From Jobs to Careers

Page 53

Why Jobs versus Careers?

l

13

A LABOR DEMAND-SIDE MODEL Consider a two-sector model in which both sectors use a combination of women and men to produce final output. If men and women are imperfect substitutes in production (for whatever reason) and the two sectors use different ratios of men and women, we can describe one as “female intensive” and the other as “male intensive.” Many trade ­models—including recent models with heterogeneous firms (for example, Melitz 2003) with two sectors that differ in factor intensity—conclude that exports of one sector (holding the other constant) will increase demand for the workers intensively employed in that sector. Bernard, Redding, and Schott (2007) demonstrate this for skilled and less-skilled workers. Traded goods have significant overlap with manufacturing industries. Within manufacturing, apparel is usually considered female intensive and other industries (as a group) as male intensive. Among export-oriented industries, the apparel industry employs a high number of females (labor intensive) and is the most female-intensive manufacturing industry. This is supported by our analysis and country studies (Klasen 2019; Kucera and Tejani 2014). As such, the apparel industry is not only the logical choice to explore in more depth but also has historically been among the only options for employing large numbers of female workers. Given that we can describe traded industries as female intensive in apparel and male intensive in other manufacturing, consider figure 1.3. It follows directly from FIGURE 1.3 M odel of FLFP Variation in Relation to Female and Male Contributions to Higher Family Income

Rising male wages

Rising female wages

FLFP

Rising female wages

Family income Source: World Bank elaboration. Note: In this model, as demand for women’s labor for apparel exports rises relative to men’s (left section), women’s wages rise, and women are more likely to enter the labor force and work more hours. But as men transition to industrial jobs with even higher wages (center section), those rising incomes are associated with less formal sector work by women in the same household. A country’s transition to a more services-led economy (right section) again increases both demand and wages for women, increasing the female labor supply. FLFP = female labor force participation.


Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook

Articles inside

A.6 Average Monthly Wages for Females and Both Genders, Manufacturing and All Industries, by Case Country

1min
page 175

A.9 Details of Education Level Data Used for Standardized Analysis, by Case Country

2min
pages 177-178

A.4 Average Monthly Wages in Local Currency, by Industry, in Case Countries

1min
page 173

Education Analysis Issues and Methodology

2min
page 170

A.5 Average Monthly Wages in the Apparel Industry, by Gender, and the Gender Wage Gap in Case Countries

1min
page 174

5.2 North Carolina and Bangladesh: Programs That Spotlight Apparel Careers

2min
page 159

Seven Middle-Income Countries, 2020

6min
pages 161-163

Break Glass Ceilings

2min
page 160

Conclusion

2min
page 164

Increase Access to Education to Promote Female Participation in Careers

4min
pages 157-158

Introduction

4min
pages 150-151

Increase Participation of Female Production Workers in Export-Oriented Apparel Manufacturing and Related Industries

3min
pages 153-154

Key Messages

1min
page 149

Increase the Number of Female Supervisors and Upgrade Apparel Jobs to Manufacturing-Related Services

4min
pages 155-156

Economies, 1995–2015

1min
page 139

Conclusion

1min
page 145

Bangladesh, Cambodia, and Vietnam, 2013

1min
pages 140-141

Can Apparel Exports Increase Jobs and Female Labor Force Participation?

2min
page 136

The Multifiber Arrangement, Export Dependence, and Women

1min
page 132

Conclusion

2min
page 119

of Peak Apparel Exports

4min
pages 134-135

References

3min
pages 122-124

by Scale of Operation

1min
page 131

Notes

4min
pages 120-121

Key Messages

1min
page 125

Middle-Income Countries and the United States

1min
page 118

The Three Female Employment Groups

2min
page 106

The Three Barriers to Career Progression

2min
page 108

Sample Middle-Income Countries, Mid-2010s

4min
pages 116-117

Key Messages

1min
page 101

Selected Industries, 2017

1min
page 105

Global Patterns of Female Labor Intensity

2min
page 103

Introduction

2min
page 102

Annex 2A: Mincerian Equation Results

2min
page 90

Middle-Income Countries, 2000s–2010s

2min
page 78

Sample Middle-Income Countries, by Earliest and Latest Data Years

2min
page 76

Introduction

1min
page 68

Indicator One: Investment in Human Capital

4min
pages 70-71

Indicator Four: Earnings Gaps between Men and Women

4min
pages 79-80

Key Messages

1min
page 67

References

6min
pages 63-66

1.2 Job Classification by ISCO Code, Skill Level, and Education Level

2min
page 61

B1.3.1 Share of Total Female Employment, by Sector and Selected Industries, in Sample Middle-Income Countries, 2017

1min
page 60

Apparel Jobs to Careers

1min
page 55

Feminization U-Shaped Curve

2min
page 50

National Income, 2017

3min
pages 48-49

1.3 Apparel: The Most Important Manufacturing Industry for Female Jobs

1min
page 59

Contributions to Higher Family Income

4min
pages 53-54

Country Cases and Labor Market Classifications

4min
pages 56-57

Middle-Income Countries

1min
page 58

O.4 Returns to Education for Females in Selected Countries, 2007–15 xxvi O.5 Decomposition of Occupations in Women’s and Total Employment Worldwide, by Broad Category and Country Income Level, 2017 xxvii O.6 Relationships of GVC Activities and Country Roles to Occupational Skill and Country Income Levels xxix 1.1 The Path from Jobs to Careers for US Women in the Twentieth Century

4min
pages 46-47
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.