Outcomes

Page 311

China Case Study | 275

BOX 10.1

How did China achieve the goal of spending 4 percent of GDP on education? In 1993, the central government set a target of raising government expenditure on education from 2.4 percent to 4 percent of gross domestic product (GDP)—the world average at that time—by 2000. However, by 2000, government educational expenditure was only 2.6 percent of GDP. In 2001, the central government recommitted to reaching the target by 2005 but failed again, reaching only 2.8 percent by 2005. The failure was related to the highly decentralized nature of the education system; grassroots governments did not have much room in their budgets for more educational investment; the central government ’s emphasis on increasing educational i nvestment was hindered by its failure to ­ provide financial support to local governments. In 2006, the central government proposed the 4 percent target again and reemphasized the requirement of three increases in local government education budgets: appropriations for education should increase at a faster rate than revenues; average expenditure per student should increase steadily; and teacher salaries and the average administrative expenditure per student should both increase steadily. The central government also emphasized the need for increases in two ratios: government educational expenditure as a share of GDP; and government educational expenditure as a share of total government expenditure. Government educational expenditure as a share of GDP increased steadily to 3.5 percent in 2009. In 2010, the central government set a deadline of two years to meet the 4 percent target and exploited

several new instruments. First, the central government encouraged local governments to expand their revenue for education by expanding the tax base for the educational surcharge; collecting a local educational surcharge; and using 10 percent of local net revenue from land sales. Second, the central government gave local governments an incentive to hit the target: basing the evaluation of local government performance and promotion of local government officials on a weighted average of four indexes: (1) the growth in government educational expenditure (30 percent); (2) the increase in government educational expenditure as a share of total government expenditure (50 percent); (3) the educational surcharge rate (10 percent); and (4) the completion rate of extracting 10 percent of revenue from land sales (10 percent). Third, the central government established an administration office focusing on achieving the 4 percent goal, which coordinated different departments and supervised and monitored local governments to reach the 4 percent target. These instruments were very effective, and China finally achieved the goal in 2012, when ­g overnment expenditure on education reached 4.3 percent of GDP. At the end of 2013, the central government decided to remove pegged links between public expenditure on education and fiscal revenue or GDP. Nevertheless, government educational expenditure as a share of GDP has remained over 4 percent since 2012.

sources of funding, and institutions. The statements also made stipulations regarding the use of funds, school building, and management. The shift away from the decentralization of compulsory education was followed by a considerable increase in government education spending and noticeable improvements in education outcomes in poor regions. The ratio of government expenditure per student between the highest and the lowest provinces dropped from a peak of 10.6 in 2005 to 5.3 in 2016 in primary education and from 9.6 in 2005 to 5.7 in 2015 in junior high education. Meanwhile, the gross enrollment rate rose from 95 percent in 2005 to 104 percent in 2016 for junior high schools and from 53 percent in 2005 to 88 percent in 2016 for senior high schools.


Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook

Articles inside

Notes

2min
page 333

References

9min
pages 334-339

Key policy directions

2min
page 332

Fiscal transfer mechanisms

2min
page 312

education?

2min
page 311

10.2 Education expenditure in Shandong, 2018

7min
pages 307-309

9.1 Evolution of the allocation mechanism in school finance

2min
page 288

9.2 Improving education outcomes in Ceará, Brazil

5min
pages 296-297

Key policy directions to strengthen decentralized education financing

5min
pages 294-295

Introduction

2min
page 301

9.4 Pillars for central government education transfers to municipalities

4min
pages 284-285

governments

7min
pages 274-276

Conclusion

2min
page 265

References

3min
pages 268-270

Notes

7min
pages 266-267

8.2 Change in IDEB scores, 2005–17

1min
page 263

Impact of Brazil’s decentralized financing system on subnational spending and education outcomes

2min
page 258

in Ceará

4min
pages 253-254

8.10 Federal contributions to FUNDEB, 2007–17

2min
page 252

8.7 Brazil’s results on PISA, 2000–18

1min
page 245

8.1 Learning poverty in Brazilian municipalities, 2017

1min
page 244

8.1 Preuniversity education responsibilities of governments in Brazil

4min
pages 240-241

Introduction

4min
pages 237-238

References

1min
pages 235-236

7.9 Impact of total local expenditure on reading

2min
page 230

7.1 Distribution of education transfers as a zero-sum game

5min
pages 217-218

7.9 Subnational education spending by financing source, 2018

4min
pages 211-212

How is the system financed? Effects of decentralized financing system on subnational spending

2min
page 207

and 2018

2min
page 201

6.13 Transfers and education spending

1min
page 191

Context

1min
page 199

7.12 Allocation of education transfers, 2005–19

2min
page 215

6.15 Predicted education outcomes and district spending

1min
page 194

6.14 District spending and education outcomes

4min
pages 192-193

Introduction

1min
page 173

Fiscal transfer mechanisms

2min
page 183

References

12min
pages 168-172

Notes

9min
pages 165-167

Key policy directions to strengthen the decentralized education finance system

5min
pages 163-164

5.24 GERs in government primary schools, by LG, 2019/20

1min
page 155

and high primary GER and falling secondary GER, 1996/97–2019/20

1min
page 152

Effects of the decentralized finance system on subnational spending and education outcomes

4min
pages 150-151

Introduction

4min
pages 121-122

5.2 Government responsibilities under the Education Act

12min
pages 127-132

4.18 Fund flows in education

1min
page 109

for education

5min
pages 103-104

governments

2min
page 93

4.1 Population pyramid of Sudan, 2000–30

1min
page 90

4.9 Gender parity index, by state

2min
page 98

Notes

2min
page 82

Introduction

1min
page 89

References

10min
pages 83-88

Political economy constraints

2min
page 81

transfers for education

13min
pages 75-80

Education (FUNDEB

2min
page 66

Intergovernmental transfers

2min
page 48

3.3 Marginal effects of fiscal transfers on subnational education spending

5min
pages 61-62

3.3 The No Child Left Behind Act in the United States

5min
pages 72-73

outcomes?

5min
pages 70-71

Tax assignment

2min
page 47

Impact of fiscal transfers in education: A literature review

7min
pages 51-53
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.