Preferential Trade Agreement Policies for Development: A Handbook Part 2

Page 1

Preferential

Trade Agreement Policies for Development A

HAndbook

Editors Jean-Pierre Chauffour • Jean-Christophe Maur


21 Human Rights Susan Ariel Aaronson

Many of the world’s most important trading economies have introduced human rights language into their preferential trade agreements (PTAs). As a result, more than 70 percent of the world’s governments now participate in PTAs with human rights requirements. The growing number and scope of these trade agreements reflects a new reality: policy makers understand that economic integration will not be successful without a stronger focus on improving governance among trade partners. If human rights provisions are designed carefully, they can work both to improve governance and to empower people to claim their rights. Yet policy makers, scholars, and activists still know very little about the effects of including human rights provisions in trade agreements. As long as men and women have traded, they have wrestled with how to advance human rights while expanding trade. In some instances, policy makers have used the incentive of trade expansion; at other times they have used trade sanctions—the disincentive of lost trade—to punish officials from other countries that have undermined human rights. For example, after the United Kingdom and the United States outlawed the slave trade in 1807, the United Kingdom signed treaties with Denmark, Portugal, and Sweden to reinforce its own ban. After the United States banned goods manufactured by convict labor, Australia, Canada, and the United Kingdom adopted similar measures. These efforts stimulated international cooperation, and in 1919 the signatories of the Treaty of Versailles formed the International Labour Organization (ILO) to establish fair and humane rules regarding the treatment of labor (Bidwell 1939). The United States and the European Union (EU) were the first trade entities to include human rights language in trade agreements. In the 1980s and 1990s, U.S. and EU officials began to include human rights conditionality clauses in their preference programs (Charnovitz 2005, 29, n. 103–05). The 1993 North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA),

signed by Canada, Mexico, and the United States, was the first PTA to include explicit human rights provisions. Trade policy makers agreed to include labor rights in a side agreement. They also included additional chapters and language focused on encouraging transparency (access to information) and public participation. These obligations went beyond the provisions of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and its successor organization, the World Trade Organization (WTO); scholars call this WTO+. Some analysts see these provisions as “legal inflation” and assert that governments are using trade agreements to globalize their social policies or regulatory approaches. They argue that trade agreements are not the right place to address human rights issues, and they point out that trade agreements in themselves, even without special provisions, may have positive human rights spillovers. Whatever the arguments, the proliferation of human rights provisions signals the new reality for trade liberalization. Many PTAs go far beyond commercial policy; they are really governance agreements that contain thousands of pages of obligations related to topics ranging from corporate governance to environmental policy to human rights. Still, the association of trade and human rights in PTAs is a relatively new phenomenon. In a sense it is a shotgun wedding; and it is too early to tell whether this marriage will be effective and enduring. This chapter examines the who, what, when, where, how, and why of the trade–human rights linkage and why we should care about it. Who? The demandeurs for the link include both industrial and developing countries, and at least 131 countries have accepted such links.1 What? Human rights are rights and freedoms to which all humans are entitled. Our discussion is limited to only those human rights set forth in the Universal Declaration of Human Rights (UDHR).2 This study finds that only some of the human rights contained in the declaration have been incorporated into trade agreements. 443


444

Susan Ariel Aaronson

When? Policy makers first made an explicit link between human rights and trade in the U.S. generalized system of preferences (GSP) program in 1984. NAFTA, signed in 1993, was the first preferential trade agreement to include specific human rights language. Where? The provisions may be found in the preamble, in side agreements, or in the body of the agreement. How? Some countries condition the agreement on the partner’s changing its laws to meet international standards (the U.S. approach); others commit governments “not to reduce” high standards in the interests of attracting investment or trade. Examples of the latter approach are the agreement between the European Free Trade Association (EFTA) and the South African Customs Union (SACU), and the PTA between the United States and Colombia (Bartels 2009a). The “how” can also relate to whether the demandeur and the target government adopt monitoring or enforcement strategies in concert with the agreement; whether they link the agreement to capacity building designed to build governance expertise and will; and whether one signatory can challenge human rights violations of the trade agreement or suspend it. Why? We discuss below the reasons why nations might include human rights provisions and why states accept them. So what? We also discuss the outcomes of efforts to link trade and human rights. Some governments have changed their attitudes and behavior toward particular human rights. We don’t know if this change in attitudes and behavior toward human rights is temporary or permanent. This chapter does not cover all the human rights provisions in all PTAs. The discussion is limited to PTAs with explicit human rights objectives, language, or policies, no matter whether the language occurs in the preamble, in the provisions of the agreement, or in a side agreement.3 We also explore human rights spillovers from provisions related to access to information (transparency), political participation, and due process, according to which foreign and domestic producers can comment on policies or regulations affecting trade. Although property rights are important human rights, we do not focus on them except when trade agreements mention the intersection of property rights with other important human rights such as access to medicines (Drahos and Mayne 2002; WHO 2006). The chapter is organized in three sections. The first section is foundational; it defines human rights, examines the history of the global trading system and the role of human rights, and reviews the literature in this area. The second section describes how and why the United States, the EU, EFTA, and Canada became the main demandeurs of provisions for human rights governance. Next, we examine

human rights language in PTAs negotiated by emerging economies. Finally, the third section explores some of the problems and questions raised by the union of trade and human rights. I then offer a conclusion about why governments are increasingly wedding trade and human rights and whether this policy union will thrive. Definitions and Background on Human Rights This section discusses the international law of human rights and the role of human rights in trade agreements, including the International Trade Organization (ITO), the GATT, and the WTO. We then briefly review the findings of scholars active in human rights and trade issues. Human Rights Obligations of Trading Nations States are obligated to act in certain ways in order to protect, respect, and advance human rights. These obligations are delineated in the Universal Declaration on Human Rights (UDHR), which was approved by the members of the United Nations in 1948 and which spells out more than 30 rights that member states are supposed to promote and protect. But the declaration does not legally bind member states (Petersmann 2000). To ensure that human rights would be binding obligations, policy makers developed two covenants that included all the UDHR rights: the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights (ICCPR), and the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (ICESCR).4 The ICCPR enumerates the rights that a state may not take away from its citizens, such as freedom of speech and freedom of movement. In contrast, the ICESCR generally defines rights (often, necessities) that a state should provide for its citizens, such as basic education or health care. The signatories of the ICESCR recognize that governments need expertise and funds to provide all their citizens with rights such as access to education, jobs, and health care. But it is difficult for governments to advance, respect, and realize human rights; it takes considerable governance expertise, funds, and will. Accordingly, a government is only obligated to provide these cultural, economic, and social rights as far as “it is able.”5 The declaration and the covenants have different standings in international law. The Universal Declaration of Human Rights is universal in scope; it applies to everyone, whether or not individual governments have formally accepted its principles or ratified the covenants. The covenants, by their nature as multilateral conventions, are legally binding only on those states that have accepted


Human Rights

them by ratification or accession. They did not go into force until 1976, when 35 member states of the United Nations ratified them. However, many nations have not ratified both covenants.6 In addition, the Universal Declaration does not include all the human rights found in national constitutions, nor does it include many new human rights, such as the right to a healthy environment. Since these newer rights are not embodied in the covenants, they are, thus far, not binding on states, and so they are not discussed in this chapter. Of the 38 human rights set forth in the UDHR, some rights are not affected by or are not relevant to trade, but others, such as labor rights, have been explicitly mentioned in trade agreements (see table 21.1). Table 21.2 summarizes some of the human rights embedded in trade agreements, as of 2010. Some human rights provisions are in the preamble; others are in the body; and still others are expressed in side agreements. Some provisions are binding on the signatories of the agreement, and others are rhetorical. Under international law, states are supposed to do everything in their power to respect, promote, and fulfill human rights. But advancing human rights is not easy. As noted above, many states are unable to meet all of their “international� human rights responsibilities. Moreover, few officials win or maintain office on the basis of their efforts to promote the human rights of noncitizens. However, many people are not comfortable knowing that other human beings lack basic rights in other countries, or live in countries where government officials undermine human rights. These individuals may demand that policy makers take action to protect human rights in other countries. Trade policy is not the only or the best means of extending such protection, but policy makers

445

have few options short of force for changing the behavior of leaders of other countries. Market access can be an important instrument of leverage because it can affect the economic and political health of targeted countries. Furthermore, in recent years policy makers have come to understand that failure to protect human rights (such as labor rights) can affect market access conditions for their own producers.7 Although policy makers may respond to public pressure to use trade to advance human rights, most policy makers do not make human rights a top priority for trade policy making. In most countries, policy makers develop trade policies as though they were strictly commercial instruments. They weigh the interests of their producers and consumers, and although they may consider national security or political concerns, they rarely introduce the interests of the global community into such deliberations. Although policy makers are well aware of the human rights consequences of some of their trade decisions, they have few incentives to ensure that trade policies advance the human rights outlined under the UDHR. Moreover, trade policy makers are generally not charged with ensuring that trade policies or trade flows do not undermine specific human rights at home or abroad. In trade negotiations, governments are charged with pursuing national commercial interests, not global interests (Commission on Human Rights 2004; 3D 2005; Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007). ITO, GATT, and WTO Provisions on Human Rights During World War II, the postwar planners devised several international institutions to govern the global economy. They envisioned an International Trade Organization (ITO)

Table 21.1. Examples of Human Rights Embedded in PTAs: Demandeurs and Position of Provisions in Agreement

Labor rights

Democratic rights

Canada Mercosur Preamble and Linked side agreement protocol Chile Side agreement Mercosur Body United States Body New Zealand

Access to affordable medicines

Right to cultural participation

Freedom of movement

Costa Rica

Canada

EFTA/EEA Body

United States Side letters

New Zealand

CARICOM Body

Indigenous minority rights

Political participation and due process

Canada Preamble and side agreements New Zealand

Canada Body and side agreements

Australia

United States Body

Privacy Canada Body EU Body

Source: Susan Ariel Aaronson. Note: CARICOM, Caribbean Community; EEA, European Economic Area; EFTA, European Free Trade Association; EU, European Union; Mercosur, Southern Cone Common Market (Mercado ComĂşn del Sur); PTA, preferential trade agreement.


446

Susan Ariel Aaronson

Table 21.2. The Universal Declaration on Human Rights and Its Two Covenants International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights Right to life (Art. 3) Right to liberty (Art. 3) Right to security (Art. 3)

Right to the abolition of slavery and slave trade (Art. 4) Right to the prevention of torture or cruel, inhuman, or degrading treatment or punishment (Art. 5) Right to recognition before the law (Art. 6) Right to equality before the law and to equal protection of the law (Art. 7) Right to effective judicial remedy (Art. 8)

Right to the prevention of arbitrary arrest, detention, or exile (Art. 9) Right to fair and public hearing by a neutral tribunal (Art. 10) Right to presumption of innocence (Art. 11.1) Right to nonretroactive penal code (Art. 11.2) Right to privacy (Art. 12) Right to freedom of movement and residence in the country (Art. 13.1) Right to leave the country and return (Art. 13.2) Right to seek and enjoy asylum from prosecution (Art. 14) Right to a nationality (Art. 15) Right to freedom of thought, conscience, and religion (Art. 18) Right to freedom of opinion and expression (Art. 19) Right to freedom of peaceful assembly and association (Art. 20) Right to governmental participation, directly or through freely chosen representatives (Art. 21.1) Right of equal access to public services (Art. 21.2) Right to periodic and fair elections (Art. 21.3)

International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights Right to marriage and found a family (Art. 16) Right to social security (Art. 22) Right to work, free choice of employment, just and favorable conditions of work, and protection against unemployment (Art. 23.1) Right to equal pay for equal work (Art. 23.2) Right to just and favorable remuneration (Art. 23.3) Right to form and join a trade union (Art. 23.4) Right to rest and leisure, including reasonable limitation of working hours and periodic holidays with pay (Art. 24) Right to a sustainable standard of living (including food, clothing, housing, medical care, and necessary social services); right to security in the event of unemployment, sickness, disability, widowhood, old age, or other lack of livelihood in circumstances beyond his control (Art. 25.1) Right to special care and assistance for motherhood and childhood (Art. 25.2) Right to education (Art. 26) Right to cultural participation (Art. 27.1) Right to the protection of intellectual property (Art. 27.2)

Source: Prepared by Philip Van der Celen; in Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007. Note: Italics indicate that the right is included in one or more preferential trade agreements (PTAs).

to reduce barriers to trade. The draft treaty for the ITO was the first trade agreement to include explicit human rights language (related to labor rights). The ITO was designed to ensure that signatories to the agreement did not “export their unemployment” and thereby undermine the ability of workers to provide for their families. In addition, the draft ITO allowed signatories to breach its rules through an “exception” for domestic policies “necessary to protect public morals” or to protect human or plant life and health. (It also included a national security exception.) But the ITO was abandoned after the U.S. Congress failed to vote on implementing legislation (Wilcox 1949; Diebold 1952; Charnovitz 1987). The end of the ITO was not the death knell of efforts to link trade and human rights. In 1995 the members of the

GATT agreed to join a new international organization, the World Trade Organization (WTO). The WTO contains the GATT agreement, and it has a stronger system of dispute settlement. GATT and WTO signatories must adhere to two key principles to reduce trade distortions: the most favored nation principle and the national treatment principle. The most favored nation principle (MFN) requires that the best trading conditions extended to one member by a nation must be extended automatically to every other nation. The national treatment principle provides that once a product is imported, the importing state may not subject that product to regulations less favorable than those that apply to like products produced domestically. The WTO does not explicitly prohibit countries from protecting human rights at home or abroad, but its rules do


Human Rights

constrain the behavior of governments in providing that when member states seek to promote human rights, at home or abroad, they must not unnecessarily or unduly distort trade. It is hard to use trade to promote human rights when nations can’t use trade to distinguish among those nations that may undermine the human rights of their citizens and those that strive to advance these rights. The GATT and the WTO do not directly address how governments relate to their own citizens, and they say very little about human rights.8 But human rights are seeping into the workings of the WTO (Aaronson 2007). Some WTO members have used the GATT/WTO exceptions to advance human rights abroad or to protect human rights at home. Under Article XX, nations can restrict trade when necessary to “protect human, animal, or plant life or health” or to conserve exhaustible natural resources. This article also states that governments may restrict imports relating to the products of prison labor. Although it does not refer explicitly to human rights, the public morals clause of Article XX is widely seen as allowing WTO members to put in place trade bans in the interest of promoting human rights (WTO 2001; Howse 2002; Charnovitz 2005). Brazil used the Article XX exception to ban imports of retreaded tires, which could not easily be disposed of. The national security exception, Article XXI, states that WTO rules should not prevent nations from protecting their own security. Members are not permitted to take trade action to protect another member’s security or to protect the citizens of another member. If, however, the United Nations Security Council authorizes trade sanctions, WTO rules allow countries to use such measures to promote human rights, as when sanctions were instituted against South Africa’s apartheid regime in the 1980s (Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007, 19). Members of the GATT/WTO can use other avenues to protect human rights at home and within other member states (table 21.3). In recent years, member states have used temporary waivers of GATT rules to promote human rights. For example, after the UN called for a ban in trade in conflict diamonds, WTO member states agreed to temporarily waive WTO rules to allow trade in only those diamonds certified by the Kimberley process to be free of

447

conflict (Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007, 43). In addition, some members bring up human rights during accessions, when new members are asked to make their trade and other public policies transparent, accountable, and responsive. They have also discussed human rights issues at trade policy reviews, when member states review the trade and governance performance of other member states. Finally, members have discussed some human rights issues during recent trade negotiations: examples include food security, intellectual property rights (IPRs), and public health (Aaronson 2007). Although the GATT/WTO contains no explicit human rights provisions, it does refer to human rights implicitly. Some of these provisions relate to economic rights such as the right to property, and others, to democratic and political rights. For example, under GATT/WTO rules, member states give economic actors “an entitlement to substantive rights in domestic law including the right to seek relief; the right to submit comments to a national agency or the right to appeal adjudicatory rulings” (Charnovitz 2001). Member states must also ensure that “Members and other persons affected, or likely to be affected, by governmental measures imposing restraints, requirements and other burdens, should have a reasonable opportunity to acquire authentic information about such measures and accordingly to protect and adjust their activities or alternatively to seek modification of such measures.”9 These can be termed due process, information, and political participation rights (Powell 2005); see box 21.1.10 A Brief Review of the Literature on Trade and Human Rights In recent years, scholars from many disciplines have examined the relationship between trade and human rights. Many economists argue that human rights is not a trade issue, but trade can have positive human rights spillovers. As trade expands, individuals exchange ideas, technologies, processes, and cultural norms and goods. With more trade, people in countries with fewer rights and freedoms become aware of conditions elsewhere, and with such knowledge, they may demand greater rights. Isolated

Table 21.3. Examples of Avenues and Actions at the WTO Related to Human Rights, 2005–10 Avenue Accessions Trade policy reviews Disputes Negotiations Source: Susan Ariel Aaronson.

Human right affected Labor rights, access to information, due process (Vietnam, Saudi Arabia, Cambodia) Members discussed labor rights, women’s rights, access to medicines Right to health (Brazil tires) Access to safe, affordable food


448

Susan Ariel Aaronson

Box 21.1. Transparency, Due Process, and Democracy Spillovers from the WTO From 1948 to 1964, contracting parties to the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) were required to promptly publish laws, regulations, and judicial decisions affecting imports and exports (GATT Article X). In this way, exporting interests could learn about legal developments affecting trade and respond to them. GATT contracting parties gradually strengthened these notification requirements, and members were required to administer trade-related laws, regulations, rulings, and agreements in a uniform, impartial, and reasonable manner. Today, the World Trade Organization (WTO) has strong rules for transparency and due process. It requires governments to make their trade laws and regulations transparent and public and to allow citizens to comment on and challenge these laws and regulations. However, neither the GATT nor the WTO requires that members involve their publics in trade policy making. Moreover, many countries do not have a free press, adequate funds, informational infrastructure, or the political will to effectively involve their citizenry in public policy making. The GATT/WTO may also have some unintended human rights spillovers. Member states must provide the same rules and privileges to domestic and foreign actors. These provisions may prod policymakers to provide access to information and enforce rights to public comment in countries where governance is not transparent and participatory. In repressive states, WTO rules may empower domestic market actors (consumers and taxpayers, as well as producers) who may not have been able to use existing domestic remedies to obtain information, influence policies, or challenge their leaders (Aaronson and Abouharb forthcoming). In WTO countries without a strong democratic tradition, member states may make these changes because they want to signal investors that they can be trusted to enforce property rights, uphold the rule of law, and act in an evenhanded, impartial manner (Dobbin, Simmons, and Garrett 2007; Büthe and Milner 2008; Mansfield and Pevehouse 2008, 273).

societies, by contrast, may be more prone to human rights abuses (van Hees 2004). Thus, many of these economists conclude that policy makers need not include human rights provisions in trade agreements (Bhagwati 1996, 1; Sykes 2003, 2–4). Other analysts disagree; they believe that human rights are trade issues, and they cite history and the increasing number of human rights provisions in PTAs as evidence for their perspective. Some legal scholars have proposed ways of finding common ground between WTO trade law and international human rights law (Charnovitz 1994; Dunoff 1999; Garcia 1999; Mehra 1999; Petersmann 2001). Some believe that the best strategy is to enhance the international human rights system and make it more like the WTO, with stronger dispute settlement and enforcement mechanisms. Others believe that the WTO should have explicit human rights provisions (Lim 2001). Some academics have used case studies to discuss the relationship between trade agreements and specific human rights, such as the right to food (Cottier, Pauwelyn, and Bürgi 2005). Others have suggested bridging mechanisms to ensure better dialogue and coordination between trade and human rights officials (Petersmann 2002). Finally, some scholars have examined how the WTO’s dispute settlement system might address a trade dispute involving human rights (Bal 2001; Marceau 2001). However, as policy makers began to refocus their trade liberalization efforts on new PTAs, the debate over how best to reach trade and human rights goals has moved to examining the record of these PTAs. Most of the scholars who have examined human rights provisions focus on labor and environmental language— what some call “trade and” provisions. Dawar (2008) finds that labor and environmental provisions “constitute an unnecessary, inefficient and inappropriate use of a trade

agreement.” Bourgeois, Dawar, and Evenett (2007) argue that the current approach to mainstreaming labor rights in PTAs is ineffective because the provisions commit parties to enforce domestic labor law only. Horn, Mavroidis, and Sapir (2010) conclude that U.S. and EU environmental and labor standards in PTAs are groundbreaking “means for the two hubs to export their own regulatory approaches to their PTA partners.” In short, some scholars see the link as ineffective; others as a means of exporting governance. But these scholars did not examine the panoply of trade–human rights links; they have focused only on labor rights Scholars who have examined human rights provisions in PTAs agree that these provisions are intended to improve governance and advance human rights. Petersmann (2006), a legal scholar, has argued that governments use their PTAs to achieve extraterritorial political reform. As evidence, he cites the growing number of governments that explicitly refer to human rights as an objective or as a fundamental principle of economic integration. Damro (2006) argues that governments include extensive human rights and rule of law provisions in their PTAs because they recognize they must develop coordinated policies in order to address regional threats to security, such as environmental damage, illegal migration, drug smuggling, and international terrorism. In a number of studies, Bartels examines how governments incorporate human rights into their trade agreements (Bartels 2005b, 2008, 2009a, 2009b, and, for an analysis of the objectives of the agreements, Bartels 2005a). He concludes that provisions linking trade and human rights are useful because they set up mechanisms for dialogue, allow civil society in multiple countries to monitor compliance with international norms, and make human


Human Rights

rights part of the trade relationship. Hafner-Burton (2009, 22) compares EU and U.S. approaches toward linking human rights and trade in their GSP and free trade agreements. She notes that although policy makers may be motivated by “protectionist intent,” the agreements appear to be having a positive impact on the realization of human rights in many countries. Aaronson and Zimmerman (2007, 207) compare how the United States, the EU, South Africa, and Brazil make trade policy and find that governments are increasing the scope of human rights, as well as the number of agreements with human rights provisions. They conclude that if people are the “wealth of nations,” policy makers that weigh human rights as they make trade policy are more likely to ensure that their citizens thrive at the intersection of trade and human rights. Few scholars have examined the PTA–human rights nexus empirically. Hafner-Burton (2009, 160–64) focuses on physical integrity rights such as freedom from arbitrary imprisonment and finds that about 82 percent of the countries that have a PTA with the EU improve their human rights protection, as against 75 percent for countries without a trade agreement. However, she relies on personal integrity rights (for example, freedom from arbitrary imprisonment) to make a generic case about human rights, which is not fully convincing. PTAs may have different effects on different human rights. Finally, some scholars have examined whether PTAs serve as an anchor or lock-in mechanism for domestic reforms, including laws advancing human rights. U.S. International Trade Commission (USITC) economist Michael Ferrantino (2006) examined negotiations on PTAs with the United States. He argues that these agreements may improve governance but warns that it is difficult to ascertain whether a particular reform is stimulated by negotiations or by the

449

domestic reform process. Clearly, to better understand the impact of the PTAs, we need both more empirical work and country-specific case studies. Case Studies: PTAs and Human Rights This section examines how Canada, the EU, EFTA, and the United States incorporate human rights provision into their PTAs: table 21.4 summarizes their approaches.11 Table 21.5 examines these provisions according to specific human rights and shows that industrialized countries are not the only countries to link human rights and trade in PTAs. We begin our analysis with Canada, which has become an enthusiastic negotiator of PTAs. Canada Canada is a trade-dependent nation; trade represents more than 70 percent of its gross domestic product (GDP). In recent years the Canadian government has embraced PTAs, on the grounds that this strategy will ensure trade-related economic growth and international competitiveness.12 Canadian policy makers assert that these agreements can help Canada foster a commitment to human rights, freedom, democracy, and the rule of law.13 In Canada the executive branch makes trade policy, which is then approved by the parliament. Although there is no explicit mandate regarding the relationship between trade and human rights, the Canadian government has included several types of human rights in its recent trade agreements: labor rights, cultural rights, indigenous rights, and rights to political participation and due process.14

Table 21.4. Human Rights in Preferential Trade Agreements: Comparing EFTA, the EU, the United States, and Canada EFTA Strategy

Universal human rights

Which rights?

