Efficiencies in merger control - Presentation by John Kwoka

Page 1


Efficiencies in Merger Control

Northeastern University, Boston

OECD Roundtable

Paris 17 June 2025

Delegation Notes indicate broad agreement on some issues

• There is broad agreement on these propositions:

(1) Efficiencies play a role in mergers and in principle should be considered in merger evaluation

(2) Efficiencies consist of more than conventional cost savings. They also include

Improvements in quality and variety of products

Innovation efforts and methods ( R&D, exploiting complementarities)

Cost savings in production, distribution, transactions, finance, etc

(3) There are criteria for assessing efficiencies

Efficiencies must be inherent in (specific to) the merger

Must be verifiable by competition agency

Benefits must be at least in part passed on to consumers

Also, timely, likely, and sufficient in magnitude

Principles vs. practice: The paradox

• Despite this conviction that efficiencies are important, delegations commonly indicate that their agencies scarcely ever—perhaps never—find that efficiencies matter in actual merger analysis

• Or at least do not matter enough to reverse an agency determination of competitive problems with a specific merger

• Many examples are cited where claims of efficiencies are not accepted

• Most frequent reasons are verifiability and merger specificity

• This is the apparent paradox: Efficiencies are acknowledged as important in principle, even though they are not often found significant in practice

• Two explanations for this apparent paradox

• Theory is not as simple as often portrayed

• Empirical evidence cautions about actual effects

Theoretical explanation

• Original theory due to Williamson implied the importance of efficiencies

• Merger both created market power but lowered cost

• Trade off between costs (red) and benefits (blue)

• Williamson concluded: “A merger which yields non-trivial real economics must…result in relatively large price increases for the net effects to be negative.”

• But Williamson called this particular demonstration a “naïve” model since it did not acknowledge “a variety of essential qualifications”

• He listed the following qualifications

• “Inference and enforcement expense

• Timing

• Incipiency

• Weighting

• Technological progress

• And the effects of monopoly power on managerial discretion”

• Williamson understood the abstract nature of his demonstration

• Explicitly stated that any of these can modify—possibly substantially--his “naïve” conclusion

• So theory does not so clearly favor efficiencies

Empirical explanation

• Empirical studies generally find little evidence of systematic efficiencies

• Rose and Sallett (2020) surveyed economic literature on efficiencies and concluded that:

• “a substantial body of work casts doubt on their presumptive existence and magnitude”

• Went on to observe that current policy has had an “overly-optimistic view of the existence of cognizable efficiencies” leading to acceptance of anticompetitive mergers

• My own meta-analysis (2015) of merger retrospectives focusing on cost savings concluded much the same

• Average cost efficiency netted out to zero

• So evidence, too, suggests little systematic efficiency benefit from merger

• Why, then, all the attention to efficiencies?

• Reason is variation—not the average--in outcomes

• On average, efficiencies do not result from mergers, so most claims should not be accepted

• But the significant variation in outcomes implies that there are some cases of substantial efficiencies, which policy seeks to identify

• Challenge for agencies is to identify unusually large and important efficiencies…

• BUT to avoid crediting others with efficiencies they will not achieve

• AND avoid having to evaluate many or most claims in order to identify very small fraction of meritorious cases

• To illustrate difficulties, early U.S. Merger Guidelines (1982) stated that guideline thresholds were written so as to allow for small routine efficiencies in most mergers

• Agencies said they would examine specific claims only in “extraordinary” cases

• But the “extraordinary” became routine as most merging parties claimed some efficiencies and agencies had to evaluate claims in most cases

• Later guidelines continued to seek—largely unsuccessfully-- methods to focus on cases with plausible efficiency claims

The Enforcement Challenge: Looking ahead

• Delegations are in broad agreement on need to identify and accept valid and important efficiency claims, while avoiding expending resources on others

• One delegation note urges consideration of several procedural reforms

Standardization of types of efficiencies to be considered

Indicate types of evidence for each

Conduct reviews of past experience in order to make improvements

• Elsewhere, I have proposed 2-stage process

First stage would screen out claims of small routine efficiencies

• Admissable claims would only be large since others already allowed

• Must be based on ordinary course documents or earlier studies

• No weight given to studies commissioned within preceding year

• Sliding scale based on level of concentration in affected market

Only those passing first screen would get full agency review

• These reforms might begin to bring actual practice closer to intended policy

Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.