Ebb and Flow: Volume 1. Water, Migration, and Development

Page 102

Water, Migration, and Development

infrastructure must be in place in the dense settlements that are likely to host low-skilled migrants. Low-skilled migrants are also willing to pay for these basic services. In Brazil, migrant workers earning a minimum wage were found to be willing to pay R$390 per year to have access to better health services, R$84 for better access to sewage services, and R$42 for better access to electricity (Lall, Timmins, and Yu 2009). More broadly, better accounting for the human capital dimension would allow policy makers to harness the power of migration toward the productive reallocation of labor for long-term growth. But caution is also warranted when considering policy responses. It may be tempting to consider, for instance, place-based policies as a promising tool for building national resilience if they provide an outlet for surplus labor during times of low rainfall or drought while keeping urban areas safe from the productivity impacts of low-skilled migration. But the costs and benefits of such policies need to be weighed carefully because investments in lagging regions must be sufficiently targeted to ensure that the expected benefits outweigh the high costs that can often arise from misallocation. Poorly targeted investments may disincentivize the productive migration of highskilled workers into regions where they could make higher contributions to GDP. Thus, accounting for the interplay between migration and human capital is at the heart of the issue of ensuring efficient spatial allocation of labor across sectors in the face of climatic variability and increasing urbanization rates. Perhaps the link between migration, climate adaptation, and human capital provides additional impetus to invest in the expansion of schooling infrastructure. If households are willing to invest in children’s education to diversify their income portfolio in regions with high rainfall variability, it may be prudent to prioritize rural education investment in such areas. Such investments would ensure that if these children migrated as adults, they would carry competitive skills to the cities and regions they move to. Investing in human capital because of its portable nature would allow for higher returns for workers irrespective of whether they choose to stay in or leave their home region and can be a potent tool to accelerate the process of structural transformation (Porzio, Rossi, and Santangelo 2020). Policies aimed at investing in people rather than in places while increasing economic integration and mobility stand the best chance of incentivizing better allocation of human capital resources across regions.

NOTE 1. These estimates are based on returns of 8 percent per year of education, as found by Kraay (2019).

88


Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook

Articles inside

Policy Options at the Destination

11min
pages 144-148

Policy Options at the Origin

8min
pages 136-139

Figure 5.1 Policy Approaches at the Source and Destination Figure 5.2 Share of Regions in North Africa and G5 Sahel Countries That Experienced Different Types of

1min
page 135

The Policy Challenge

2min
page 134

Key Highlights

1min
page 133

Years of Water Deficits, 1992–2013

1min
page 114

Quantifying the Cost of Day Zero–Like Events

4min
pages 112-113

Key Highlights

1min
page 105

The Importance of Water for Growth

2min
page 109

References

3min
pages 103-104

Note

2min
page 102

Implications for Development Policy

2min
page 101

Productivity, Growth, and Welfare

4min
pages 97-98

References

13min
pages 83-88

Map B3.3.1 The Subregions of Brazil, Indonesia, and Mexico Explored Using Census Data Map 4.1 Location of Cities Experiencing Deep Three-Plus

1min
page 96

Key Highlights

1min
page 89

Notes

2min
page 82

Water as a Conduit for Development

4min
pages 80-81

Box 2.4 Water Shocks and Declining Wetlands

2min
page 77

Green Infrastructure

8min
pages 73-76

Box 2.2 Choosing Not to Migrate Box 2.3 Measuring the Buffering Effect of Gray and

2min
page 71

Migration?

1min
page 72

Should I Stay or Should I Go? Estimating the Impacts of Water Shocks on Migration Decisions Does Buffering Rural Income from Rainfall Shocks Influence

2min
page 65

Introduction

2min
page 64

Key Highlights

1min
page 63

Spotlight: Inequality, Social Cohesion, and the COVID-19 Public Health Crisis at the Nexus of Water and Migration

16min
pages 55-62

References

10min
pages 50-54

Box 1.6 Social Cleavages Run Deep

2min
page 49

Box 1.3 COVID-19 (Coronovirus) Fallout

4min
pages 41-42

Box 1.4 Exploring Water Scarcity through Water Shocks

2min
page 43

Climate Change and the Increasing Variability of Rainfall Learning about Water’s Role in Global Migration from

1min
page 40

References

1min
pages 33-34

Going with the Flow: The Policy Challenge

11min
pages 25-32

Box 1.2 Is Water a Locational Fundamental?

2min
page 38

The Cost of Day Zero Events: What Are the Development Implications for Shocks in the City?

3min
pages 23-24

Focus of the Report

6min
pages 16-18

Box 1.1 Water and the Urbanizing Force of Development

1min
page 37

Focus of the Report

1min
page 36

Introduction

1min
page 35
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.