How enforced?

No enforcement

EU

United States

Canada

Universal human rights and specific rights Labor rights, transparency, due process, political participation, and privacy rights

Specific human rights

Specific human rights

Transparency, due process, political participation, access to affordable medicines, and labor rights

Human rights violations lead to dialogue and possible suspension, depending on nature of violation.

In newest agreements, labor rights can be disputed under a dispute settlement body affiliated with the agreement; process begins with bilateral dialogue to resolve issues First challenge: Guatemala

Transparency, due process, political participation, labor rights, privacy rights, cultural and indigenous rights Only labor rights (monetary penalties); use dialogue first

Any challenge? Source: Susan Ariel Aaronson. Note: EFTA, European Free Trade Agreement; EU, European Union.


450

Susan Ariel Aaronson

Table 21.5. Examples of Human Rights Embedded in Preferential Trade Agreements

Labor rights Canada Chile Mercosur United States New Zealand

Democratic rights Mercosur

Access to affordable medicines

Right to cultural participation

Costa Rica United States

Canada New Zealand

Freedom of movement EFTA EEA CARICOM

Indigenous rights

Political participation

Privacy

Canada New Zealand Australia

Canada United States

Canada EU

Source: Susan Ariel Aaronson. Note: CARICOM, Caribbean Community; EEA, European Economic Area; EFTA, European Free Trade Agreement; EU, European Union; Mercosur, Southern Cone Common Market (Mercado Común del Sur).

As of March 2011, Canada has negotiated eight PTAs: the Canadian–U.S. Free Trade Agreement (CUSFTA, now part of NAFTA), and agreements with Peru, EFTA, Costa Rica, Chile, Israel, Jordan, Panama, and Colombia, of which seven are in force. The Canadian government is soliciting public comment on negotiations with about 12 other countries or trading entities. It is engaged in active negotiations with many of these countries or entities.15 Canadian officials clearly see these trade agreements as governance agreements, although they do not call them that. The government asserts that “Canadians recognize that their interests are best served by a stable, rules-based international system. Countries which respect the rule of law tend to respect the rights of their citizens, [and] are more likely to benefit from development.”16 The Department of Foreign Affairs and International Trade (DFAIT) also notes that “The UN Charter and customary international law impose on all countries the responsibility to promote and protect human rights. This is not merely a question of values but a mutual obligation of all members of the international community.”17 Overview of Canada’s human rights–trade strategy. Canada’s approach toward embedding human rights is both broad and specific. The preambles of recent agreements with EFTA, Jordan, Peru, and Colombia refer to human rights objectives, citing the UDHR, labor rights, cultural participation, and protection of human rights and freedoms.18 These agreements include chapters with language on labor rights, transparency, and the environment. The agreements also contain a chapter on exceptions (akin to those in the WTO) and a provision safeguarding the right to regulate and to maintain high standards. The exceptions chapter notes that nothing in the agreement is to apply to cultural sectors and mentions the need to be supportive of trade waivers.19 Labor rights. Because of the division of powers in the areas of environmental and labor regulation under the Canadian constitution, Canadian policy makers believe that

labor and environmental provisions cannot be included in the body of a trade agreement but must be in side agreements, termed labor cooperation agreements.20 According to Human Development and Skills Resources Canada, which negotiates and monitors labor rights internationally, Canada has ratified six labor cooperation agreements in its PTAs with Chile, Costa Rica, Colombia, Jordan. Peru, and NAFTA. (Interestingly, Canada has also negotiated memoranda of understanding on labor cooperation outside its PTAs.)21 The labor side agreements state that signatories must ensure that their labor laws comply with ILO standards and must establish offices to evaluate complaints related to labor rights. In this way, the side agreements are clearly governance agreements, since they attempt to build labor rights governance capacity. The recent agreements also include a nonderogation clause stating that neither party shall waive or otherwise derogate from, or offer to waive or otherwise derogate from, its labor laws in order to encourage trade or investment (Article 2). Both parties commit not only to core standards but also to acceptable occupational health and safety protection and acceptable minimum employment standards. They also agree to provide migrant workers with the same legal protections as nationals with respect to working conditions. These provisions go beyond ILO core labor standards because they also focus on both the demand (public) and supply (policy maker) sides of good labor governance. Signatories are required to educate and involve their publics regarding their rights under labor law. Article 4 articulates a right to private action: “Each party shall ensure that a person with a legally-recognized interest . . . has appropriate access . . . to administrative or tribunal proceedings . . .”22 Article 5 contains procedural guarantees designed to ensure that proceedings “are fair, equitable, and transparent and respect due process of law.” Canadian policy makers seem to agree that by educating foreign workers as to their rights, these workers are more likely to use these rights.


Human Rights

Due process provisions. Canada has expanded on the WTO’s due process provisions for trade-related policy making. Chapter 19 (transparency) in recent Canadian PTAs requires each party to “ensure that in its administrative proceedings . . . persons of the other Party that are directly affected by a proceeding are provided reasonable notice . . . and reasonable opportunity to present facts and arguments in support of their positions.”23 The environmental side agreement also contains due process requirements.24 Here again, Canada uses human rights language to prod its PTA partners to make trade-related policies in a transparent and accountable manner. Political participation provisions. The Canadian government has incorporated several references to political participation into its recent trade agreements. This language is included in Chapter 19 on transparency, as well as in the labor and environmental side agreements. The transparency chapter obligates signatories to include regulations guaranteeing public participation, public comment, and the ability to challenge relevant regulations. The environmental chapter commits the parties “to promote public awareness of environmental laws and policies by ensuring that information regarding environmental laws and policies, as well as compliance and enforcement is available to the public.” These provisions also commit the countries to ensure that the public is able to participate in environmental assessment procedures. In addition, they include a provision allowing any person residing in or established in the territory of either country to submit a written question to either country obliging the country to make the questions and responses available to the public. Although the language is binding, it is also relatively weak: the signatories are asked to strive to cooperate in these areas, endeavor to engage the public, or as the Colombia labor side agreement says, “encourage[e] education of the public regarding its labor laws” (emphasis added). Cultural reservations and exemptions. Canada includes provisions in all its PTAs to ensure that these trade agreements do not affect Canada’s ability to maintain the cultural heritage of the Canadian people or to determine Canadian cultural policies. These provisions are contained in the agreements’ chapters on exceptions. The agreements define Canada’s cultural industries as persons engaged in the publication, distribution, or sale of books, magazines, periodicals, newspapers, music, films and videos, and so on.25 Indigenous rights. The Canada–Colombia (as well as Canada–Peru) side agreement on the environment states, “The Parties also reiterate their commitment, as established by the Convention on Biological Diversity, to respect, preserve and maintain traditional knowledge, innovations and practices of indigenous and local communities that con-

451

tribute to the conservation and sustainable use of biological diversity, subject to national legislation.”26 Because the provision is aspirational, nonbinding, and not disputable, some Canadian nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) see it as inadequate. Response of Canadian NGOs to these human rights provisions. Canadian NGOs working on development, human rights, and labor rights remain critical of the country’s approach. They demanded that Canada perform human rights impact assessments before it initials trade agreements with countries, such as Colombia, where the rule of law is inadequate.27 They argue that such assessments must be conducted by international human rights bodies rather than by the two governments (CCIC 2009). This debate has influenced Canada’s parliament, which seems increasingly interested in the relationship between trade agreement provisions and human rights and in whether Canada’s approach to dealing with these rights is effective.28 In 2010 Canada and Colombia agreed to perform yearly human rights impact assessments of their PTA.29 Canada became the first nation to require such assessments with future trade agreements. However, as of March 2011, Canada has yet to do such a human rights impact assessment or to provide the public with information as to how it will evaluate human rights at home and abroad. Canada’s PTAs and human rights: A summary. The Canadian government has incorporated a wide range of human rights into its PTAs. Canada sees its human rights and trade work as complementary. Its approach is both hortatory and pragmatic, making use of language that sets forth explicit obligations and delineates objectives that the signatories will strive or endeavor to meet. Some of this language, such as obligations focused on transparency and political participation, reflects longstanding Canadian norms on how to govern. Some of the provisions are designed to encourage some of Canada’s trade partners to comply with international human rights norms such as labor rights. But Canadian policy makers recognize that it is not sufficient for outsiders to demand good governance. The public, both in Canada and in Canada’s trade partners, must be informed about and involved in the development of rules if these rules are to be perceived as evenhanded and effective. Yet the Canadian public has not been very supportive of Canada’s approach. Many Canadian NGOs see Canada’s PTAs as opaque, ineffective at improving governance, and undemocratic (CCIC 2009). Canada does not require all of its trade partners to adopt these human rights obligations. For example, it has not embedded many of these provisions in its PTA with EFTA, but, as the next section shows, neither EFTA nor


452

Susan Ariel Aaronson

Canada “requires” such obligations in its PTAs. It will be interesting to see how Canada negotiates with the EU on labor and other human rights in preparation for a transatlantic free trade agreement. Negotiators working on scoping documents for these negotiations agreed that “it would be appropriate to address sustainable development issues through provisions on the environment and labor rights, including the core labor standards embodied in the 1998 ILO Declaration . . . Such provisions could include, inter alia: the right to regulate while aiming for high levels of protection; effective enforcement of environment and labor laws; a commitment to refrain from waiving such laws in a manner that affects trade or investment; a framework for cooperation; public involvement; and mechanisms to monitor and address disputes.”30 European Free Trade Association (EFTA) EFTA began in 1960 as a framework for liberalizing trade and promoting economic cooperation among several European nations. At that time, some EFTA member states were unwilling or unable (for reasons of sovereignty or neutrality) to join the EU. The membership of EFTA has changed over time; Austria, Denmark, Finland, Portugal, Sweden, and the United Kingdom left to join the EU. Iceland, Liechtenstein, Norway, and Switzerland are the members of EFTA as of March 2011. In recent years, EFTA has become an active PTA negotiator. EFTA has 22 free trade agreements, covering 31 countries.31 It is now negotiating with Algeria; Bosnia and Herzegovina; Hong Kong SAR, China; India; Indonesia; Montenegro; the Russian Federation, Belarus, and Kazakhstan; and Thailand. EFTA’s PTAs do not include explicit human rights provisions, although trade policy makers have included references to human rights in both the preamble and the investment chapters of several agreements (Bartels 2009a). The preamble typically mentions the desire to create new employment opportunities, improve working conditions and living standards, and promote sustainable development, and it reaffirms the parties’ “commitment to the principles and objectives set out in the UN Charter and Universal Declaration.” But the agreements do not aim to improve human rights or strive toward sustainable development; they do not go beyond WTO exceptions regarding public morals, public health, and trade in goods made with prison labor.32 For FTAs with African states, EFTA includes language in its investment chapter noting that “the parties recognize that it is inappropriate to encourage investment by relaxing health, safety, or environmental standards.”33 The agreements also note that the EFTA states are to provide technical assistance

to implement the objectives of the agreement and support partner countries’ efforts to achieve sustainable economic and social development.34 Some recent PTAs, such as those with Canada, Colombia, and the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC), refer to ILO principles, but contracting parties have no obligations in the agreement regarding the ILO. Since late 2008, EFTA has been exploring whether to include environmental and labor and social standards in its PTAs. The Committee of Members of Parliament of the EFTA countries has commissioned a study on environmental policies and labor standards in PTAs but is not looking at human rights per se as an issue to be included in trade agreements.35 Regarding the addition of labor and environmental provisions, the study notes that although a growing number of nations have such provisions, they may “breach” the regulatory framework of any of the parties to a PTA. The authors stress that much of the evidence regarding the quality of these provisions is qualitative rather than quantitative, and they conclude that it is difficult to assess the effectiveness of their inclusion.36 EFTA has set up working groups to examine whether or how to embed such provisions, but as of the time of writing (March 2011), they had not reached a decision. Thus, EFTA does not seem to be enthusiastic or to see an urgency about including further provisions in its PTAs. Human rights in the EEA treaty. Although EFTA has not played a leading role in linking trade and human rights, the European Economic Area (EEA) treaty—EFTA’s main agreement with the EU—does use the language of human rights. This agreement, however, is much more than a trade agreement. It is designed to ensure “four freedoms”—free movement of goods, services, persons, and capital—throughout the 30 EEA states. The agreement guarantees equal rights and obligations within the internal market for citizens and economic operators in the EEA. The provisions on social security are meant to coordinate the respective national systems of the EEA states and thus to ensure social protection in case of, among other contingencies, sickness, maternity, invalidity, death, or unemployment. EFTA also has language to safeguard the pension rights of persons who exercise their fundamental right to move and reside freely within the EEA. The preamble of the EEA agreement discusses “the contribution that a European Economic Area will bring to the construction of a Europe based on peace, democracy and human rights.” The preamble also notes the importance of “equal treatment of men and women” and cites the signatories’ desire “to ensure economic and social progress and to promote conditions for full employment, an improved standard of living and improved working conditions.”37 Part III, Article 28, of the agreement refers to free movement


Human Rights

of persons. It seeks to secure freedom of movement for workers through “the abolition of any discrimination based on nationality between [European Community] member states and EFTA states.”38 Taken in sum, the EEA agreement is very much a human rights document. EFTA’s PTAs and human rights: A summary. Although EFTA includes some human rights language in its PTAs, it is just beginning to examine whether it should go further, by making human rights provisions actionable and/or disputable. EFTA policy makers might seek inspiration in their most important agreement, the treaty that set up the EEA. We can best understand this trade agreement as a governance agreement that harmonizes a wide range of laws and regulations that could distort trade but does so in ways that enhance human rights. European Union (EU) The EU is the behemoth of world trade; it is the world’s largest trade bloc.39 It is also the most enthusiastic proponent of the inclusion of human rights provisions in PTAs. With nearly 500 million citizens, the EU possesses approximately a quarter of the world’s economic wealth. Given its size and political influence, its policies move markets. The EU is an active participant in and negotiator of bilateral and regional PTAs. Since 1995, the European Commission Directorate General for Trade, which makes trade policy for the members of the EU, has included social and labor clauses in all its free trade agreements.40 EU policy makers have incorporated social and labor clauses into more than 50 trade agreements involving more than 120 countries. The EU includes human rights in many of its agreements with other countries, including its partnership and cooperation agreements41 and its generalized system of preferences (GSP) program with developing countries. However, in this chapter we focus only on the economic partnership agreements, such as that with the Caribbean Forum of African, Caribbean, and Pacific (ACP) States (CARIFORUM) and recent free trade agreements. The EU and its member states have a long history of using trade agreements to promote human rights. In 1992 the European Commission included “an essential elements clause” in trade agreements with developing countries. The clause states that respect for human rights is an essential element of the agreement. The signatories to such agreements agree that either party may suspend the agreement without notice if these “essential elements” are violated. In 1995 the EU decided to include the human rights clause in all future international trade agreements, whether with developing or with industrial countries (Bartels 2005a).42

453

This human rights clause is given operative effect through a “nonexecution” clause stating that a failure to fulfill an obligation under the agreement, including human rights obligations, entitles the other party to take appropriate measures, subject to a consultative procedure (Bartels 2009a). As of October 2009, the EU also included human rights clauses in nine regional trade agreements (association agreements), with Algeria, the Arab Republic of Egypt, Israel, Jordan, Lebanon, Morocco, the Palestinian Authority, the Syrian Arab Republic, and Tunisia. Similar human rights clauses were also incorporated into stabilization and accession trade agreements with Croatia and the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia; in pending agreements with Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, and Montenegro; and in regional trade agreements with Chile, Mexico, and South Africa.43 The EU is currently negotiating a PTA with Canada. As noted above, it will be interesting to see how the two reconcile their unique human rights and trade strategies. Economic partnership agreements (EPAs). The nations of the EU have long-standing trade relationships with their former colonies. Not surprisingly, the EU is determined to maintain these relationships, but also to use them to foster development and economic growth and to improve governance. In 1975, the members of the EU and their 79 former colonies signed a treaty, the Lomé Convention, which set out standards for development cooperation. In 2000 the EU and its Lomé partners adopted the Cotonou Agreement.44 The Cotonou Agreement was based on four principles: equality of partners; political participation; dialogue and mutual obligations, including human rights obligations; and differentiation, based on the idea that each country is unique. Under the Cotonou Agreement, the EU and its development partners agreed to develop regional trade agreements (called economic partnership agreements) with regionally specific rights and obligations. The EU is currently negotiating with, or has completed negotiations with, six regional groupings of countries: West Africa (Ghana); the Southern African Development Community (SADC), with Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia, Mozambique, and Swaziland as members; Pacific (Fiji and Papua New Guinea); Eastern and Southern Africa (ESA), encompassing the Comoros, Madagascar, Mauritius, the Seychelles, Zambia, and Zimbabwe; and the East African Community (EAC), composed of Burundi, Kenya, Rwanda, Tanzania, and Uganda.45 The EU and the CARIFORUM countries concluded negotiations on their EPA in October 2008.46 The EU uses the CARIFORUM EPA agreement as a model for delineating human rights obligations in other EPAs. Although several countries have signed these regional agreements, the European Commission is


454

Susan Ariel Aaronson

waiting on other countries to approve these agreements, which are quite controversial both in Europe and in the developing world.47 The CARIFORUM agreement refers to human rights, democratic principles, and the rule of law as essential elements of the Cotonou Agreement and cites “good governance” as a fundamental element.48 The signatories agree to respect basic labor rights in line with their ILO commitments. Article 3 of the agreement states that the parties agree to work cooperatively toward the realization of “sustainable development centered on the human person.” Article 5 continues with that focus on human beings, noting that the parties will continuously monitor the agreement to ensure that benefits for people are maximized. Article 32 calls for transparent rules and for public explanation of legislation. Labor issues are delineated in Chapter 5; the EU refers to labor provisions as the “social aspects” of the agreement. In Article 191 the parties reaffirm their commitment to labor standards and decent work; in addition, the parties recognize the benefits of fair and ethical trade products. Finally, Article 193 is the nonderogation clause, which requires the parties not to try to gain competitive advantage by lowering standards or ignoring their laws. Article 195 sets out a process for consultation and monitoring and creates a committee of experts to examine compliance with the agreement. The committee can be called on to examine concerns among the members regarding “obstacles that may prevent the effective implementation of core labor standards.”49 Chapter 6 of the agreement refers to trade in data. Articles 196 and 197 continue the focus on individuals; here the parties recognize their “common interest in protecting fundamental rights and freedoms of natural persons, and in particular, their right to privacy, with respect to the processing of personal data.”50 Although these agreements contain considerable human rights language, most of it is aspirational and nonbinding. Only the sustainable development chapters of the EPAs, on the environment and on social issues, employ public scrutiny, expert panels, and consultations as means of resolving disputes (Bartels 2005a, iv–vi). The agreements have no dispute settlement mechanism. The only way to hold governments to account is for citizens to monitor human rights violations and press policy makers to discuss any such violations bilaterally. In short, the EU relies on negotiations to monitor human rights linked to trade in these EPAs. Free trade agreements (FTAs). In 2006 EU member states agreed to negotiate what it calls FTAs with several rapidly growing Asian nations. The EU made it clear that these trade agreements would include a wide range of issues not

typically covered in the WTO, such as investment, the environment, and social and labor clauses.51 As of March 2011, the EU was actively negotiating FTAs with Colombia, Peru, Central America, Canada, India, Malaysia, Singapore, the Southern Cone Common Market (Mercosur, Mercado Común del Sur), and Ukraine, as well as regional and bilateral Euro-Mediterranean agreements.52 The European Commission completed its first FTA, with the Republic of Korea, in 2009. In February 2011, the European Parliament approved by agreement.53 The Korean agreement illuminates the EU’s new approach toward linking sustainable development (social and environmental) clauses to trade. The preamble reaffirms both parties’ commitment to the Universal Declaration of Human Rights and to sustainable development. It also notes the parties’ desire to “strengthen the development and enforcement of labor and environmental laws and policies, promote basic workers’ rights and sustainable development and implement this agreement in a manner consistent with these objectives.”54 Like the CARIFORUM agreement, this FTA contains language protecting the right to privacy. Article 7.43, in the services chapter, states that each party should reaffirm its commitment to protecting the fundamental rights and freedoms of individuals and should adopt adequate safeguards for the protection of privacy. The agreement with Korea includes a separate chapter on trade and sustainable development. Article 13.4 commits the two parties to respect, promote, and realize core labor rights. The parties also reaffirm their commitment to effectively implement the ILO conventions that both states have ratified. Article 13.6 states that the parties “shall strive to facilitate and promote trade in goods that contribute to sustainable development, including goods that are the subject of schemes such as fair and ethical trade.” Article 13.7 contains the nonderogation clause, in which the parties agree to effectively enforce environmental and labor laws and not to weaken, waive, or derogate from those laws in a manner affecting trade or investment. Finally, Article 13.9 commits the parties to “introduce and implement any measures aimed at protecting the environment and labor . . . in a transparent manner with due notice and public consultation.” To achieve that goal, the agreement creates a unique domestic advisory group on sustainable development, as well as a civil society forum on these issues (Annex 13). Thus, the agreement sets up a citizen monitoring process. The new paradigm includes a strategy for government consultations on social issues, as well as a panel of experts to examine issues that cannot be settled through governmental consultations. In contrast with the U.S. model, the EU has designed no formal mechanism for trade disputes


Human Rights

related to these issues; instead, civil society will monitor commitments (Articles 13.14 and 13.15). The new model PTA also has a transparency chapter (Chapter 12) requiring that information be made available to all interested persons, as well as rules for public comment (Article 12.3) and due process (Article 12.5, on administrative proceedings). This new chapter is very similar to the U.S. and Canadian transparency chapters, but it also includes a nondiscrimination section that provides, in part, “Each party shall apply to interested persons of the other Party transparency standards no less favourable than those accorded to its own interested persons, to the interested persons of any third country, . . . whichever are the best.” Finally, Protocol 3 provides for cultural cooperation and recognizes cultural diversity and cultural heritage.55 The new FTA model, as embodied by the FTA with Korea, contains a wide range of human rights provisions, some of which are binding on the signatories. But, as with the EPAs, neither policy makers nor citizens can challenge another state’s nonperformance. Thus, this model is unlikely to satisfy the many NGOs that are critical of how the EU links trade and human rights.56 Moreover, the EU does not examine the broad impact of its trade policies on human rights, but it does hire independent consultants to carry out sustainability impact assessments. These consultants look at income, poverty, and biodiversity; except in the area of gender inequality, they do not attempt to assess how the provisions of a free trade agreement might affect human rights conditions in trading-partner nations.57 Given their concerns about the EU model, some NGOs have asked EU policy makers not to conclude or ratify trade or partnership agreements with countries that have questionable human rights records. They fear that such agreements could strengthen or reward repressive regimes.58 EU policy makers, however, are not eager to cut off trade in the interest of promoting human rights, and they believe it is important to use trade as a tool for shaping relations with emerging markets. The EU’s PTAs and human rights: A summary. At first glance, the EU’s approach is supportive of the human rights set forth in the UDHR. The EU takes the position that human rights are universal and indivisible and that these rights are key aspects of the rule of law. Although the trade agreements include considerable human rights language, much of it is rhetorical, nonbinding, and not disputable. In its new FTAs and EPAs, the EU not only refers to the UDHR; it also emphasizes sustainable development (social and environmental issues). This approach creates new advisory roles for experts and civil society, but neither states nor individuals can use these provisions to challenge human rights violations.

455

In considering a potential agreement, the EU hires consultants to assess the impact of its trade agreements on sustainable development. It seems strange that these assessments do not focus on the bulk of human rights delineated in the UDHR (Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007, 138–43; Bartels 2009a). EU policy makers believe that dialogue and capacity building are the best means of changing the behavior of other countries.59 EU policies focus on the supply side of governance but seem to be less focused on empowering citizens in other countries. Moreover, the EU rarely cuts trade or adopts trade sanctions toward trade agreement partners that may violate human rights. Thus, despite the EU’s professed belief in the universality and indivisibility of international human rights, policy makers are sending a message that some rights are more important than others and that only some countries can be prodded with trade policy tools to change their behavior.60 United States The United States bears much of the responsibility for the world’s recent renewed focus on PTAs. In 2001 U.S. Trade Representative Robert Zoellick proposed that the U.S. government reorient trade liberalization toward bilateral and regional PTAs in the hope of encouraging “competitive trade liberalization.” He theorized that if countries saw significant progress in bilateral PTAs, they might accept deeper market access concessions at the WTO. But instead of stimulating a renewed commitment to multilateral trade talks, the U.S. focus on PTAs prodded other countries to negotiate their own PTAs, which in turn has stimulated ever more PTAs.61 U.S. policy makers don’t describe American PTAs as governance agreements, but the United States does use the lure of its huge market to encourage other countries to make significant policy changes. The United States has pushed for governance improvements that protect foreign investors. Recent research has found that these provisions have human rights spillovers—they seem to empower domestic as well as foreign actors who gain benefits from increased transparency, greater evenhandedness, and the due process rules promoted in these agreements. But the United States promotes only some human rights in its trade agreements. At the behest of labor unions and their congressional allies, the United States is most concerned about using these agreements to advance labor rights among U.S. PTA partners. U.S. trade policy is complicated, confusing, and often inconsistent, vacillating between market-opening strategies and protectionist measures. To some degree, this is because no one individual is in charge of trade policy making; authority is shared between the legislative and executive branches. The 535 members of


456

Susan Ariel Aaronson

Congress and the president have divergent views about trade and about the linkage between trade and human rights (Smith 2006). Members of Congress “think local” and, in times of recession, are focused on local economic growth. Without a great understanding of what trade agreements do, many members have little enthusiasm for negotiating them. As a result, Congress has not provided authority to negotiate new trade agreements at the bilateral or multilateral level since 2002. Yet, during the eight years of the George W. Bush administration, the U.S. Trade Representative (USTR) negotiated trade agreements with Australia, Bahrain, CAFTA–DR (Central America Free Trade Agreement— Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua— and the Dominican Republic), Chile, Colombia, Jordan, Morocco, Oman, Panama, Peru, and Singapore (U.S. GAO 2009). As of March 2011, Congress had approved all but the agreements with Colombia, Korea, and Panama. The Obama administration has agreed to move these agreements forward, but it has also asked Korea, Panama, and Colombia to make additional changes in order to win congressional approval. As of March 2011, the Korean government had agreed to several changes, but the Obama administration continues to work with Panamanian and Colombian officials.62 With two wars and a burgeoning budget deficit, these agreements do not seem to be a top priority for either the administration or the Republicandominated house. Congress sets the objectives for trade policy making, but it has not made the advancement of human rights through trade agreements a top priority. In the Trade Promotion Act of 2002 (hereafter, TPA), which grants the president “fast-track” authority to negotiate trade agreements, the words “human rights” never appear.63 Congress has directed negotiators to focus on the following specific human rights: labor rights, access to information, public participation, and due process. In recent years, negotiators have also been directed to balance the rights of U.S. intellectual property rights (IPR) holders with U.S. obligations in the Doha Declaration on Public Health. Almost all recent PTAs contain language related to these human rights. Negative spillovers of the focus on labor rights rather than on broader human rights. Activists and legislators have focused most of their attention on provisions addressing labor rights (see Elliott, ch. 20 in this volume). This is partly attributable to the clout of trade unions, but also to the failure of many U.S. trade partners to enforce the labor laws on their books. These partners’ difficulties regarding labor rights may be a symptom of a larger governance problem, and the focus on labor rights may make it more difficult to use the agreements to promote good governance and human rights. The dilemma is most visible in the case of Colombia.

The U.S.–Colombia FTA has been pending since 2006. Many Democratic members of Congress have signaled that they cannot vote for the agreement because of Colombia’s problems with labor rights. They note the high rate of violence (murders, arbitrary detentions, and kidnappings of trade unionists), as well as weak enforcement of labor laws. Colombia’s labor rights problems are part of a greater problem of impunity, inadequate governance, and corruption (Bolle 2009). The pending PTA is not designed to address these issues per se, yet its fate rests on the public’s and policy makers’ perception of these problems as mainly labor rights issues. In this way, the PTA illuminates the inadequacies of the U.S. focus on labor rights, rather than good governance per se.64 Moreover, the United States seems to be moving from using these PTAs as an incentive to improve human rights to using them to hold nations accountable for specific human rights performance. In July 2009 the Obama administration announced that it would make important changes in trade policy making to advance “the social accountability and political transparency of trade policy” (USTR 2009). On July 16, 2009, U.S. Trade Representative Ron Kirk made it clear that the U.S. government was less interested in delineating labor rights provisions or providing incentives for international labor rights through its trade agreements than in establishing “a level playing field for American workers.” He added that the “USTR will, proactively monitor and identify labor violations and enforce labor provisions . . . When efforts to resolve violations have been expired, USTR will not hesitate . . . to invoke formal dispute settlement.”65 However, as of March 2011, the United States has filed only one such case, against Guatemala, under the CAFTA-DR agreement, for alleged violations of obligations on labor rights.66 Nonetheless, the United States has signaled that labor rights violations under FTAs will be investigated, and if violations are not remedied, the United States could bring the issue to a trade dispute. This new policy has clearly elevated labor rights. Public participation, transparency, and due process. As noted above, the U.S. Congress requires its trade agreement partners to agree to PTA provisions related to transparency, due process, and political participation.67 These provisions are embedded in the transparency, anticorruption, and regulatory practices sections of the TPA. The Congress declared that the United States aims to “obtain wider and broader application of the principles of transparency” through “increased transparency and opportunity for the participation of affected parties in the development of regulations.” The legislation also states that trade negotiators should “establish consultative mechanisms among parties to trade agreements to promote increased


Human Rights

transparency in developing guidelines, rules, regulations and laws.”68 Finally, the act notes that to avoid corruption, the United States intends “to obtain high standards and appropriate domestic enforcement mechanisms applicable to persons from all countries participating in the applicable trade agreement.”69 The United States has been promoting transparency and due process rights in multilateral trade agreements since the end of World War II (Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007). U.S. policy makers have long argued that “transparency is the starting point for ensuring the efficiency, and ultimately the stability of a rules-based environment for goods crossing the border.”70 All U.S. PTAs approved since 2002 contain a chapter on transparency, and they thus go beyond the WTO rules—they are “WTO+.” (There are also transparency provisions in other chapters of the PTA.) Although the language in these chapters varies from agreement to agreement, in general, the passages are framed in the language of human rights. They require governments to publish, in advance, laws, rules, procedures, and regulations affecting trade, thereby giving “persons of the other party that are directly affected by an agency’s process . . . a reasonable opportunity to present facts and arguments in support of their positions prior to any final administrative action.” These agreements also contain a section on review and appeal, designed to give the parties a reasonable opportunity to support or defend their respective positions.71 Such provisions are not intended to promote human rights as such, but they may have human rights spillovers. In contrast, U.S. efforts to foster public participation are relatively new, dating from 1992. The United States and its partners first experimented with public participation provisions in the environmental side agreements to NAFTA. As part of that agreement, Mexico, Canada, and the United States set up a mechanism, the Citizen Submissions on Enforcement Matters, to enable members of the public from any of the three countries to submit a claim when a government is allegedly not enforcing its environmental laws.72 The commission investigates the allegation and issues nonbinding resolutions. These investigations have occasionally led governments to change course. For example, the Mexican government has become more responsive to the environmental side effects from trade. Based on public pressure from citizen submissions, the Mexican government promised remediation in the case of toxic pollutants abandoned at a lead smelter in Tijuana, and Mexico’s president declared the Cozumel Coral Reef a protected area (Silvan 2004). The George W. Bush administration (2001–09) decided to enhance public participation provisions. Administration officials believed that trade agreements could act as an

457

incentive for democracy in the Middle East and might also cement democracy in Latin American nations such as Colombia and El Salvador that had experienced conflict.73 These officials recognized that democracy could not simply be exported; they understood that some countries need help in strengthening democratic institutions, processes, and accountability.74 They hoped that if the United States helped such countries to become more democratic and accountable to their publics, they (and the United States) would gain greater legitimacy, and over time these allies would become more stable. They also believed that trade agreements with the United States would gain public support if citizens in partner countries could comment on various versions of the agreement and in so doing shape key public policies. Under pressure from several members of Congress, trade policy makers developed three models for public participation, which were incorporated first in the environmental chapters of PTAs and later in the labor chapters, as well. The first model was for developed democratic countries such as Australia, and it thus contained minimal public participation provisions in the environmental chapter. The second model was designed for countries with relatively weak systems of environmental regulation and accountability, or countries relatively new to democracy; it was used for Bahrain, Chile, Morocco, Oman, and Singapore.75 Under this second model, the bilateral trade partners set up an advisory committee, an Environmental Affairs Council, that would meet regularly and engage the public in discussion on the environment.76 Policy makers also agreed to provide capacity-building assistance to support public participation (USTR 2005). Senator Max Baucus, a Democrat from Montana, played an important role in developing a third, more extensive, approach. In 2004 he called on the USTR to put the public participation provisions directly in the trade agreement, to develop benchmarks and “ways to measure progress over time,” and to find ways to encourage objective monitoring and scrutiny by the public (Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007, 174–76). The CAFTA–DR agreement was the USTR’s first test of the third model. In February 2005 the United States and its six partners in CAFTA–DR agreed to establish a mechanism and secretariat allowing the general public to submit petitions regarding the operation of the agreement’s labor or environmental provisions. If members of the public from any party to CAFTA–DR believe that any party is not effectively enforcing its labor or environmental laws, they can make a new submission to this subbody, which reports to the Environmental Affairs Council. The agreement states that each party should review and respond to such communications in accordance with


458

Susan Ariel Aaronson

its own domestic procedures.77 CAFTA–DR also authorizes the tribunal “to accept and consider amicus curiae submissions from a person or entity that is not a disputing party.” To develop a workable system, the United States agreed to fund the first year of the secretariat’s work.78 The USTR has replicated this model in more recent PTAs, such as those with Colombia, Korea, Panama, and Peru.79 The labor chapter of these PTAs, Article 19.4, notes, “Each party shall ensure that persons with a recognized interest under its law in a particular matter have appropriate access to tribunals for the enforcement of the Party’s labor laws.” In addition, “Each party shall promote public awareness of its labor laws including by (a) ensuring that information related to its labor laws and enforcement and compliance procedures is publicly available; and (b) encouraging education of the public regarding its labor laws.”80 The United States and its trade partners have also established Labor Affairs Councils with other PTA partners.81 As readers might imagine, the placement of participation provisions in trade agreements cannot magically stimulate democracy. Such an approach may not work in countries lacking a tradition of political participation or free speech, and it may appear to violate another country’s sovereignty or cultural mores. However, these provisions might push partner governments to allow more public participation and could gradually teach citizens how to engage and challenge policy makers. Since signing a free trade agreement with the United States, PTA partners Chile, the Dominican Republic, Jordan, Kuwait, Mexico, and Morocco have established channels through which organized civil society can comment on trade policies (Cherfane 2006: Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007). Access to affordable medicines. Congress has long viewed protecting intellectual property rights (IPR) holders as a top priority. The United States is by far the most assertive country in defending intellectual property rights within the context of trade policies and agreements, even when trade partners and human rights activists argue that U.S. policies undermine the ability of policy makers or citizens to obtain access to affordable medicine or to protect indigenous knowledge. U.S. assertiveness stems from a long-standing belief among policy makers that the country’s economic future is rooted in America’s global economic dominance of creative industries such as software, biotechnology, and entertainment.82 These intellectual property–based industries represent the largest single sector of the U.S. economy.83 To protect that future, U.S. policy makers work with their overseas counterparts to enforce intellectual property rights, seize counterfeit goods, pursue criminal enterprises involved in piracy and counterfeiting, and “aggressively engage our trading partners to join our efforts” (CEA 2005, 226).

U.S. policy makers are increasingly sensitive to public concerns that there are costs to elevating IPR protection. Drugs and vaccines are increasingly expensive, and the policy does not encourage the development of generic brands. Moreover, some argue that the policy does not adequately protect indigenous knowledge—knowledge passed down through familiar and cultural ties, but not protected under domestic law. In the 2002 TPA, Congress required the Bush administration to rethink its approach, and “secure fair, equitable, and nondiscriminatory market access opportunities for United States persons that rely upon intellectual property protection; and to respect the Declaration on the [Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)] Agreement and Public Health.”84 The executive branch, however, was not given a mandate to ensure access to affordable medicines. Beginning in April 2004, all PTAs include a letter entitled “Understandings Regarding Certain Public Health Measures” that is signed by representatives of both governments. The letter, found in the Bahrain, CAFTA–DR, Colombia, Morocco, Oman, and Peru PTAs, says that the IPR provisions of the agreement “do not affect a Party’s ability to take necessary measures to protect public health.”85 But the letter does not make it clear that governments can breach IPR obligations in order to ensure that their citizens have access to affordable medicines. These side letters do not assuage critics, including the World Bank (Mercurio 2006, 234–35). Interestingly, this policy may not change dramatically under the Obama administration. There is no mention of public health in the President’s Trade Policy Agenda, and the Trade Agreements Report, like others before it, simply stresses that strong intellectual property protection is essential for protecting public health (USTR 2011). U.S. PTAs and human rights: A summary. The U.S. approach to linking PTAs and human rights is contradictory. On the one hand, it ignores the internationally accepted notion that human rights are universal and indivisible, yet on the other hand, the United States works hard to promote specific human rights and now makes some of these rights binding. The United States is essentially saying to its partner nations: make the rights we value top priorities. In this way, the U.S. strategy toward linking human rights is insensitive toward other cultures, which may have different human rights priorities. This strategy may inspire U.S. trade partners to do more to advance some human rights, but it is unlikely to inspire these governments to devote more resources to human rights in general. The United States (like Canada) uses its trade agreements to improve governance and, in so doing, to empower citizens to demand their rights. However, the United States


Human Rights

uses the leverage of trade agreements to induce other nations to invest in the governance priorities valued by U.S. policy makers instead of in human rights as delineated in international law. South-South Agreements Although developed countries are the main demandeurs of human rights provisions in PTAs, a number of emerging economies include such links in their trade agreements. Policy makers have incorporated language dealing with access to affordable medicines, indigenous or minority rights, due process, cultural rights, and labor rights. These provisions are usually located in the preamble of the agreement, with a few in the body of the text. Some developing countries link trade and human rights by building on the exceptions in GATT/WTO Article XX described earlier. For example, Article 8 of the agreement between Egypt and Jordan allows measures “for religious, hygienic, security or environmental reasons as long as they are in conformity with the applicable laws and regulations in both countries.” (This is the only provision that we have found that associates trade and freedom of religion.) Other countries target different human rights. For example, the Caribbean Community (CARICOM) allows for the free movement of university graduates and those in listed occupations. Some countries have more restricted provisions regarding free movement of people. (See Stephenson and Hufbauer, ch. 13 in this volume, on labor mobility.) For example, NAFTA and the Canada–Chile and U.S.–Chile PTAs contain chapters on temporary entry of business persons.86 Article 6 of the treaty establishing the Common Market of Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA) commits members to promote democracy and human rights.87 Several human rights are embedded in the Mercosur agreement between Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, and Uruguay.88 If any party to Mercosur fails to protect ILO core labor standards, a supranational Commission on Social and Labor Matters can review allegations at the behest of another member state, although it cannot impose trade sanctions or other penalties in the event of such a violation.89 Like the EU, Mercosur is built on the recognition that if the members want to jointly expand trade, they must collaborate on a wide range of issues. Thus, it is more of a governance agreement than simply a trade agreement. In 1998 Mercosur members adopted the Ushuaia Protocol on democratic commitment, which prohibits the entry of undemocratic states into the common market. Although the protocol text itself makes no explicit mention of human rights, Mercosur members invoked the protocol as a joint response to a 1996 coup d’état in Paraguay, and the Brazilian delegation

459

cited numerous human rights motivations when it presented the protocol to the United Nations in 2000. For instance, when explaining the rationale for a democracy clause, Brazilian policy makers argued that “democracy, development, and respect for human rights and fundamental freedoms are interdependent and mutually reinforcing.”90 Thus, although the Mercosur trade agreement contains no binding human rights commitments, Brazil and its Mercosur partners see the protection of human rights and democracy as a rationale for, and a side effect of, the agreement (Anderson and Zimmerman 2007, 106). Nevertheless, Mercosur refused to investigate allegations of human rights abuses by member state Argentina (Garcia 2003). Chile has incorporated labor rights language into several of its more recent bilateral PTAs. For example, as noted by Elliott (ch. 20 in this volume), the trade agreement between Chile and China includes two labor and environmental side agreements. Article 108 commits both parties “to carry out cooperation activities in the fields of employment and labor policies and social dialogue.” Although Chile’s language is aspirational, this language does underscore the importance of labor rights.91 In addition, Chile’s agreements with Costa Rica, Colombia, and Korea, as well as the CARICOM–Costa Rica PTA, refer to social protection (Bartels 2009a). Summary These South-South trade and human rights provisions, as well as those in the U.S., European, and other agreements, reflect a changing attitude about what trade agreements should include and what they are about. According to Bartels, “the idea that these links are valid seems to be gaining its own dynamic” (Bartels 2009a, 365). Moreover although many of these provisions are aspirational and not binding, such provisions may not remain rhetorical. Bartels concludes that as the number of agreements containing preambular references to human rights grows in number and scope, “this may well lead to operative provisions at a later stage,” as happened with EU human rights provisions (365). The Effects of the Marriage of PTAs and Human Rights Although the wedding of trade and human rights is new, this marriage is leading to important changes in the way policy makers make trade policy. The sheer number and dispersion of PTAs with human rights links seem to be changing some policy makers’ opinions about human rights. These provisions have thus contributed to the recognition and


460

Susan Ariel Aaronson

internationalization of human rights norms. Second, these provisions are changing the behavior of government officials in a wide variety of countries, as described below. Mauritania. The European Commission used consultations to warn the new government of Mauritania that the government’s behavior breached that country’s commitments under the Cotonou Agreement. Soon thereafter, the new Mauritanian regime pledged to hold free and fair elections and initiated a process to establish an independent National Commission for Human Rights. In 2007 the government held free and fair elections. While one can’t say that the PTA’s human rights provisions pushed the military government to protect human rights, political scientist Hafner-Burton concludes that these provisions gave the EU leverage over the government’s progress toward reforms (Hafner-Burton 2009, 151–60). Thailand. In 2003 Thailand entered into PTA negotiations with the United States. In 2005 the Thailand National Human Rights Commission drafted a report on the human rights implications of the proposed trade agreement, expressing concern about traditional knowledge and intellectual property rights. The report concluded that Thailand would have to adopt U.S. laws if it agreed to the trade agreement.92 The Thai public began to oppose the agreement. The Thai prime minister pledged to ensure greater public involvement in the negotiating process to shape the agreement.93 However, the negotiations ended after a military coup. El Salvador and Guatemala. The USTR asserted that El Salvador and Guatemala held their first public hearings on trade as they negotiated CAFTA. These governments continue to engage their citizens in trade. during the negotiations of CAFTA. With such hearings, individuals and NGOs learn how to influence trade policy. Trade policy makers in these countries may have acted under U.S. pressure, but they may also have recognized that they must involve their publics if they don’t want to engender significant opposition to such agreements (Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007, 176). As noted earlier, other nations with little tradition of civil society or even business involvement in trade, such as Bahrain, Jordan, and Oman, also created public advisory bodies (Cherfane 2006; Lombardt 2008). Mexico. Since joining NAFTA, Mexican trade policy has become more responsive to public concerns. For example, the Mexican government revamped its agricultural policies. It has also begun to work internationally to protect its citizens’ labor rights. For example, in September 2009, Mexican consulates attempted to educate Mexican guest workers in the United States regarding their labor rights. NAFTA leaders meet regularly, and human rights and the rule of law have become important parts of their discussions.

Thus, at their meeting in August 2009, the leaders of the three NAFTA countries discussed public health, border controls, and public safety—all issues relating to human rights.94 Linkages and Knowledge Gaps: Some Problems Presented by Current PTAs The many variants of PTAs raise questions about the linkage of trade and human rights and what it means for both the international human rights regime and the status of human rights. 1. Countries Have a Wide Range of Views about Using Trade to Advance Human Rights Abroad.

The United States, the EU, and Canada are quite comfortable using their trade agreements to advance human rights in other countries. While some developing and middleincome countries have included some human rights provisions in their PTAs, policy makers in these countries may not believe it is appropriate to intervene in the affairs of other nations, even in the most extreme cases of human rights abuse. 2. Countries Have a Wide Range of Views as to Whether They Should Accept Human Rights Provisions in Trade Agreements.

Some nations, such as Australia, have actually refused to negotiate trade agreements with human rights provisions. Yet China has accepted human rights provisions in its PTAs with Chile and New Zealand. How do we explain these differences? Some countries are comfortable using their economic power to promote political change; some countries are neutral and noninterventionist; and others may be using their acceptance of these provisions to signal investors and funders. Perhaps China sees adopting these provisions as a way to signal foreign investors that it is evenhanded and is attempting to promote the rule of law. 3. Incentives Work Better Than Disincentives to Change Behavior.

Some countries have decided to use disincentives as a means of advancing the human rights embedded in particular trade agreements. However, sanctions or fines can do little to build demand for human rights or to train governments or factory managers in how to respect human rights. Isolating a government or punishing it will do little to increase the targeted country’s commitment to human rights over time. Other countries rely on dialogue to prod changes, but dialogue may do little to encourage a country to change its behavior. Still others rely on incentives. We


Human Rights

need to understand whether these incentives are really effective and, if so, when these incentives should be offered. 4. There Is a Lot Scholars Don’t Know about This Relationship.

Scholars are just beginning to examine the relationship between human rights and trade performance.95 Aaronson and Zimmerman did a simple correlation and found that states that protect human rights signal investors that they are evenhanded and promote the rule of law (Aaronson and Zimmerman 2007, 193–95). Scholars also don’t know if human rights provisions in trade agreements lead to greater trade distortions. 5. These Provisions Have Costs as Well as Benefits.

The world and its people benefit when more governments protect, respect, and realize human rights. Yet some human rights provisions are expensive for developing countries to implement. These governments often have few resources, and yet under many recent trade agreements, they must choose to protect intellectual property, provide access to affordable medicines, and/or invest in education. Trade agreements may prod policy makers to make the human rights priorities of their trade partners their human rights priorities. We don’t know if this strategy ultimately increases the demand for and supply of human rights. To gain better understanding of the costs and benefits of the association of trade and human rights, scholars, policy makers, and activists could use qualitative studies, empirical studies, or human rights impact assessments. Scholars have several global datasets they can use to do empirical research (for example, the Cingranelli-Richards [CIRI] Human Rights Dataset or the now open World Bank datasets).96 Human rights impact assessments are relatively new; they are designed to measure the potential impact of a trade agreement on internationally accepted human rights standards. Trade and human rights policy makers should collaborate with scholars, NGOs, and others to develop a clear and consistent methodology for evaluating such impact (3D 2009; Walker 2009). Conclusions More countries are marrying trade and human rights. If this marriage is to endure, we need greater understanding as to whether this union is effective and whether it can and should endure. We can begin by doing a comprehensive study of which PTA strategies encourage policy makers to do a better job of advancing human rights and if particular trade agreements help people realize their human rights under law.

461

Notes 1. The United States has included human rights language in all its PTAs (17 in force and 3 pending), except that with Israel, as well as in its generalized system of preferences (GSP) program with 131 countries. The EU has PTAs with 14 countries, and 13 of these agreements include human rights provisions; about 120 countries are subject to human rights provisions in the EU’s GSP program. 2. United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights website, http://www.unhchr.ch/Huridocda/Huridoca.nsf/0/c462b62cf8a07b13c12 569700046704e?Opendocument. 3. See the databases at the World Trade Law website, http://www.world tradelaw.net/fta/ftadatabase/PTAs.asp; WTO, Regional Trade Agreements Information Service, http://rtais.wto.org/UI/PublicMaintainRTAHome .aspx; and, for the latest news, Bilaterals.org, http://www.bilaterals.org. 4. The two covenants and the UDHR together form the International Bill of Rights. 5. United Nations High Commissioner for Human Rights, “Fact Sheet,” http://www.unhchr.ch/html/menu6/2/fs2.htm (accessed February 12, 2006). 6. Ibid. 7. For example, if a government ignores its own labor laws, it is effectively allowing its labor-intensive firms to become more cost-competitive with imports (see GATT 1989; Bagwell and Staiger 1998; Brown 2001, 29–31). 8. Some WTO agreements require governments to accord due process rights (such as the right to recognition before the law) to importers as well as exporters. For example, under the WTO’s Safeguards Agreement, when workers or industries petition their government for import relief, the responding government must give public notice and hold hearings in which interested parties can respond to a safeguard investigation (Interpretation and Application of Article 1 of the WTO Agreement on Safeguards, http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/analytic_index_e/safeguards _02_e.htm#). The Agreement on Safeguards envisages that the interested parties will play a central role in the investigation and that they will be a primary source of information for the competent authorities. The Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade requires governments to publish standards and technical regulations and allow interested parties (whether foreign or domestic) to become acquainted and respond to the regulation (http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/analytic_index_e/tbt_01_e. htm#p). The Customs Valuation Agreement requires governments to establish in law the right of the importer to appeal a determination of customs value. Appeal may first be to a higher level in the customs administration, but the importer shall have the right in the final instance to appeal to the judiciary (Text of Interpretive Note to Article XI, http:// www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/analytic_index_e/cusval_02_e.htm #article11A). 9. Paragraph 2(a) General 319, GATT Analytical Index, http://www .wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/analytic_index_e/gatt1994_04_e.htm# articleXA. 10. Powell (2005) notes, as an example, that provisions to implement transparency are embedded in NAFTA Articles 510, 909, 1036, and 1411. 11. See World Trade Law database, http://www.worldtradelaw.net/fta/ ftadatabase/PTAs.asp; WTO Regional Trade Agreements Information System database, http://rtais.wto.org. 12. See discussion in House of Commons Committee, “Government Response to the Seventh Report of the Standing Committee on International Trade,” March 2007, 39th Parliament, 1st Session, 1–3. 13. “Speaking Notes for Honorable Jean-Pierre Blackburn, Minister of Labor and Minister of the Economic Development Agency of Canada at Montreal Council on Foreign Relations, Montreal, Quebec, February 29, 2008,” http://www.hrsdc.gc.ca/eng/corporate/newsroom/speeches/ blackburnjp/2008/080229.shtml. 14. Foreign Affairs and International Trade Canada (DFAIT), “Negotiations and Agreements,” http://www.international.gc.ca/trade-agreementsaccords-commerciaux/agr-acc/index.aspx. Canada’s four most recent PTAs


462

Susan Ariel Aaronson

are with Peru (in force as of August 1, 2009); Jordan (signed June 28, 2009, but not yet approved by Parliament); Colombia (signed November 28, 2008, but not yet approved); and EFTA (in force as of January 28, 2009). 15. DFAIT, “Negotiations and Agreements.” 16. United Nations Association in Canada (UNAC), “Canada and Human Rights,” http://www.unac.org/rights/actguide/canada.html. 17. DFAIT, “Canada’s International Human Rights Policy,” http://www.international.gc.ca/rights-droits/policy-politique.aspx. 18. The Peru, Colombia, and Jordan agreements share the same basic preamble. 19. DFAIT, “Canada-Peru Free Trade Agreement,” http://www.inter national.gc.ca/trade-agreements-accords-commerciaux/agr-acc/andeanandin/can-peru-perou.aspx?lang=en; DFAIT, “Canada-Jordan Free Trade Agreement,” http://www .international.gc.ca/trade-agreements-accordscommerciaux/agr-acc/jordan-jordanie/chapter15-chapitre15.aspx?lang= eng. 20. Canada’s approach to labor rights is discussed by Elliott, in chapter 20 of this volume; the present chapter focuses on how the labor rights side agreement addresses other important human rights. Canadian officials state that labor and environmental provisions need to be embedded in side agreements rather than in chapters because the provinces, which regulate labor, could challenge the right of the federal government to force them to adhere to a treaty in their areas of jurisdiction. The side agreements allow for voluntary adherence by the provinces. This arrangement respects provincial jurisdiction on labor matters but gives Canada the ability to immediately access the dispute resolution process, regardless of the level of provincial participation in the labor cooperation agreement. 21. Human Resources and Skill Development Canada, “International Labour Affairs,” http://www.hrsdc.gc.ca/eng/lp/ila/index.shtml/. 22. See the 32-page “Agreement on Labour Cooperation” between Canada and Colombia, http://www.hrsdc.gc.ca/eng/labour/labour_agree ments/ccalc/Canada-Colombia_LCA.pdf. 23. DFAIT, “Canada-Peru Free Trade Agreement, Chapter 19, Transparency,” http://www.international.gc.ca/trade-agreements-accords-comm erciaux/agr-acc/peru-perou/peru-toc-perou-tdm.aspx?lang=eng. 24. DFAIT, “Canada-Colombia Free Trade Agreement, Chapter 19, Transparency,” http://www.international.gc.ca/trade-agreements-accordscommerciaux/assets/pdfs/EN%2019%20Colombia%20FTA%20-%20Trans parency.pdf. 25. Media Awareness Network, “Canada’s Cultural Policies,” http://www.media-awareness.ca/english/issues/cultural_policies/canada_ cultural_policies.cfm; DFAIT, “Culture,” http://www.international.gc.ca/ trade-agreements-accords-commerciaux/fo/index.aspx?lang=en. 26. For Colombia, http://www.ec.gc.ca/caraib-carib/default.asp? lang=En&n=F24F07DD-1; for Peru, http://www.ec.gc.ca/caraib-carib/ default.asp?lang=En&xml=5CBDDB77-6054-4FD3-A348-125840CEDF29. 27. Human Rights Impact Resource Center, http://www.humanrightsimpact.org/news/newsitem/article/roundtable-on-human-rights-impactassessments-in-canada-on-16-november-178/?tx_ttnews[backPid]=769& cHash=0a3f7f441d60fbea25cc641a768a1a1c; Canadian Labour Congress, http://www.canadianlabour.ca/news-room/publications/canada-colombiafree-trade-agreement-round-two-0. 28. Hearing on Canada–South America Trade Relations, 40th Parliament, 2nd session, Standing Committee on International Trade, June 16, 2009, http://www2.parl.gc.ca/HousePublications/Publication.aspx?DocId= 4000400&Language=E&Mode=1&Parl=40&Ses=2. 29. International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD), “Canada–Colombia FTA Gets Human Rights Amendment,” http://ictsd.org/i/news/bridgesweekly/73372/. 30. DFAIT, “Canada–European Union Joint Report: Towards a Comprehensive Economic Agreement,” http://www.international.gc.ca/trade-agree ments-accords-commerciaux/agr-acc/eu-ue/can-eu-report-can-ue-rapport. aspx?lang=eng. 31. EFTA, “Free Trade Agreements,” http://www.efta.int/free-trade/ free-trade-agreements.aspx.

32. See, for example, EFTA–Colombia, http://www.efta.int/free-trade/ free-trade-agreements/colombia/fta-en.aspx; for Chile, http://www.efta .int/free-trade/free-trade-agreements/chile/fta.aspx, Article XXI. 33. World Trade Law, “Free Trade Agreement between the EFTA States and the SACU States,” http://www.worldtradelaw.net/fta/agree ments/SACU_EFTA_FTA.pdf. 34. Ibid., Article 30. 35. Committee of Members of Parliament of the EFTA Countries, “Environmental Policies and Labor Standards in PTAs,” August 24, 2009, Brussels. 36. Committee of Members of Parliament of the EFTA Countries, “Environmental Policies and Labor Standards in PTAs,” Ref. 1090382, March 18, 2009, Brussels, 3–4. 37. EFTA, http://www.efta.int/eea/eea-agreement.aspx, 5–6. 38. European Commission, Employment, Social Affairs, and Inclusion, “Free Movement of Workers,” http://ec.europa.eu/social/main.jsp? catId=458&langId=en; “Equal Treatment,” http://ec.europa.eu/social/ main.jsp?catId=462&langId=en. 39. The European Community was founded as the European Economic Community on March 25, 1957; in 1993 it was renamed the European Union. 40. European Commission, Trade, “FTA Negotiations,” http://trade.ec .europa.eu/doclib/docs/2006/december/tradoc_118238.pdf; Aaronson and Zimmerman (2007, 139). 41. European Union, “Partnership and Cooperation Agreements (PCAs),” http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/external_relations/rela tions_with_third_countries/eastern_europe_and_central_asia/r17002_en .htm. 42. Bartels and other analysts have noted that Australia refused to accept a human rights clause in its trade agreement, and thus, the EU and Australia were unable to negotiate a PTA. 43. European Union, “EC Regional Trade Agreements,” http:// trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2006/december/tradoc_111588.pdf. 44. European Commission, “The Cotonou Agreement,” http://ec .europa.eu/development/geographical/cotonouintro_en.cfm; European Commission, Trade, “Economic Partnerships,” http://ec.europa.eu/trade/ wider-agenda/development/economic-partnerships/. 45. EU, “Economic Partnerships.” 46. European Commission, “An Overview of the Interim Agreements,” http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2009/january/tradoc_142188 .pdf; and, according to http://www.bilaterals.org, as of 2009:

EU–ACP subgroup Caribbean

Central Africa West Africa

East Africa

Status of agreement • Full EPA initialed in December 2007 and signed in October 2008 (but not by Haiti) and approved by the European Parliament (March 2009). • Interim EPA initialed (December 2007) and signed by Cameroon only (January 2009). • Seven countries have not initialed anything yet. • Interim EPA initialed (December 2007) and signed by Côte d’Ivoire (November 2008) and approved by the European Parliament (March 2009). • Interim EPA initialed by Ghana (December 2007). • Fourteen countries have not initialed anything yet. • Interim EPA initialed by Zimbabwe, the Seychelles, Mauritius, the Comoros, Madagascar, and Zambia (November–December 2007) and signed by Zimbabwe, the Seychelles, Mauritius, and Madagascar only (August 2009). • Interim EPA initialed by East African Community members Burundi, Kenya, Rwanda, Tanzania, and Uganda (November 2007). • Five countries have not initialed anything yet.


Human Rights

Southern Africa

Pacific

• Interim EPA initialed by Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia, Swaziland, and Mozambique (November–December 2007) and signed by Botswana, Lesotho, Swaziland, and Mozambique only (June 2009). • Angola has not initialed anything yet. • Interim EPA initialed by Papua New Guinea and Fiji (November 2007) and signed by Papua New Guinea only (July 2009). • Thirteen countries have not initialed anything yet.

47. TradeMark Southern Africa, http://www.trademarksa.org/node/ 485; http://ictsd.org/i/news/tni/57509/; Forbes.com, “Africa–E.U. Economic Agreement Stalls,” http://www.forbes.com/2010/08/11/eu-africaepa-business-oxford-analytica.html. 48. European Commission, Official Journal of the European Community, “Economic Partnership Agreement between the CARIFORUM States, of the One Part, and the European Community and Its Member States, of the Other Part,” http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2008/ february/tradoc_137971.pdf. 49. The EPAs can be examined at http://www.bilaterals.org/spip.php? rubrique17. 50. Ibid. Canada has similar provisions. 51. European Commission, Trade, “European Competitiveness,” http://ec.europa.eu/trade/creating-opportunities/trade-topics/europeancompetitiveness/index_en.htm; European Commission, “Global Europe: Competing in the World,” http://ec.europa.eu/trade/creating-oppor tunities/trade-topics/european-competitiveness/global-europe/. 52. European Commission, Trade, “Overview of FTA and Other Trade Negotiations,” updated March 3, 2011, http://trade.ec.europa.eu/ doclib/docs/2006/december/tradoc_118238.pdf. 53. European Commission, Trade, “Overview of FTA and Other Trade Negotiations.” 54. European Commission, “Free Trade Agreement between the European Community and Its Member States, of the One Part, and the Republic of Korea, of the Other Part,” http://trade.ec.europa.eu/ doclib/docs/2009/october/tradoc_145139.pdf. 55. On transparency, European Commission, Trade, http://trade.ec .europa.eu/doclib/docs/2009/october/tradoc_145184.pdf; on the cultural protocol, http://trade.ec.europa.eu/doclib/docs/2009/october/tradoc_ 145194.pdf. 56. Much of the text that follows is from Aaronson and Zimmerman (2007, 139–47). 57. European Commission, Trade, “Sustainability Impact Assessments,” http://ec.europa.eu/trade/analysis/sustainability-impact-assessments/. 58. Human Rights Watch, Christian Solidarity Worldwide, and International Crisis Group, “No Trade Agreement for Turkmenistan-Joint Letter,” March 20, 2006, http://hrw.org/english/docs/2006/03/20/turkme1 3040.htm (accessed April 24, 2006). 59. EU, “Human Rights and Democracy in the World: Report on EU Action July 2008 to December 2009,” 2010, http://www.eeas.europa .eu/_human_rights/docs/2010_hr_report_en.pdf. 60. European Commission, Communication from the European Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, “The European Union’s Role in Promoting Human Rights and Democratisation in Third Countries,” COM(2001)252 final, May 8, 2001, Brussels. 61. For two views of “competitive liberalization,” see Evenett and Meier (2008) and Aaronson (2002). 62. USTR (2011); for Colombia, http://www.ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements/colombia-fta; for Korea, http://www.ustr .gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements/korus-fta; for Panama, http:// www.ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements/panama-tpa. 63. Public Law 107-210, August 6, 2002, Section 2102 (a) Trade Negotiating Objectives of the Bipartisan Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2002; USTR 2009.

463

64. “The President’s 2011 Trade Policy Agenda,” http://www.ustr.gov/ webfm_send/2587. 65. USTR, “Trade Policy: A Level Playing Field for America’s Workers,” July 16, 2009, http://www.ustr.gov/about-us/press-office/fact-sheets/ 2009/july/trade-policy-level-playing-field-american-workers. 66. USTR, “Guatemala Submission under CAFTA-DR,” http:// www.ustr.gov/trade-topics/labor/bilateral-and-regional-trade-agreements/ guatemala-submission-under-cafta-dr; USTR, “USTR Kirk Addresses Workers in Pennsylvania on Obama Administration Enforcement of U.S. Trade Agreements,” http://www.ustr.gov/node/6046, 4; USTR, “The 2010 National Trade Estimate Report: Key Elements,” http://www.ustr .gov/ about-us/press-office/fact-sheets/2010/march/-2010-national-trade-estimatereport-key-elements. 67. Transparent, accountable governance can foster democracy, capitalism, and political stability. Thus, by promoting transparency, the rule of law, and political participation, policy makers can promote many human rights. See UNDP (2002), 2–4. 68. Bipartisan Trade Promotion Authority Act, Section 2102 (b) (5), (8). 69. Ibid., Section 2102 (b) 6 (A). 70. U.S. communication on Article X of GATT 1994, G/C/W/384, June 7, 2002; Robert B. Zoellick, “Free Trade and the Hemispheric Hope,” Council of the Americas meeting, May 7, 2001, http://ctrc.sice.oas .org/geograph/westernh/zoellick_3.pdf. 71. For example, Chapter 20 of the Australia–U.S. FTA, http://www.dfat.gov.au/trade/negotiations/us_fta/final-text/chapter_20 .html; Chapter 17 of the U.S.–Bahrain FTA; Section 19 of the Peru FTA, www.ustr.gov/Trade_Agreements/Bilateral. 72. Commission for Economic Cooperation of North America, “A Guide to Articles 14 and 15,” http://www.cec.org/Page.asp?PageID=122& ContentID=1388&SiteNodeID=210. 73. According to President Bush, “open trade . . . spurs the process of economic and legal reform. And open trade reinforces the habits of liberty that sustain democracy over the long term.” Quoted in testimony by USTR Robert Zoellick to the Senate Finance Committee, “America’s Trade Policy Agenda,” March 5, 2003. 74. Robert B. Zoellick, “Global Trade and the Middle East: Reawakening a Vibrant Past,” World Economic Forum, Jordan, June 23, 2003; statement by Peter F. Algeier, Acting U.S. Trade Representative, before the Senate Finance Committee, April 13, 2005, 6–8. On Central America, see Robert B. Zoellick, “A Free Trade Boost for Our Hemisphere,” Wall Street Journal, November 17, 2003; Zoellick, “The Route From Miami to Economic Freedom,” Financial Times, December 9, 2003. 75. Interview with Mark Linscott, Assistant USTR for the Environment, and Jennifer Prescott, Deputy Assistant USTR for the Environment, August 1, 2006. 76. See Article 19.3 and 19.4 of the U.S.–Chile FTA, http://www .ustr.gov/Trade_Agreements/Bilateral/Chile_FTA/Final_Texts/Section_ Index.html. 77. Part of the agreement’s work program is to build capacity to promote public participation in environmental decision making. The agreement was negotiated by the Department of State; see Environmental Cooperation Agreement, February 1, 2005, http://www.state.gov/g/oes/ env/trade/caftacooperation/142688.htm. Also see “U.S., Central America, Dominican Republic Sign Environment Pacts,” U.S. Department of State, http://www.america.gov/st/washfile-english/2005/February/20050218133 452GLnesnoM0.3828546.html. The Environmental Affairs Council met for the first time on May 24, 2006. 78. On dispute settlement, see CAFTA-DR, Article 10.20. 3; “Communiqué of the Environmental Affairs Council of the Dominican Republic–Central America–United States Free Trade Agreement,” May 24, 2006, http://www.worldtradelaw.net/fta/agreements/CAFTADR_RelDoc_ CommEnvAff.pdf . 79. Interview with Mark Linscott and Jennifer Prescott, Office of the USTR, August 2, 2006. For the Peru agreement, see http://www.ustr .gov/trade_agreements/bilateral/; for the draft Colombia FTA, see


464

Susan Ariel Aaronson

http://www.ustr.gov/Trade_Agreements/Bilateral/Colombia_FTA/Draft _Text/Section_Index.html. 80. Chapter 19, Labor, in the Korea, Panama, Peru, and Colombia FTAs. See, for example, Chapter 19 in the U.S.–Korea FTA, http://www .ustr.gov/sites/default/files/uploads/agreements/fta/korus/asset_upload_ file934_12718.pdf; Article 20, http://www.ustr.gov/sites/default/files/ uploads/agreements/fta/korus/asset_upload_file852_12719.pdf. 81. USTR (2011, 149–51). “As part of increased engagement in 2010, Labor Affairs Council and labor subcommittee meetings, as provided for under the FTAs, were held with several FTA partners, including first-time meetings with Peru, Morocco, and Bahrain. (For additional information, see Chapter III.A).” 82. “House Chairmen Warn USTR against Patent Changes in Doha Round,” Inside U.S. Trade (April 14, 2006), 7. 83. Press release, “Commerce Secretary Carlos Gutierrez Unveils Initiatives to Fight Intellectual Property Theft,” September 21, 2005, http://www.commerce.gov/opa/press/Secretary_Gutierrez/2005_Releases /September/09-21-05%20IPR%20initiatives.htm. Keyder (2005) has an interesting scholarly take on this issue. 84. Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2002, Section 2102, (4) (A) (B) (C). 85. See, for example, “Understandings Regarding Certain Public Health Measures,” Colombia, http://www.ustr.gov/Trade_Agreements/ Bilateral/Colombia_FTA/Draft_Text/Section_Index.html (accessed August 7, 2006). 86. Basically, free movement of skills entails the right to seek employment in any member state and the elimination of the need for work permits and permits of stay. See CARICOM, http://www.caricom.org/jsp/sin gle_market/skill.jsp?menu=csme. 87. COMESA’s Integration Agenda also rests on the belief that the consolidation of democracy and the rule of law are the foundation stones for regional socioeconomic development and political stability. 88. Mercosur is incorporated into the Latin America Integration Association/Asociación Latinoamericana de Integración (LAIA/ALADI) legal regime, as Economic Complementarity Agreement 18. These agreements are open to accession by any LAIA/ALADI country. 89. See “Treaty Establishing a Common Market,” March 26, 1991, UN Doc. A/46/155 (1991), reprinted in 30 I.L.M. 1041 (1991). 90. For the full text of the Brazilian delegation’s speech, see http://www.un.int/brazil/speech/00d-mercosul-human-rights-2610.htm. 91. Memorandum of Understanding, http://www.sice.oas.org/Trade/ CHL_CHN/CHL_CHN_e/Labor_e.asp. 92. The English version of the draft report is available at http://www .measwatch.org/autopage/show_page.php?t=5&s_id=3&d_id=7. 93. MCOT News, “PM Calls for More Public Participation in FTA Deals,” http://www.bilaterals.org/article.php3?id_article=953&var_ recherche=public+information (accessed August 3, 2006). Meanwhile, the EPA is reviewing its public participation efforts. 94. USTR, “Joint Statement of the 2009 NAFTA Commission Meeting,” http://www.ustr.gov/about-us/press-office/press-releases/2009/ october/joint-statement-2009-nafta-commission-meeting. 95. In a widely cited, albeit out-of-date, study, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) examined the relationship between freedom of association and trade and investment patterns and found that, the more successful is trade reform, the greater is respect for association rights. The authors concluded that freer trade does not lead industrialized countries to lower their standards, and higher standards do not jeopardize trade reforms (OECD 1996, 9, 105). 96. http://ciri.binghamton.edu/; http://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/ EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/0,,contentMDK:20388241~menuPK: 665266~pagePK:64165401~piPK:64165026~theSitePK:469382,00.html.

Selected Bibliography Aaronson, Susan Ariel. 2002. “George W. Bush: Protectionist.” International Economy 16: 54–56.

———. 2007. “Seeping in Slowly: How Human Rights Concerns Are Penetrating the WTO.” World Trade Review 6 (3): 413–49. Aaronson, Susan Ariel, and Rod Abouharb. Forthcoming. “Strange Bedfellows: The WTO and Democratic Rights.” International Studies Quarterly. Aaronson, Susan Ariel, and Jamie M. Zimmerman. 2007. Trade Imbalance: The Struggle to Weigh Human Rights in Trade Policymaking. New York: Cambridge University Press. Bagwell, Kyle, and Robert W. Staiger. 1998. “The Simple Economics of Labor Standards and the GATT.” NBER Working Paper 6604, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. http://www.nber.org/ papers/w6604. Bal, Salman. 2001. “International Free Trade Agreements and Human Rights: Reinterpreting Article XX of the GATT.” Minnesota Journal of International Trade 10 (62): 62–108. Bartels, Lorand. 2005a. “Human Rights and Democracy Clauses in the EU’s International Agreements.” Prepared for the Subcommittee on Human Rights, Committee on Foreign Affairs, European Parliament, EP/EXPOL/B/2005/, Brussels. ———. 2005b. Human Rights Conditionality in the EU’s International Agreements. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. ———. 2008. “The Application of Human Rights Conditionality in the EU’s Bilateral Trade Agreements and Other Trade Arrangements with Third Countries.” Report for the European Parliament, Brussels. ———. 2009a. “Social Issues: Labour, Environment and Human Rights.” In Bilateral and Regional Trade Agreements: Commentary and Analysis, ed. Simon Lester and Bryan Mercurio, 340–66. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. ———. 2009b. “Trade and Human Rights.” In Oxford Handbook of International Trade Law, ed. D. Bethlehem et al., 571–96. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Bartels, Lorand, and Federico Ortino. 2006. Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO Legal System. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Barton, John H. 2006. The Evolution of the Trade Regime: Politics, Law, and Economics of the GATT and the WTO. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Bhagwati, Jagdish. 1996. “Introduction.” In Economic Analysis. Vol. 1 of Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade? ed. Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert Hudec. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Bidwell, Percy. 1939. The Invisible Tariff: A Study of the Control of Imports into the United States. New York: Council on Foreign Relations. Bolle, Mary Jane. 2009. “Proposed Colombia Free Trade Agreement: Labor Issues.” Report RL34759, Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress, Washington, DC. http://88.80.13.160/leak/crs/ RL34759.pdf. Bourgeois, Jacques, Kamala Dawar, and Simon J. Evenett. 2007. “A Comparative Analysis of Selected Provisions in Free Trade Agreements.” Prepared for the Directorate General for Trade, European Union, Brussels. Brown, Drusilla K. 2001. “Labor Standards: Where Do They Belong on the International Trade Agenda?” Working Paper, Department of Economics, Tufts University, Medford, MA. http://ase.tufts.edu/econ/ papers/200113.pdf. Büthe, Tim, and Helen V. Milner. 2008. “The Politics of Foreign Direct Investment into Developing Countries: Increasing FDI through International Trade Agreements?” American Journal of Political Science 52 (4, October): 741–62. CCIC (Canadian Council for International Co-operation), Americas Policy Group. 2009. “What Role for Canada in the Americas?” CCIC, Ottawa. http://www.ccic.ca/_files/en/working_groups/003_apg_200904-15_statement_what_role_for_cda_in_americas.pdf. CEA (Council of Economic Advisors). 2005. Economic Report of the President, 2005. Washington, DC: CEA. Charnovitz, Steve. 1987. “The Influence of International Labor Standards on the World Trading Regime: A Historical Overview.” International Labour Review 126 (5): 565–84.


Human Rights

———. 1994. “The World Trade Organization and Social Issues.” Journal of World Trade 28 (5, October): 17–33. ———. 1998. “The Moral Exception in Trade Policy.” Virginia Journal of International Law 38 (4, Summer): 689–745. http://www.worldtradelaw.net/articles/charnovitzmoral.pdf. ———. 2001. “The WTO and the Rights of the Individual.” Intereconomics 36 (2, March): 98–108. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=282021. ———. 2005. “The Labor Dimension of the Emerging Free Trade Area of the Americas.” GWU Law School Public Law and Legal Theory Paper 140, George Washington University, Washington, DC. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=705301. Cherfane, Carol Couchani. 2006. “Trade and Environment DecisionMaking in the Arab Region.” United National Economic and Social Commission for Western Asia, Muscat, Oman. http://css.escwa.org.lb/ 25mar06/14.pdf. Commission on Human Rights. 2004. “Economic, Social and Cultural Rights: On Human Rights Resolution 2003/25.” E/CN.4/2004/10, United Nations, New York. Compa, Lance A., and Stephen F. Diamond, eds. 1996. Human Rights, Labor Rights, and International Trade. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press. Cottier, Thomas, Joost Pauwelyn, and Elizabeth Bürgi, eds. 2005. Human Rights and International Trade. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Cox, Phyllida, Peter Newell, Tracy Tuplin, and Diana Tussie. 2006. “Civil Society Participation in Trade Policy-Making in Latin America: Reflections and Lessons.” IDS Working Paper 267, Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex, Brighton, U.K. http://www.iadb .org/intal/intalcdi/PE/2009/02463.pdf. Damro, Chad. 2006. “The Political Economy of Regional Trade Agreements.” In Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO Legal System, ed. Lorand Bartels and Federico Ortino. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Dawar, Kamala. 2008. “Assessing Labour and Environmental Regimes in Regional Trading Arrangements.” University of Amsterdam Law School, Amsterdam, Netherlands. Diebold, William. 1952. “The End of the I.T.O.” Essays in International Finance 16: 1–37. Dobbin, Frank, Beth Simmons, and Geoffrey Garrett. 2007. “The Global Diffusion of Public Policies: Social Construction, Coercion, Competition, or Learning?” Annual Review of Sociology 33: 449–72. Dommen, Caroline. 2002. “Raising Human Rights Concerns in the World Trade Organization: Actors, Processes and Possible Strategies.” Human Rights Quarterly 24 (1, February): 1–50. Drahos, Peter, and Ruth Mayne. 2002. Global Intellectual Property Rights: Knowledge, Access and Development. London: Macmillan. Dunoff, Jeffrey L. 1999. “Does Globalization Advance Human Rights?” Brooklyn Journal of International Law 25 (1). Evenett, Simon J., and Michael Meier. 2008. “An Interim Assessment of U.S. Trade Policy of Competitive Liberalization.” World Economy 31 (1): 31–66, Ferrantino, Michael. 2006. “Policy Anchors: Do Free Trade Agreements and WTO Accessions Serve as Vehicles for Developing-Country Policy Reform?” U.S. International Trade Commission, Washington, DC. SSRN: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=895272. Florentine, Robert V., Luis Verdeja, and Christelle Toqueboeuf. 2007. “The Changing Landscape of Regional Trade Agreements: 2006 Update.” WTO Discussion Paper 12, World Trade Organization, Geneva. Garcia, Frank. 1999. “The Global Market and Human Rights: Trading Away the Human Rights Principle.” Brooklyn Journal of International Law 25: 51–97. ———. 2003. “Integrating Trade and Human Rights in the Americas.” Research Paper 26, Boston College of Law, Boston, MA. SSRN: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=470201. GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade), Negotiating Group on Dispute Settlement. 1989. “Non-Violation Complaints under GATT Article XXIII: 2.” Note by the Secretariat, MTN.GNG/

465

NG13/W/31, GATT, Geneva. http://www.worldtradelaw.net/history/ urdsu/w31.pdf. Hafner-Burton, Emilie M. 2009. Forced to Be Good: Why Trade Agreements Boost Human Rights. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Hamilton, Carl B. 2002. “Globalization and Democracy.” CEPR Discussion Paper 3653, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London. Harrison, James. 2009. “Conducting a Human Rights Impact Assessment of the Canada–Colombia Free Trade Agreement, Key Issues.” Americas Policy Group, Canadian Council for International Co-operation, Ottawa. http://www.ccic.ca/_files/en/working_groups/003_apg_200902_hr_assess_of_cfta.pdf. Horn, Henrik, Petros C. Mavroidis, and André Sapir. 2010. “Beyond the WTO? An Anatomy of EU and US Preferential Trade Agreements.” World Economy 33 (11): 1565–88. Howse, Robert. 2002. “Human Rights in the WTO: Whose Rights, What Humanity? Comment on Petersmann.” European Journal of International Law 13 (3): 651–59. Keyder, Virginia Brown. 2005. “From Information to Property and Back Again.” Information and Communications Technology Law 14 (3, October): 299–312. Lester, Simon, and Bryan Mercurio. 2009. Bilateral and Regional Trade Agreements: Commentary and Analysis. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Lim, Hoe. 2001. “Trade and Human Rights: What’s at Issue?” E/C 12/2001/WP.2, United Nations Economic and Social Council, New York. http://www.unhchr.ch/tbs/doc.nsf/0/907f88e4d28e4cb9c1256a 63003069fd?Opendocument. Lombardt, Ivin. 2008. “Role and Influence of Civil Society in Malawi’s Trade Policy Making Process: The Case of the Malawi Economic Justice Network.” One World Action, London. http://www.oneworldaction .org/OneStopCMS/Core/CrawlerResourceServer.aspx?resource=2BAA 53AE-4BEF-44CD-9CD0-B5679F7411C4&mode=link&guid=bd9097b 13c2f433e891e779111c14bc3. Mansfield, Edward D., and Jon C. Pevehouse. 2008. “Democratization and the Varieties of International Organizations.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 52 (2, April): 269–94. Marceau, Gabrielle. 2001. “WTO Dispute Settlement and Human Rights.” Prepared for the joint meeting of the American Society of International Law and the World Trade Forum on “International Economic Law and Human Rights.” Mehra, Malini, ed. 1999. Human Rights and Economic Globalisation: Directions for the WTO. London: Global Publications Foundation and International NGO Committee on Human Rights in Trade and Investment. Mercurio, Bryan. 2006. “TRIPS-Plus Provisions in RTAs: Recent Trends.” In Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO Legal System. ed. Lorand Bartels and Federico Ortino. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Morales-Moreno, Isidro. 2005. “Mexico’s Agricultural Trade Policies: International Commitments and Domestic Pressure.” In Managing the Challenges of WTO Participation: 45 Case Studies, ed. Peter Gallagher, Patrick Low, and Andrew L. Stoler. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/case studies_e/case28_e.htm. Nickel, James. 2006. “Human Rights.” In Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy: Fall 2006 Edition, Stanford University, Stanford, CA. http://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2006/entries/rights-human/. OECD (Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development), 1996. “Trade Employment and Labor Standards: A Study of Core Workers’ Rights and International Trade.” OECD, Paris. Petersmann, Ernest-Ulrich. 2000. “The WTO Constitution and Human Rights.” Journal of International Economic Law 3 (1): 19–25. ———. 2001. “Human Rights and International Economic Law in the 21st Century: The Need to Clarify Their Interrelationship.” Journal of International Economic Law 4 (1, March): 3–39.


466

Susan Ariel Aaronson

———. 2002. “Time for a United Nations ‘Global Compact’ for Integrating Human Rights into the Law of Worldwide Organizations: Lessons from European Integration.” European Journal of International Law 13 (3): 621–50. ———. 2006. “The WTO and Regional Trade Agreements as Competing Fora for Constitutional Reforms: Trade and Human Rights.” In Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO Legal System, ed. Lorand Bartels and Federico Ortino, 281–312. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Powell, Stephen J. 2005. “Regional Economic Arrangements and the Rule of Law in the Americas: The Human Rights Face of Free Trade Agreements.” Florida Journal of International Law 17 (1): 59–100. SSRN: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1115298. Silvan, Laura. 2004. “10 Years of NAFTA’s Commission on Environmental Cooperation in Mexico: Resolving Environmental Problems and Fostering Citizen Participation.” IRC Strategic Dialogue 1, International Relations Center, Silver City, NM. Smith, Carolyn C. 2006. “Trade Promotion Authority and Fast-Track Negotiating Authority for Trade Agreements: Major Votes.” Report RS21004, Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress, Washington, DC. http://fpc.state.gov/documents/organization/73937.pdf. Sykes, Alan O’Neil. 2003. “International Trade and Human Rights: An Economic Perspective.” John M. Olin Law and Economics Working Paper 188, Law School, University of Chicago, Chicago, IL. SSRN: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=415802. Thomas, Melissa. n.d. “The Rule of Law in Western Thought.” World Bank Rule of Law and Development website, World Bank, Washington, DC. http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/EXTLAWJUSTINST/0,,contentMDK:20763590~menuPK:1989584~pageP K:210058~piPK:210062~theSitePK:1974062,00.html. 3D. 2005. “Planting the Rights Seed: A Human Rights Perspective on Agriculture Trade and the WTO.” Backgrounder 1, 3/2005, 4, 3D, Geneva. ———. 2009. “Insights on Human Rights Impact Assessments of Trade Policies and Agreements.” 3D, Geneva. http://www.3dthree.org/ pdf_3D/HRIAsbackgroundinformation.pdf. Trebilcock, Michael J. 2001. “Trade Policy and Labour Standards: Objectives, Instruments and Institutions.” Law and Economics Research

Paper 02-01, University of Toronto Faculty of Law, Toronto, Canada. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=307219. UNDP (United Nations Development Programme). 2002. Human Development Report: Deepening Democracy in a Fragmented World. New York: UNDP. http://hdr.undp.org/reports/global/2002/en/. U.S. Congress. 2002. Bipartisan Trade Promotion Authority Act of 2002. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. http://www.law.cor nell.edu/uscode/html/uscode19/usc_sup_01_19_10_24.html. U.S. GAO (General Accountability Office). 2009. “Four Free Trade Agreements GAO Reviewed Have Resulted in Commercial Benefits, but Challenges on Labor and Environment Remain.” Highlights of GAO09-439 (July), GAO, Washington, DC. USTR (Office of the U.S. Trade Representative). 2005. “Participation, Empowerment, Partnership: Seeking Sustainable Results through US Trade Capacity Building.” USTR, Washington, DC. ———. 2009. “The President’s Trade Policy Agenda and 2008 Trade Agreements Report.” USTR, Washington, DC. http://www.ustr.gov/ about-us/press-office/reports-and-publications/2009/2009-tradepolicy-agenda-and-2008-annual-report. ———. 2011. “2011 Trade Policy Agenda and 2010 Annual Report of the President of the United States on the Trade Agreements Program.” USTR, Washington, DC. http://www.ustr.gov/webfm_send/2597. van Hees, Floris. 2004. “Protection v. Protectionism: The Use of Human Rights Arguments in the Debate for and against the Liberalization of Trade.” Åbo Akademi University, Turku, Finland. http://web.abo.fi/ instut/imr/norfa/floris.pdf. Walker, Simon. 2009. The Future of Human Rights Impacts Assessments of Trade Agreements. Mortsel, Belgium: Intersentia. WHO (World Health Organization). 2006. “Public Health, Innovation and Intellectual Property.” Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, Innovation and Public Health, WHO, Geneva. http://www.who .int/intellectualproperty/report/en/. Wilcox, C. 1949. A Charter for World Trade. New York: Macmillan. WTO (World Trade Organization). 2001. “Trade and Labour Standards: A Difficult Issue for Many WTO Member Governments.” DOHA Ministerial 2001, Briefing Notes, WTO, Geneva. http://www.wto.org/eng lish/thewto_e/minist_e/min01_e/brief_e/brief16_e.htm.


22 Dispute Settlement Amelia Porges

The past 15 or so years have seen the emergence and elaboration of ever more complex preferential trade agreements (PTAs), forming multiple and rapidly proliferating networks. Almost all of these PTAs include a dispute settlement clause of some sort. Indeed, dispute settlement provisions have become a sine qua non for PTA negotiators, even though the number of actual government-government disputes within PTAs is only a fraction of the hundreds of existing agreements. Governments enter into PTAs expecting to secure economic benefits. In particular, estimates of the welfare benefits of PTAs normally assume that the parties will faithfully implement their market access commitments. If private investors doubt that the partners to a PTA will actually keep their commitments, they will not engage in the type of risk-taking investment that the PTA could otherwise generate. If a PTA is to be fully implemented and to yield the expected benefits, the agreement should, at a minimum, be equipped with institutions that facilitate information exchange among the parties, help the parties monitor implementation, and provide an incentive structure that meaningfully supports compliance. A dispute settlement arrangement is part of this necessary structure because there will inevitably be disagreements in a PTA concerning the scope and nature of the commitments that the parties have made. The PTA must provide an orderly way for its members to settle disputes and move on, or else the disputes will poison bilateral relations, reduce the PTA’s benefit, and perhaps even lead to the demise of the agreement. Dispute settlement mechanisms are also needed to ensure that the promises in a PTA are kept. Economic studies on PTAs teach that where the parties’ tariffs are low ex ante, a PTA between them will only produce gains if it involves deep integration provisions. Those provisions need to be backed up by enforcement. Every economic projection of the gains from a PTA is based on the assumption

of 100 percent compliance with the PTA’s obligations. Ensuring compliance through enforcement is essential if the gains are to materialize. PTAs therefore typically include some mechanism incorporating elements of both compliance enforcement and dispute settlement. By participating in a PTA with strong dispute settlement provisions, a government signals its level of commitment to private and public interests at home and abroad. Each PTA competes with other PTAs for investment, jobs, and economic growth, in a field that becomes more crowded every year. Even if no disputes are anticipated, enforcement provisions in a PTA reinforce the precommitment of the governments, make their promises more credible, and signal that the PTA is a solid platform for investment that will create jobs and economic growth. Solid dispute settlement is even more important in North-South (or South-South) PTAs with asymmetrical power relations. Recently concluded PTAs in Latin America, Europe, and Asia demonstrate to a striking extent that as PTA obligations deepen, become more complex, and provide more value, PTA partners seek more certainty than purely diplomatic dispute settlement can provide. In theory, the parties to a PTA are the masters of their own treaty and could design an original dispute settlement mechanism from the ground up, or have no dispute settlement mechanism at all. In practice, almost all PTAs rely on one of the three general types of dispute settlement mechanisms: diplomatic settlement by negotiation; judgments by standing tribunals; or the World Trade Organization (WTO) model, in which an ad hoc panel is convened to hear the dispute. Many recent PTAs have adopted the third system, based on the WTO’s Dispute Settlement Understanding (DSU). The WTO model has provided a useful focal point for bargaining; its familiarity means that negotiators and stakeholders understand how it works and what trade-offs can be made. This chapter, the last in the volume, discusses the options available for dispute settlement and enforcement 467


468

Amelia Porges

provisions in PTAs. Following a brief literature review, we outline the three models of dispute settlement in PTAs, discuss their scope and exclusions, and compare them from the standpoint of development, infrastructure cost, and open regionalism. We then examine how PTAs define the scope of disputes that they will deal with, their handling of overlap and forum choice between the PTA and WTO dispute settlement systems, and various procedural and institutional issues. Subsequent sections describe alternative dispute resolution procedures and examine compliance procedures and enforcement issues and decisions. The final sections explore the reasons for the limited use of PTA dispute settlement procedures to date and present the conclusions and recommendations that emerge from the study.

Kwak and Marceau (2006) present an updated crossregional summary of PTA dispute settlement provisions and conclude that there is a real possibility of overlaps or conflicts of jurisdiction between the WTO and PTA dispute settlement mechanisms. They outline in tabular form the dispute settlement provisions of the main PTAs in all regions, with attention to issues that affect such overlaps or conflicts. Morgan (2008) confirms the trend toward greater legalism in PTA dispute settlement but argues that the absence of effective enforcement mechanisms forces the parties to find negotiated solutions. He points out that even within the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), Canada opted for a negotiated settlement to its long-running softwood lumber dispute with the United States, after a series of rulings in NAFTA and the WTO.

Literature on PTA Dispute Settlement

European Union (EU) PTAs

The surge in the number of PTAs is a rather recent phenomenon. As yet, few cross-regional comparative surveys of PTA dispute settlement have been published, and those that do exist focus on the dispute settlement mechanisms in particular PTA agreements, regions, or networks rather than on the application of the mechanisms. The reason is that the number of cases of government-to-government PTA disputes that can be examined is still small.

Garcia Bercero (2006), a negotiator for the European Commission, surveys the development of the Commission’s thinking on dispute settlement in trade agreements, starting with the traditional diplomatic approach seen in the EU’s association agreements and other agreements before 2000, and discusses why the Commission’s preferences have shifted toward ad hoc arbitration procedures in the free trade agreements (FTAs) with Mexico and Chile. In studies of earlier EU PTAs, Ramirez Robles (2006) finds that the political model of dispute settlement has been the dominant model for EU association agreements, and Broude (2007) surveys the disputes brought under these earlier PTAs. Broude argues that the dispute settlement provisions of most EU PTAs contribute to EU regional hegemony by encouraging and perpetuating nonjudicialized bilateral dispute settlement, where the EU has advantages. He points out that EU PTA partners do not even use the WTO system for settlement of their own disputes and do not have the real option of recourse to judicial dispute settlement procedures in their relations with the EU.

General Surveys The most significant recent general survey, by Donaldson and Lester (2009), concentrates on a sample of 20 recently concluded PTAs, primarily in the Asia-Pacific area, and almost all with dispute settlement systems based on the WTO model. The authors provide a detailed comparison of the various stages of handling disputes in these PTAs and in the DSU and include a useful discussion of the institutions that administer dispute settlement. An older study (Smith 2000) evaluates legalism in PTA disputes by analyzing a coded dataset of 60 pre-1996 PTAs. Smith finds that legalism improves compliance by increasing the costs of opportunism and the probability of detection. He argues that negotiators, in drafting PTAs, weigh the benefits of improved treaty compliance against the costs of limited policy discretion for their own countries. PTA parties with high relative economic power accordingly favor less legalistic dispute settlement, and so standing tribunals such as the European Court of Justice (ECJ) exist only in those PTAs in which asymmetry of power is low. Deeper integration also favors legalism because it generates more economic gains and because the trade barriers involved are more complex.

U.S. PTAs EU association agreements have opted for political settlement of bilateral disputes. Thus, the first PTAs to incorporate formal panel procedures of the type used in the WTO and its predecessor, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), were the Canada–U.S. FTA (CUSFTA) and NAFTA. U.S. PTAs still largely follow the CUSFTA/NAFTA model, although post-2001 PTAs have departed from it in some respects, as discussed below. Annex A gives an account of the dispute settlement choices made in negotiating these agreements—choices that influenced the design of the WTO


Dispute Settlement

469

Dispute Settlement Understanding (DSU). Hart, Dymond, and Robertson (1994); Kreinin (2000); and Cameron and Tomlin (2002) provide detailed accounts of the negotiations. Among the abundant literature on these agreements, Loungnarath and Stehly (2000) analyze CUSFTA and NAFTA disputes and argue that political pressure has impaired outcomes for Canada, as the weaker partner. Davey (1996) presents a detailed retrospective on every CUSFTA dispute. He concludes that binational review of trade remedy decisions under CUSFTA Chapter 19 has been generally reasonable but could be improved, and he makes suggestions for minor changes to that end. He also finds that the general trade dispute procedures of Chapter 18 were not an improvement on GATT procedure; in practice, the parties largely preferred GATT for their bilateral disputes, and he predicts that the NAFTA governments will continue to prefer WTO procedures wherever possible. Gantz (2006) surveys experience under the three NAFTA dispute settlement mechanisms (state-to-state trade disputes, antidumping and countervailing duty binational reviews, and investor-state arbitration), reviews U.S. attitudes toward NAFTA dispute settlement, and discusses the decline in U.S. government support for NAFTA since 1994. He rates Chapter 19 review of antidumping and countervailing duty decisions as a success—although it enjoys little support in the U.S. government, which has not included such a provision in any post-NAFTA PTA.1

Choi (2004) analyzes the dispute settlement provisions of a selection of East Asian PTAs and makes a number of specific suggestions for PTA dispute settlement procedures. Choi suggests that opening panel hearings in such disputes would be undesirable because it would increase pressure on panelists by domestic interest groups. Luo (2005) discusses the “Asian way” of dispute settlement under ASEAN and points out that, following the establishment of the ASEAN Dispute Settlement Mechanism (DSM) in 1996, there were many actual disputes among ASEAN members concerning implementation of the ASEAN Free Trade Area, but none were brought to the DSM. Luo suggests the use of an independent enforcement body, or access for private parties, to counteract governments’ reluctance to engage in open conflict. Nakagawa (2007) analyzes the use of dispute settlement by East Asian governments in the WTO and in PTAs. He argues that most trade disputes between Asian PTA parties will be brought to the WTO and that settlement of disputes through negotiated deals will continue to be the trend in East Asia because of underlying economic factors and the limits on what dispute settlement mechanisms can accomplish. Kawai and Wignaraja (2009) present the results of a survey of firms in East Asia. They find that most of the firms surveyed do not use PTA preferences because of lack of information, costs related to rules of origin, and low margins of preference. Obviously, if firms are not using PTAs, there will be fewer PTA-related disputes.

East Asian PTAs

Latin American PTAs

As Baldwin (2008) points out, East Asia’s regional integration into “Factory Asia” took place initially not through PTAs but through unilateral cuts in most favored nation (MFN) tariffs. Baldwin notes the potential insecurity of such liberalization, which is not backed by any enforceable legal obligations. He characterizes the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN)–China FTA initiative in 2000 as the trigger for similar moves by Japan, the Republic of Korea, and others, resulting in the current “noodle bowl” of East Asian PTAs. Wang (2009) describes the Dispute Settlement Mechanism Agreement of the ASEAN–China FTA as a “landmark agreement,” since it is China’s first PTA to provide for settlement of bilateral or regional disputes through formal procedures, even to the extent of authorizing trade retaliation. Snyder (2009) analyzes China’s PTAs and finds that almost all have used WTO dispute settlement as a template, with the exception of China’s Closer Economic Partnership Agreements (CEPAs) with Hong Kong SAR, China, and Macao SAR, China. Disputes under the CEPA agreements are settled diplomatically, by consultation and agreement between the parties.

A wealth of data is available on dispute settlement in PTAs in Latin America and the Caribbean.2 Sáez (2007) finds that countries in the region have been very active in dispute settlement, that they use the WTO even when PTA dispute settlement mechanisms exist, and that in Latin American PTAs, disputes on tariff application, drawback, and excise tax discrimination have tended to peak during an agreement’s initial period, when tariffs are being phased out. There is a substantial scholarly literature in Spanish examining the Andean Community institutions, the dispute settlement mechanism of the Southern Cone Common Market (Mercosur, Mercado Común del Sur), the Latin American Integration Association/Asociación Latinoamericana de Integración (LAIA/ALADI), and other regional institutions in the light of Latin American domestic and international legal doctrine. Englishlanguage sources consulted for this chapter include the valuable recent empirical studies on the Andean Community by Helfer and Alter (2009) and Alter and Helfer (2011), as well as a collection edited by Lacarte and


470

Amelia Porges

Granados (2004), which covers dispute settlement under LAIA/ALADI (Rojas Penso 2004), Mercosur (Opertti 2004; Whitelaw 2004), the Andean Community (Vigil Toledo 2004), and various Central American trade agreements (Echandi 2004). African PTAs World Bank and International Monetary Fund (IMF) studies on African regionalism (Foroutan 1992; Yang and Gupta 2005), as well as discussions in World Bank (2000), Schiff and Winters (2003), Gathii (2010), and Thorp (2010), note the dense web of PTAs in Africa. These studies generally find that, although most African PTAs have a high level of ambition for integration, they have not been effective in eliminating intraregional trade and investment barriers and have struggled with (or succumbed to) economic conflict resulting from an asymmetric distribution of gains from liberalization. Implementation of PTAs has been beset with obstacles, including linguistic differences, intra-PTA differences between common law and civil law systems, and a pervasive shortage of resources for PTA institutions, including those involved in dispute settlement. As noted by Essien (2006), general information on the status of PTA courts in Africa is difficult to find. Gathii (2010) presents a broader portrait of African PTAs, arguing that they must be understood as flexible regimes that incorporate variable geometry, asymmetric obligations, mechanisms for redistributing benefits, and commitments that are perhaps not meant to be enforced. If enforcement is not intended, a scarcity of formal trade agreement disputes should be no surprise. Dispute Settlement and Enforcement: The Basic Options In theory, the negotiators of a PTA start with a blank slate and can choose any form or type of dispute settlement they wish. In practice, dispute settlement mechanisms in PTAs fall into three broad groups: political or diplomatic dispute settlement; systems based on a standing tribunal; and referral to an ad hoc arbitral panel, as in the WTO. In a negotiating situation, the choice of system depends, first, on whether the governments wish to have a third-party dispute settlement procedure, rather than rely solely on negotiation to settle disputes. If they opt for a third-party decision maker, they can go down the path of establishing a standing tribunal, or they can follow the currently dominant approach of using a WTO-type ad hoc panel procedure. The pros and cons of each approach are discussed next.

Political or Diplomatic Dispute Settlement Political or diplomatic dispute settlement consists of settling disputes by negotiation and agreement. It gives the parties to a PTA maximum flexibility. The agreement may have no dispute settlement provisions at all; it may provide only for consultations; it may provide for consultations and refer disputes to a political body for resolution; or it may provide for referral to a third-party adjudicator but allow a party or parties to block the referral. The choice of a political dispute settlement model often reflects asymmetric power relations between the PTA parties. For instance, China’s Closer Economic Partnership Agreements with Hong Kong SAR, China, and with Macao SAR, China, state that the parties “shall resolve any problems arising from the interpretation or implementation of the ‘CEPA’ through consultation in the spirit of friendship and cooperation.” In pre-2000 European Union PTAs and in the 1969 Southern African Customs Union (SACU), disputes were settled exclusively through political processes. The use of political dispute settlement may also reflect a low level of ambition for implementation of intra-PTA liberalization, as in the case of partial-scope agreements in LAIA/ALADI, in ASEAN trade liberalization in the 1990s, and in the Economic Cooperation Organization Trade Agreement entered into by Central Asian countries. The choice of political dispute settlement method may also reflect a level of deep integration that gives both sides in a PTA real leverage, even without third-party adjudication, as in the Australia–New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement (ANZCERTA) and in the relations between Australia and New Zealand under the recently signed ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand agreement. The diplomatic model of dispute settlement was the dominant model in all the EU’s pre-2000 association agreements and PTAs. These include the Europe Agreements with Eastern European accession candidate countries; the Euro-Mediterranean Agreements with the Arab Republic of Egypt, Israel, Jordan, Morocco, and Tunisia; and the Stabilization and Association Agreements with Balkan countries (Ramirez Robles 2006). A party to one of these agreements may refer to the agreement’s Association Council any dispute concerning the application or interpretation of the agreement, and the Association Council may, by consensus, adopt a binding decision to resolve the dispute. Broude (2009) describes this concept as “a case of faux institutionalization—the Association Council is a ministerial-level body, designed to meet but once a year.” He notes that, in practice, disputes are officially delegated to an Association Committee that reports to the Council and are handled by diplomatic negotiation. In theory, these


Dispute Settlement

agreements permit any party to have recourse to arbitration if negotiations fail to settle a dispute, but the appointment of arbitrators can be blocked, and there are no deadlines or procedures. The agreements provide no organized procedures for ensuring compliance with arbitral awards except for a “nonexecution clause” that permits a party to take “appropriate measures,” even without going through a dispute settlement procedure, if it considers that the other party has failed to fulfill an obligation under the agreement. Garcia Bercero (2006) states that this diplomatic approach has been an effective means of settling “low profile trade irritants” but that some disputes linger unresolved for years, if one party is stubborn and the other is unwilling to blow up the relationship by taking retaliatory action. He reports that the arbitration procedure has seldom been used, that the nonexecution clause has been invoked very sparingly, and that most of these invocations have involved EU disputes with the Russian Federation. The standard dispute settlement procedure in LAIA/ALADI is set forth in Resolution 114 of the association’s Committee of Representatives. The resolution, adopted in 1990, provides for consultations between the parties, after which a member country may request the Committee of Representatives to propose a nonbinding solution. The association’s secretary-general has characterized this system as “virtually useless” and ineffective in resolving disputes (Rojas Penso 2004). As a result, parties to the partial-scope agreements within LAIA/ALADI have adopted specific dispute settlement procedures. Some agreements simply rely on direct negotiations, and some recent ones provide for third-party panels. The 1992 ASEAN Framework Agreement and the Agreement on the Common Effective Preferential Tariff Scheme for the ASEAN Free Trade Area both provided for settlement of disputes by agreement between the parties, with referral of nonsettled disputes to a ministerial-level body. (This scheme has since been replaced by a panel mechanism, as discussed below.) To a notable extent, PTAs that started with diplomatic or political dispute settlement have moved toward ruleoriented third-party dispute settlement modeled on the DSU. Examples include ASEAN, which replaced earlier arrangements with the 2004 ASEAN Protocol on Enhanced Dispute Settlement Mechanism; SACU, which implemented a DSU-type scheme in the 2002 SACU Agreement; and Mercosur, an agreement formally within the LAIA/ ALADI framework, which provides an elaborate thirdparty dispute settlement system, including appellate review. The FTAs and economic partnership agreements (EPAs) negotiated by the EU since 2007 have shifted to panel-based third-party dispute settlement.

471

Standing Tribunals The standing tribunals of the European Union represent the oldest system of this kind. Its example has been highly influential worldwide, but especially in countries with historical ties to Europe. The EU system. The European Court of Justice (ECJ) is the original PTA standing tribunal. Established in 1952 as the Court of Justice of the European Coal and Steel Community, it later became the Court of Justice of the European Communities and is now known formally as the Court of Justice of the European Union. It now consists of the 27-judge Court of Justice itself; a 27-judge court of first instance, the General Court; and the Civil Service Tribunal, for EU civil service employment disputes. In 2009 the ECJ received 562 new cases, completed 588 cases, and had 742 cases pending at the end of the year. The 562 new cases comprised 302 requests from EU member state courts for preliminary rulings on issues of EU law, 143 direct actions, 105 appeals, and a few other cases (ECJ 2010a). Direct actions include enforcement actions brought by the European Commission against a member state for failure to fulfill an obligation under Article 258 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union and (very rarely) cases brought by one member state against another regarding nonfulfillment of EU Treaty obligations (Article 259). In enforcement actions, the Commission sends a letter of formal notice to a member state— the most recent official figures show that about 68 percent of complaints are settled before this point (European Commission 2009). After giving the member state an opportunity to reply, the Commission delivers a “reasoned opinion”; about 84 percent of infringement procedures based on a complaint are settled before this stage. If the member state does not comply with the reasoned opinion by a deadline set by the Commission, the Commission may bring a case before the ECJ; around 94 percent of these infringement procedures are settled before an ECJ ruling. Thus, only 6 percent of all procedures are resolved by the court. Judgments under Article 259 or its predecessor provisions have been extremely rare (fewer than five since 1951). In practice, if an EU government or stakeholder has a problem with another member state’s compliance with EU Treaty rules, it lobbies the Commission to negotiate with the noncomplying government and possibly bring an action under Article 258. The Commission then takes on the resource and reputational costs of negotiation and litigation and is also free to pursue its own institutional agenda. The ECJ and the European Commission enforcement infrastructure represent the maximum in treaty enforcement,


472

Amelia Porges

as measured by activity and resources. At the end of 2008, the Commission was handling 1,557 complaints and infringement files. Complaints accounted for two-thirds of all cases other than those regarding late implementation of EU directives. In 2008 the Commission opened 2,223 infringement procedures, sent 512 reasoned opinions, and referred 209 cases to the ECJ (European Commission 2009). The ECJ also provides guidance to the courts in all member states, through preliminary rulings on EU law requested by national courts. These preliminary references ensure uniform application of EU law, and the principles they establish affect the entire EU legal order. They have given the ECJ a platform for establishing fundamental principles of EU law, such as its direct effect in national law, and legal doctrines safeguarding freedom of movement of goods and services. Private actors can bring domestic court cases in order to obtain an ECJ preliminary ruling. The ECJ and the judicial structure under it represent a very large commitment of resources. Its 27 judges, one for each member state, are assisted by a registrar; 8 AdvocatesGeneral who provide impartial advisory opinions on the cases before the Court; and a large staff, including many translators, housed in a new building in Luxembourg. The ECJ also acts as an appellate court for cases brought before the 27-judge General Court or the Civil Service Tribunal. The 2011 draft budget for the Court of Justice of the European Union, comprising all these courts, is projected at 345,293,000 euros (about US$450 million), not including the Commission’s enforcement expenses. Of the total, 75 percent goes for personnel and 25 percent for buildings and other costs (EU 2010). Other standing tribunals. The obligations of the European Free Trade Area (EFTA) and the European Economic Area (EEA) are enforced by the EFTA Surveillance Authority and the EFTA Court. The most recent figures, for 2008, show an actual cost for both of 3,606,035 euros (EFTA Court 2009). A number of South-South PTAs have patterned their dispute settlement institutions on the ECJ and the European Commission: they include the Andean Community, the Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS), the West African Economic and Monetary Union/Union Économique et Monétaire Ouest-Africaine (WAEMU/UEMOA), the Economic and Monetary Community of Central Africa (CEMAC, Communauté Économique et Monétaire de l’Afrique Centrale), the East African Community (EAC), and the Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA).The reasons for following the EU model are partly historical and (in the case of African PTAs) partly attributable to the influence of the EU as the regional hegemon. At the time many of these

PTAs were negotiated, the GATT dispute settlement mechanism was in disuse or did not otherwise provide a positive model for enforcement of obligations. The project of building the European Community and then the European Union provided a stronger model for PTA ambitions. The most judicialized South-South PTA dispute settlement institutions, the Andean Tribunal of Justice (ATJ) and the Andean Community General Secretariat, were established in 1979 as part of the Andean Pact. Treaty amendments in 1996 created a new Andean Community, strengthened the ATJ, gave the General Secretariat a stronger role, and reduced diplomatic elements in the procedures. The General Secretariat may now initiate a noncompliance investigation on its own and must initiate an investigation in response to a complaint by a government or private party. There have been up to 30 such cases per year.3 The General Secretariat sends a notice to the government concerned, which must respond. The General Secretariat then issues a reasoned opinion, which is published and with which the government concerned is obligated to comply. If the government does not comply, then the General Secretariat, a complaining member state, or a private party whose rights have been affected may bring a noncompliance case (acción de incumplimiento) against the noncomplying country to the ATJ, which sits in Quito. There have been up to 20 such cases per year.4 If the ATJ makes a finding of noncompliance and the losing government fails to comply by the deadline set by the ATJ, the ATJ may initiate a summary procedure (procedimientosumario) in response to a request by the General Secretariat, a member state, or an affected private party and may authorize sanctions against the noncomplying government by other member states (Vigil Toledo 2004; CAN 2008a). Alter and Helfer (2011) observe that, compared to the ECJ, the ATJ has been deferential to Andean states and unwilling to push for compliance with Andean law and that the ATJ has “refused to serve as the engine of Andean legal integration”—which they characterize as a politically prudent path in the face of Andean states’ “tepid” commitments to Andean integration. The ATJ also can issue rulings in response to references from national courts; such rulings account for 90 percent of ATJ case law. Ninety-six percent of preliminary references through 2007 involved intellectual property disputes, for three reasons: first, private litigants have rarely used Andean rules to challenge other policies; second, intellectual property agencies in the Andean countries actively encouraged such references and incorporated them into their domestic decision making; third, national courts rarely send novel questions to the ATJ; fourth, there is no infrastructure of scholars and practitioners proselytizing


Dispute Settlement

for Andean law; and, fifth, these conditions have continued the same no matter what the level of political support for the Andean Community project (Helfer and Alter 2009; Alter and Helfer 2011). The fiscal 2008 budget for the Andean Tribunal was US$1,170,667.5 As part of an overall initiative to strengthen Central American regional integration, governments in the region established the Central American Court of Justice (CACJ), or Corte de Justicia Centroamericana, in 1994. The CACJ has almost never been used for trade disputes. In the late 1990s, the countries established a Central American Trade Dispute Resolution Mechanism, modeled on the WTO, which, since 2003, has applied to all countries in the region (Echandi 2004). The Caribbean Court of Justice was created in 2001 with a dual role: to serve as a final court of appeal in civil and criminal cases for its member states, and to interpret the Treaty of Chaguaramas, which established the Caribbean Community (CARICOM). The extent of regional support for this court is unclear, and it lacks the institutional support of a secretariat to monitor compliance (INTAL 2005). In 2007 the CCJ’s administrative expenses amounted to US$32.2 million (CCJ 2008). A number of African PTAs have also established courts on the ECJ model; these include ECOWAS, WAEMU/ UEMOA, CEMAC, the EAC, and COMESA. As the following examples illustrate, a regional tribunal created to enforce trade law may also become involved in other issues, and vice versa: • The ECOWAS Community Court of Justice was created in 1991, but its members were only appointed in 2000. The court sits in Abuja and has a modest budget for handling both enforcement of ECOWAS norms and human rights issues. Originally, only states could bring disputes, but since 2005, individuals have been able to bring cases, including complaints based on human rights instruments. The court has been active recently, but mostly on cases with a human rights dimension (Banjo 2007; Hessbruegge 2011; Daily Independent 2011). • The UEMOA court has a permanent building at its seat in Ouagadougou, and a modest budget.6 CEMAC’s Court of Justice sits in Ndjamena. Each court issues fewer than 10 decisions per year. • The Court of Justice of the East African Community, which meets in Arusha, Tanzania, was dormant from 1999 until receiving its first case in December 2005. It hears both disputes between member states and preliminary references by courts in member states. Its fiscal 2010/11 budget was US$2,841,777, out of a total EAC

473

budget of US$60 million, half of which is financed by aid donors (see EAC 2010). • The COMESA Court of Justice was established in 1994 and appointed in 1998, but since moving to Khartoum in 2006, it has reportedly faced problems with inadequate funds and staff, lack of a physical location, and the need to adapt to shari’a law. It has been unable to meet even twice a year. Its 2001 budget was US$595,538 (COMESA 2000, 2009; East African 2006; AICT data).7 • The SADC Tribunal of 10 part-time members was formally established in 1992 and was inaugurated in 2005. It meets, as required, in Windhoek. It has a registrar and 16 employees. The SADC budget is largely funded by donor countries. The tribunal’s cases have included appeals by SADC employees and three cases in which the court condemned Zimbabwe’s land reform program as racially discriminatory and illegal under the SADC Treaty. Faced with noncompliance, the complainants have used South African courts to seize property of the Zimbabwe government, and the tribunal has asked the SADC heads of state to consider a request by one of the complainants that the SADC expel Zimbabwe (Nyaungwa 2010; Reuters 2010). Dispute Settlement by Referral to Ad Hoc Panel (WTO Model) The third, currently dominant, model for PTA dispute settlement is based on the WTO’s dispute settlement system (originally developed in the GATT). A panel is convened for one dispute (thus, it is “ad hoc”), with terms of reference limited to that dispute. The panel hears the written and oral arguments of disputing parties, issues a written ruling applying the trade agreement’s law to the dispute, and then disbands. The WTO’s dispute settlement procedures have shaped expectations of governments and stakeholders regarding credible dispute settlement and enforcement within trade agreements. As a result, PTA negotiators have converged on the WTO-like model. Dispute settlement procedures of this type are very widespread and appear in virtually all new PTAs, such as the following list, which includes some PTAs that have been signed but not yet ratified: • Australia: FTAs with Chile, Singapore, and Thailand • ASEAN Enhanced Dispute Settlement Mechanism, which covers disputes under at least 46 ASEAN agreements on tariff preferences, tariff nomenclature, investment, services, mutual recognition of standards or certification, customs, and the like; ASEAN FTAs with China and Korea; the ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand FTA


474

Amelia Porges

• Canada: FTAs with Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Israel, Jordan, Panama, and Peru • Chile: FTAs with Central America, China, Colombia, EFTA, Japan, Korea, Mexico, Panama, and Peru • China: FTAs with Costa Rica, New Zealand, Pakistan, Peru, and Singapore • EFTA: FTAs with Canada, Colombia, Croatia, Egypt, Israel, Jordan, Korea, Lebanon, the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Morocco, and the Palestinian Authority • EU: FTAs with Chile, Korea, and Mexico and the recent EPA with the Caribbean Forum of African, Caribbean, and Pacific (ACP) States (CARIFORUM) • India: FTAs with Chile and Mercosur • Japan: EPAs with Brunei Darussalam, Chile, Indonesia, Malaysia, Mexico, the Philippines, Singapore, Switzerland, Thailand, and Vietnam • Mercosur: Protocol of Olivos, with Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, and Uruguay • Mexico: FTAs with Bolivia, Colombia, EFTA, Israel, Nicaragua, the Northern Triangle countries (El Salvador, Guatemala, and Honduras) and Uruguay • New Zealand: FTAs with Thailand and Singapore • Singapore: FTAs with the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC), India, Jordan, Korea, Panama, and Peru; Trans-Pacific Strategic Economic Partnership (TransPacific SEP). • United States: NAFTA; U.S. FTAs with Australia, Bahrain, Dominican Republic–Central America Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA–DR), Chile, Colombia, Israel, Jordan, Korea, Morocco, Oman, Panama, Peru, and Singapore The cost of an ad hoc panel system depends on how many panels exist. If there are none, the cost of dispute settlement approaches zero, as the disputes that do not reach the panel stage will be supervised by existing PTA institutions. The out-of-pocket system costs of panels—panelist compensation and expenses; hearing venue; and clerical, translation, and interpretation services—depend on the parties’ procedural choices and the number of disputes. The WTO’s annual budget for dispute settlement panels (excluding the organization’s first three years) has ranged from a high of 1,195,300 Swiss francs (Sw F) in 1999 to a low of Sw F 655,592 in 2006. For 2011, it was estimated at Sw F 987,000 for panels and Sw F 50,000 for arbitrations (WTO 2009, 52). The WTO’s costs for panel proceedings are low in relation to the number of disputes handled because WTO members whose delegates serve as panelists contribute their services without compensation. The estimated 2011 budget for the WTO Appellate Body is

Sw F 5,691,000, of which personnel costs account for 69 percent, or Sw F 3,909,500 (WTO 2009, 52). These system costs exclude the costs of participation for the parties. Some governments maintain an internal legal staff or otherwise represent themselves in trade disputes. Others hire counsel or expect stakeholders to pay for counsel engaged by the government. The standard ceiling fees for legal assistance (without further subsidy) set by the Advisory Centre for WTO Law provide a lower-bound estimate for legal costs in the WTO: Sw F 47,628 for consultations and Sw F 143,856 for panel proceedings, or Sw F 191,484 together (ACWL 2007). Choosing among the Options In considering dispute settlement, the first choice is whether to rely exclusively on diplomatic or political dispute settlement or to provide for third-party dispute settlement of some sort. The key difference between the two is that in the former, a complaining party that has tried and failed to negotiate a mutually satisfactory solution does not have the option of obtaining a determination by a neutral third party. In a tribunal or ad hoc panel system, if there is no agreement, the complaining party can refer the dispute to a neutral decision maker who rules on the dispute. Settlement by negotiation is possible in any system; indeed, the classic WTO model requires that the complaining party give the responding party an opportunity to settle the problem through bilateral consultations, and the preliminary stages in a tribunal system may also result in compliance or a compromise settlement. Negotiators may choose to rely solely on diplomatic or political dispute settlement if the PTA is unambitious or represents only a low sunk investment in integration. They may also feel that government-government dispute settlement is not necessary if the PTA partners have a transparent commercial and legal environment with stable trade relations and a high degree of economic integration, as in ANZCERTA. And there may be no place for third-party dispute settlement in a PTA with strongly asymmetric relations, such as the CEPAs that China has negotiated with Hong Kong SAR, China, and with Macao SAR, China. Political or diplomatic means of dispute settlement are unlikely, however, to provide a sufficient incentive structure to keep markets open in times of economic stress. Most recent PTAs have opted for third-party dispute settlement because of significant factors that distinguish the new and enhanced PTAs negotiated since 1994 from their predecessors of the GATT era, as described by Schiff and Winters (2003).


Dispute Settlement

First, many of these agreements have embraced deep integration, going well beyond border measures to cover subjects such as investment, services, and domestic regulation. Where a partner has relatively low border barriers, expansion of the scope of the PTA to behind-the-border measures may be necessary if the PTA is to offer substantial economic benefits—as Francois and Manchin (2009) find for a possible PTA between the EU and the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS). The increased level of ambition involved in a deep integration agreement requires the parties to make a greater resource investment in implementing the agreement. Accordingly, negotiators typically choose legalized, formal dispute settlement, following some widely understood model—currently, that of the WTO. In North-South PTAs with asymmetrical power relations, binding third-party dispute settlement becomes even more important (World Bank 2000, 69–70). Recently concluded PTAs in Latin America, Europe, and Asia demonstrate to a striking degree that as PTA obligations deepen, become more complex, and provide more value, PTA partners seek more certainty than can be had through purely diplomatic dispute settlement. Second, the dominant paradigm has shifted to integration into the globalized economy through open regionalism. “Open regionalism” implies that PTA parties actively seek inclusion in global supply networks under transparent, rule-of-law conditions by using the PTA to secure market access rights, and by turning away from import-substituting industrialization or administrative protectionism. Open regionalism can also lead to coexistence of PTA networks, docking (legal connection) of PTA networks, and even multilateralization of PTA networks. Dispute settlement can reinforce open regionalism in the first sense by ensuring full PTA implementation and reinforcing the PTA’s lock-in effect. Systems based on a regional court can be an important focus of region building, as seen in the case of the European Court of Justice. However, if the goal is to connect PTAs into larger networks, ad hoc panel systems are easier to merge than court-based systems of dispute settlement. Structuring a PTA Dispute Settlement System: More Decisions Some threshold decisions are required in order to set the system’s parameters. The agreement will need to define the range of possible complaints, or “causes of action,” as well as their potential subject scope. Since practically all PTAs overlap with the WTO (and may overlap with other PTAs), PTA negotiators must also decide what will happen in the event that a party brings claims under the WTO concerning a measure disputed in the PTA.

475

Defining the Grounds for Complaint Breach of obligations. Many PTAs simply state that dispute settlement will be available in cases of violation of the PTA obligations or of failure to implement the PTA; some also allow for the use of the mechanism to settle disputes regarding interpretation of the PTA. For instance, in CUSFTA and later U.S. FTAs, the dispute settlement provisions apply with respect to avoidance or settlement of disputes regarding the interpretation or application of the agreement, or regarding measures considered to be inconsistent with the obligations of the agreement. Some PTAs (e.g., the Japan–Chile and ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand agreements) draw instead on the formulation in GATT Article XXIII:1(a), which permits invocation of the dispute settlement mechanism when a “benefit accruing . . . directly or indirectly under this Agreement is being nullified or impaired . . . or the attainment of any objective of this Agreement is being impeded as the result of the failure of another [party] to carry out its obligations under this Agreement.” Nonviolation nullification or impairment of concessions or obligations. Some PTAs give their parties not just a remedy against violation or noncompliance by another party, but also a remedy against measures of other parties that are PTA-consistent but still take away the benefit of bargainedfor PTA market access. These “nonviolation nullification or impairment” remedies are modeled on GATT Article XXIII:1(b).8 GATT and WTO panels have interpreted Article XXIII:1(b) as providing for recourse when (a) benefits that could reasonably have been expected at the time of a negotiated market access concession (b) are nullified or impaired by (c) a later (GATT-consistent) government measure that upsets the conditions of competition between domestic and imported products. Under the GATT and now the DSU, remedies in such “nonviolation” cases are limited to compensatory tariff reduction on other products; the WTO cannot require a member to alter measures that are WTO-consistent. Almost all GATT nonviolation disputes concerned subsidies that were GATT-consistent but distorted trade. PTAs with panel-based dispute settlement show continued interest in nonviolation remedies as a means of protecting the market access and other benefits that these agreements provide. However, the PTAs that provide such remedies tend to explicitly identify which benefits are thus protected, typically by citing specific PTA chapters. For instance, all U.S. FTAs explicitly permit disputes regarding nonviolation impairment of benefits accruing under specific identified chapters, usually those concerning market access and national treatment for trade in goods


476

Amelia Porges

(including rules of origin), cross-border services trade, procurement, intellectual property rights (IPRs), and, sometimes, technical barriers to trade (TBTs). Some PTAs provide nonviolation remedies only for certain chapters— for example, only for goods, or for goods and services, or for goods, services, and various other categories that may include TBTs, sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) measures, aviation, procurement, and IPRs.9 A few PTAs make provision for disputes regarding nullification or impairment of PTA benefits generally (e.g., Japan–Switzerland and Canada–Israel). Other PTAs only provide for settlement of disputes regarding noncompliance with obligations under the agreement (the Australia–Singapore, Chile–China, Chile–EU, Japan–Indonesia, and Japan–Mexico PTAs, and many others) or explicitly exclude any possibility of nonviolation complaints (the ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand agreement). The Target of a Complaint Measures by a government. It goes without saying that PTA dispute settlement deals with government measures—that is, existing laws, regulations, or other official actions or failures to act that engage state responsibility, as opposed to actions of private parties. Although there is at least one case of a dispute (in Mercosur) concerning trade-obstructing actions by private parties (see annex B), the actionable measure was a PTA party’s failure to ensure free circulation of goods as required by the PTA. Proposed measures. Some PTAs permit disputes concerning proposed measures, such as pending legislation. The first modern example of such a provision appears in CUSFTA Chapter 18. Both CUSFTA and NAFTA provide for consultations and for requests for a panel decision regarding whether pending legislation in a partner is consistent with the PTA. Since 2001, U.S. PTAs have permitted consultations, but not arbitral panel proceedings, on pending legislation. As Donaldson and Lester (2009) note, dispute settlement about proposed measures raises significant policy issues. It can be a waste of resources for panels to consider measures that may never be enacted, but early consultations can help limit or prevent trade damage by persuading governments not to enact measures that would violate their PTA obligations. Subject matter exclusions. PTA dispute settlement procedures generally apply only with respect to the rights and obligations provided in that PTA. Some subject areas are often excluded from dispute settlement even when they are included in a PTA. If a PTA contains “soft-law” obligations that urge but do not mandate economic or other cooperation, those

obligations are often excluded from formal dispute settlement. Such an exclusion makes sure that no dispute settlement panel will ever read “should” as “shall.”10 As a corollary, when obligations regarding a subject area are limited to soft law, that area is likely to be excluded from formal dispute settlement.11 PTAs may also exclude areas from dispute settlement in order to ensure policy space for domestic regulation or to avoid PTA challenges to determinations by domestic regulators in particular cases. For instance, some PTAs exclude from dispute settlement any complaint regarding denial of rights to temporary entry and stay by business visitors unless the complaint concerns a pattern of practice and the nationals involved have exhausted local administrative remedies.12 The objective is clearly to prevent the agreement’s being used for immigration litigation. Some PTAs exclude TBT or SPS issues, or both, for similar reasons. The Japan–Switzerland FTA limits possible complaints regarding the effect of taxation on the PTA while subordinating the PTA to tax treaty obligations, following the example of Article XXII:2 of the WTO General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). In PTAs with competition chapters, the relevant chapter is often excluded from dispute settlement because competition authorities see panel review of their decisions as unwelcome and inappropriate. PTAs may exclude areas from PTA dispute settlement when the PTA’s obligations merely reaffirm WTO obligations. For instance, if a PTA simply confirms TBT or SPS obligations that are derived from the WTO Agreement, it may exclude TBT or SPS issues from PTA dispute settlement. Finally, PTAs may exclude panel interpretation of subjects that are reserved to specific bodies in one of the parties. For instance, all New Zealand PTAs that have formal dispute settlement mechanisms provide that the interpretation of the 1840 Treaty of Waitangi between the British Crown and Maori tribes shall not be subject to dispute settlement under the PTA. Under New Zealand law, matters concerning this treaty are reserved to a special tribunal. Overlap between the PTA and Another Forum Overlap in obligations between two legal regimes occurs when the same parties take part in two separate regimes and both regimes regulate the matter in dispute at the same time. Almost all PTAs overlap with the WTO Agreement, as PTAs and the WTO both require national treatment and ban quantitative restrictions in trade. Indeed, many PTAs simply incorporate GATT Articles III and XI by reference. Some PTA members are also members of another overlapping PTA, as happens with CAFTA–DR and the Central American Common Market (CACM), SACU and the


Dispute Settlement

Southern African Development Community (SADC), and ANZCERTA and the ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand FTA (Pauwelyn 2004). When both legal regimes have independent dispute settlement regimes, overlap affords opportunities for a complaining party to choose the most advantageous forum or to relitigate a case in one forum (usually, the WTO) after an unsatisfactory outcome in another (the PTA). For example, Brazil brought a Mercosur challenge to an Argentine antidumping measure on poultry; the Mercosur arbitral tribunal found that the measure was not regulated by Mercosur law and was therefore not inconsistent with Argentina’s Mercosur obligations. Brazil then went to the WTO, and the WTO panel found that the antidumping measure violated the WTO Agreement on Antidumping (Piérola and Horlick 2007). In another case, Brazil prevailed in a Mercosur challenge to an Argentine textiles safeguard, but Argentina did not remove its quotas, and Brazil obtained a settlement only after bringing the dispute to the WTO (Kwak and Marceau 2006). Similarly, Argentina brought a complaint against Chile’s price band tariffs to the WTO after Chile failed to comply with a nonbinding PTA panel decision (Tussie and Delich 2005). For any government, and particularly for developing countries, relitigation poses a resource burden, particularly if a developing country must mount multiple defenses of the same measure in different forums. Overlap also presents the possibility of conflicting rulings, as in the Argentina poultry case (Pauwelyn 2006). A WTO panel does not have jurisdiction to rule on whether a measure violates a PTA, and vice versa. Domestic law doctrines that curb duplicate litigation, such as lis alibi pendens and res judicata, are not a solution because the obligations are not the same.13 Even if GATT Article III is incorporated by reference into a PTA, in the PTA context it is part of PTA law and is subject to exceptions and dispute settlement procedures that may not be the same as in the WTO (Kwak and Marceau 2006). Resolving Overlap There are three options for dealing with forum shopping in dispute settlement: give precedence to the PTA proceeding; give precedence to the WTO or other proceeding; or allow the parties to choose but prohibit relitigation. Preference for PTA rules. A PTA may require that all disputes between PTA parties involving PTA provisions be settled exclusively within the PTA. The EU Treaty has such a requirement, and in the MOX Plant Case, the ECJ interpreted the relevant EU Treaty article as barring Ireland from bringing a dispute against the United Kingdom under

477

the UN Convention on the Law of the Sea or any other treaty concluded by the European Community (MOX Plant Case 2006). PTA negotiators have also required parties to give precedence to PTA rules that provide more policy space than WTO rules (or otherwise are “WTO-minus”) by specifying the forum for particular disputes. For instance, NAFTA’s Article 104 provides that in the event that obligations under certain listed environmental agreements are inconsistent with NAFTA obligations, the environmental agreements prevail, and under Article 2005(3), if a defending party claims that Article 104 would apply, the complaining party can only bring the dispute under NAFTA. Article 2005(4) similarly gives the responding party the right to have an SPS or TBT dispute heard only under NAFTA, which was considered to afford more policy space. The Chile–Mexico and Canada–Chile FTAs have similar clauses. NAFTA also gives a third NAFTA party the right to force a preference for PTA dispute settlement. Under NAFTA Article 2005(2), before a NAFTA party initiates WTO dispute settlement against another party on grounds that are “substantively equivalent” to those available under NAFTA, it must notify the third NAFTA party. If the third party wishes to litigate regarding the matter under NAFTA, it must inform the complaining party and consult; if the parties fail to agree on the forum, the dispute is normally to be settled in NAFTA. Preference for the WTO. The other extreme is represented by the EU–Chile PTA, which provides that if a dispute concerns a breach of a PTA obligation that is equivalent in substance to a WTO obligation, it must be brought in the WTO. Once a forum is selected, it is to be used to the exclusion of any other, and all arguments regarding forum choice must be resolved within the first 30 days (Garcia Bercero 2006). Binding election of forum. Most recent PTAs use some variant of the approach adopted first in CUSFTA. That model allows disputes arising under both the PTA and the WTO to be settled in either forum at the discretion of the complaining party but provides that, after the “initiation” of dispute settlement, the procedure employed must be used to the exclusion of any other. (The “initiation” point can be defined as the parties wish; CUSFTA pegs it at the point of referral to a panel, so that the complaining party can make its choice after consultations.) The complaining party thus has the option to choose the strongest substantive and procedural rules, while duplicative proceedings are excluded. Provisions of this type appear, for instance, in CUSFTA and all later U.S. FTAs; in Mexican PTAs; and in the China–New Zealand, Japan–Indonesia, Japan–Switzerland, Australia–Thailand, and SACU–EFTA PTAs. Under Mercosur’s Protocol of


478

Amelia Porges

Olivos, which was signed in 2002 in the wake of the poultry case discussed above, if a dispute may be brought in more than one forum, the complaining party may select the forum, or the parties may agree on a forum, but once the dispute is initiated, none of the disputing parties may go to another forum. Variations on this formula permit a dispute to be brought again in another forum if the parties have so agreed (as in the China–ASEAN and ASEAN–Australia– New Zealand PTAs), or if substantially separate and distinct rights and obligations under different international agreements are in dispute (e.g., under the ASEAN–Japan and Australia–Chile PTAs). Given a choice between bringing a dispute under the WTO or under a PTA, most complainants now choose the WTO, which is one reason there are so few PTA disputes. Before the establishment of the WTO, two Canada–U.S. disputes that could have been brought under GATT Articles XI and III were brought under CUSFTA instead, because at the time, CUSFTA offered the quickest and most binding dispute settlement mechanism.14 The choice would be different today. Complainants prefer the WTO for several reasons: the large body of cases (with appellate review), which offers greater clarity and certainty about WTO obligations, and greater predictability about the likely outcome of a dispute; the fact that the WTO panel process cannot be blocked; the stabilizing effect of WTO institutions; and the availability of postjudgment compliance obligations and remedies. WTO proceedings may also provide a unique opportunity to mobilize third-party support and exert political pressure on the respondent party (Piérola and Horlick 2007). Furthermore, WTO panels are composed of neutrals, whereas PTA panels often include representatives of the parties. Gantz (2006) suggests that this is a factor in the U.S. preference for the WTO forum over NAFTA. Options for Procedures In constructing a dispute settlement mechanism, negotiators need to consider what procedures to make available, what financial and infrastructural support will be necessary, and what complaints the panels or tribunals may handle. Consultations Whether a diplomatic or political dispute settlement scheme or an ad hoc panel procedure is employed, a formal dispute officially starts with a request for bilateral consultations. The consultation clause may require that the request be in writing and that it state the legal grounds for the

complaint. It typically also requires the respondent party to consult promptly, and it may obligate the respondent to bring relevant officials to consultations and to provide sufficient information to facilitate settlement of the dispute. The consultation clause must define the scope of issues on which the parties are obligated to consult upon request. Some agreements define this broadly: the consultation clause in the ASEAN Enhanced DSM includes “any matter affecting the implementation, interpretation or application of the Agreement or any covered agreement.” The consultation clause will also determine whether a consultation request can include both existing and proposed measures and whether it can include both breaches of the rules and nonviolation nullification or impairment of trade benefits. As already noted, the consultation or pre-panel phase of a dispute may also extend to mediation, conciliation or good offices, or other forms of alternative dispute resolution. A consultation clause is important because it gives any PTA party a right to get another party to have a focused talk about market access barriers in relation to the PTA’s rights and obligations. The consultations provide a costeffective opportunity for the parties to settle their dispute with maximum control over the outcome, by negotiation and agreement. The consultation request is the first visible formal document, but it usually only comes after extensive contact between stakeholders and the complaining government, or between the governments concerned. Consultations are also important because they provide a key opportunity to clarify the facts. Governments normally do not know the details of a PTA partner’s trade or regulatory regime; they do not know foreign law; and they do not know what aspects of government regulation will have the most impact on trade flows or the interests of stakeholders. Before the consultations, the government may not have collected the facts that it needs to determine its PTA rights and prove a violation of PTA law. The government may also not have a sense of the range of options for PTAconsistent implementation. Consultations provide an opportunity for a government to gather information to help evaluate a case before committing to it and to orient its litigation strategy and settlement negotiations to maximize commercial benefit. For the respondent government, consultations may offer an opportunity to reduce litigation costs by persuading the other side that certain claims are not worth litigating. Both functions of consultations—settlement and fact-gathering—can also be fulfilled through discussions in the framework of a specialized PTA committee. Some PTAs provide that committee consultations can take the place of dispute settlement consultations procedurally, as discussed below.


Dispute Settlement

Cases of urgency or perishable products. Some PTAs (e.g., the Chile–U.S., Canada–Peru, and ASEAN–Japan agreements and the Trans-Pacific SEP) provide accelerated consultation timetables for cases of urgency, including those involving perishable products, following the example of Article 4.8 of the DSU. Most agreements do not define “perishable,” but some do define it as including perishable agricultural or fish products. The 2009 Canada–Colombia and Canada–Peru PTAs provide accelerated consultations for “cases of urgency, including those concerning perishable goods or otherwise involving goods or services that rapidly lose their trade value, such as seasonal goods or services.” This clause recognizes that if the harvest period for a crop is limited and the crop is perishable, delay can make dispute settlement worthless except as a deterrent to repetition. Requirement to have consulted. The GATT, the WTO, and all PTAs reviewed for this chapter require that before a party can use the agreement’s common resources for thirdparty arbitration of a dispute, it must give the responding party an opportunity to settle the dispute through consultations. In the WTO, written consultation requests serve as evidence that such an opportunity was provided. PTAs generally require a written consultation request, and plurilateral PTAs require that the request be circulated to all PTA parties so that they will have an opportunity to participate in consultations as third parties. The consultation procedures may also afford a minimum consultation period by stipulating that the next step can be taken only after a certain number of days have elapsed after the consultation request. The Formal Phase of a Dispute During or after the consultations, the complaining party may decide that a beneficial settlement by negotiation is not possible. At that point, it begins to draw on the collective resources of the PTA and to seek a formal determination— by submitting a request to a political body (in PTAs with political dispute settlement, such as the EU association agreements), or by submitting legal documents as required by the rules in a tribunal system, or by submitting a formal request for establishment of an ad hoc panel. Dispute settlement rules that use ad hoc panels generally require that the request be in writing and that it identify the measure or measures at issue and the legal and factual basis for the complaint. PTAs based on ad hoc panel arbitration use two approaches toward invocation of the panel process. In the first, delivery of a panel request to the other party or to the PTA’s central institutional body (or both) directly triggers

479

the obligation to start the panel appointment process; the Korea–Singapore, China–Singapore, and Australia–Chile PTAs are in this category. Under the other approach, after consultations are exhausted, the complaining party refers the dispute to a political body for conciliation, and after a specified period of time, or if conciliation otherwise fails, the complaining party delivers a written request for a panel to the other party, triggering the panel selection process. This is the approach taken in NAFTA, in later U.S. PTAs, and in some later Mexican and Canadian agreements, under which the political body is a commission or joint committee, nominally at the ministerial level. Where there is potential for settlement, the conciliation phase provides another chance to negotiate, but in practice, the required meeting of the political body can consist of a brief conference call. Infrastructure and Support for Dispute Settlement Institutions. PTA negotiators will need to decide how the PTA’s institutions will be used to support formal PTA dispute settlement. Dispute settlement requires management of document exchanges and hearings; coordination of any roster; secretarial, translation, and interpretation services; provision or rental of a place to hold hearings; research and drafting assistance to panelists; payment of panelist fees and expenses; information services; and capacity building. Negotiators may decide to have an existing secretariat take on these functions. For instance, the ASEAN Secretariat provides support to the ASEAN Enhanced Dispute Settlement Mechanism; the Mercosur Administrative Secretariat supports Mercosur dispute settlement; and each national section of the NAFTA Secretariat provides support for dispute settlement under NAFTA Chapters 19 and 20. This approach can foster consistency of approach and build common knowledge. PTAs can also have each panelist arrange his or her own support services on a reimbursable basis in the event of a dispute; this approach is more economical in the short run but can lead to uneven or legally inconsistent results from case to case. Expenses. Where dispute settlement is conducted through a political body, each side supports its own diplomatic efforts. Where dispute settlement is conducted by a standing tribunal, the tribunal and its associated secretariat will have a standing budget process that involves substantial contributions by the parties. The expenses and payment for an ad hoc panel process typically depend on whether the process is supported by a secretariat. The parties can set a standard scale for panelists’ fees and expenses, eliminating fee competition between them and making costs more predictable.


480

Amelia Porges

A PTA that provides for an ad hoc panel process without drawing on existing institutional support typically calls on the disputing parties to split the expenses. For instance, where a panel is selected by each party choosing an arbitrator, with a third or presiding arbitrator chosen by agreement, each party usually pays its own expenses and the fees and expenses for its arbitrator, and the parties divide equally the tribunal expenses (including the costs of the venue and the interpretation and secretarial services for the hearing) and the fees and expenses of the presiding arbitrator. A few agreements—for example, the Colombia–EFTA and Canada–EFTA PTAs, and the Mercosur Protocol of Olivos—permit the arbitrators to apportion costs or expenses among the parties as part of their award. In 2006, when the Mercosur Permanent Review Tribunal rejected as inadmissible an interlocutory appeal by Argentina against the designation of a panel chairman in a case, it assessed all costs and expenses against Argentina (Mercosur 2006). An existing secretariat, where there is one, may provide dispute settlement support from its budget. This support affords extra benefits to those who make more frequent use of dispute settlement (but also provides public goods for other PTA parties). PTAs can also budget and pay for dispute settlement separately or case by case. The ASEAN Enhanced DSM provides for ASEAN member states to initially contribute equally to a separate revolving ASEAN DSM Fund, to pay for the expenses of ASEAN panels, the ASEAN Appellate Body, and related administrative costs of the secretariat. The parties to a dispute otherwise bear their own legal and other expenses and can be assessed for system expenses to replenish the DSM Fund. Languages. Negotiators may also wish to consider the working language for dispute settlement submissions, hearings, and decisions. They may need to preserve the option to conduct disputes in their own language or languages, or they may wish to choose a single common language in order to economize on costs, as translation of submissions and interpretation at hearings can substantially increase the expense and time for dispute settlement. On the one hand, NAFTA provides meticulously for the use of up to three languages in dispute settlement, as do the Canada–Peru PTA and other Canadian PTAs with Latin American countries. On the other hand, some PTAs opt for disputes to be conducted in English (Japan–Switzerland, Korea–Singapore, Chile–China, Chile–Korea, ASEAN– Australia–New Zealand). The EU–CARIFORUM EPA states that the parties are to negotiate a common working language but that if they cannot agree, the defending party chooses the language, and each disputing party pays its own costs of translating submissions into that language.

Whatever the language actually used in the dispute, it may be politically necessary for texts of the decision to be made available in all the official languages of the disputing parties, to ensure public acceptance. Panel Procedures Predictability and consistency yield major benefits for any litigation process, and PTA dispute settlement is no exception. In a PTA that settles disputes through a standing tribunal, the tribunal has standard rules of procedure that establish expectations regarding requirements for submission of pleadings, evidence and arguments, deadlines, conduct of hearings, and other issues relevant for an orderly and predictable proceeding. In those PTAs that settle disputes diplomatically, procedure is less important, but if a PTA relies on ad hoc panels to settle disputes, the negotiators may wish to lay down agreed rules of procedure to ensure that the panels make consistent procedural decisions. Many PTAs require the establishment of model rules of procedure.15 Typically, the PTA text requires the establishment of model rules and specifies key issues that these rules must cover, leaving details to be negotiated later. Model rules may deal with issues such as how to commence a proceeding; the number and spacing of submissions to the panel; responsibility for administering dispute settlement proceedings; who may attend hearings; deadlines and places for filing documents; languages, translation, and interpretation; protection of business confidential information; how the panel makes decisions (consensus or vote); whether there can be separate arbitrators’ opinions; and whether such separate views must be anonymous. The rules can also provide for transparency. Panel requests for information; handling of business confidential information. Some PTA disputes may concern product bans, SPS measures, or other measures, and in such cases the parties may base their arguments on assertions of scientific or environmental fact. Examples are the disputes on SPS measures and on Argentina’s ban on retreaded tires that were adjudicated by Mercosur tribunals and the SPS measure on milk imports that went before a CUSFTA panel. A panel faced with evaluating such issues and arguments may wish to seek help. The DSU permits a panel, without limitation, to seek information from any relevant source, and so do some PTA provisions or model rules of procedure. Some PTAs, such as the Trans-Pacific SEP, require that any information obtained must be submitted to the disputing parties for comment. Under some agreements (e.g., the ASEAN–Australia–New-Zealand PTA), the


Dispute Settlement

panel has to ask the disputants before seeking outside information; the parties have a veto over such a request; and any information obtained has to be submitted to the parties for comment. Some PTAs, such as the China–New Zealand agreement, further require that if a panel takes information or technical advice into account in its report, it must also take into account any comments on that information by the parties. Claims regarding a breach of PTA rules may involve reliance on proprietary or business confidential factual data. Even information on government programs can be business confidential in nature; for example, information about Canadian government subsidies to the dairy industry was excluded from a WTO panel report (WTO 1999). Some WTO disputes (e.g., the dispute about the EU’s banana import regime and the aircraft subsidies disputes) have involved information extremely sensitive to the companies providing it. If PTAs are to be able to handle such disputes, negotiators may wish to consider requiring panelists and panels to respect the confidentiality of the data. Formalized expert groups. NAFTA, in Article 2015, authorizes panels to request a written report from a scientific review board on factual issues concerning environmental, health, safety, or other scientific matters raised by a disputing party; the Canada–Chile and Chile–Mexico PTAs contain similar provisions. These provisions have never been used. Parallel provisions in the WTO (DSU Article 13.2 and Appendix 4) also have never been used; WTO panels in cases involving health or safety issues have consulted individual experts, who did not draw up any group report. Duration of Panel Process The governments that have negotiated PTAs have shown a strong preference for speed in the panel process. For panelbased dispute settlement procedures that call for initial and final panel reports, PTAs’ notional deadlines for a panel to produce its initial report vary widely: 30 days in SACU–Mercosur; 60 days in Mercosur and the ASEAN Enhanced DSM; 90 days in NAFTA and the Canada–Peru PTA; 120 days in the Chile–U.S. PTA; and 180 days in the U.S.–Korea and Chile–Australia agreements. These PTAs typically allow two weeks for comments from the parties and then ask the panel to finalize its report within 30 to 45 days after the initial report. Stakeholders favor short deadlines. The consultations and other preliminary phases of a dispute, including panel selection, can take considerable time, and business stakeholders are almost never compensated for damage caused them by the breach of trade obligations. In practice, these deadlines may be more aspirational than real. So far,

481

NAFTA panel proceedings have taken well in excess of the prescribed time. Defending parties are often motivated to delay, and even complaining parties may prefer to take time to prepare. If the panelists cannot coordinate their timetables to schedule a hearing, or do not meet deadlines, there is little that the parties can do. Appeal, Correction, and Remand Where a trade agreement relies on ad hoc panels to settle disputes, the PTA parties may seek greater assurance that the decisions of successive panels will be consistent and legally sound. Such assurance may be essential to secure domestic acceptance of panel rulings. Tribunal systems such as the ECJ respond to the same concerns with appellate review, or provisions for revision or interpretation of past judgments. An appellate body involves incremental cost to the parties, but it generates public goods in the form of enhanced certainty and uniformity in the application of international trade law. The WTO and some PTAs now use two methods to prevent and correct panel error. The first method is to give the parties to a dispute an opportunity to comment on a panel’s report in draft form before the report is finalized; this innovation in CUSFTA was incorporated into the WTO DSU and has been adopted in many PTA ad hoc panel processes. The second method is appeal. The DSU includes an Appellate Body, which the EU required as a quid pro quo for accepting binding dispute settlement in the WTO. The EU has instituted a two-level process, with the General Court as a court of first instance for certain types of disputes, with appeal to the ECJ. Mercosur’s 2003 Protocol of Olivos created the Tribunal Permanente de Revisión (TPR), an appellate tribunal (box 22.1). The Olivos Protocol reacted to a number of difficult disputes and responded in part to smaller states’ concerns about compliance with Mercosur law (Whitelaw 2004). The TPR reflects a high level of institution-building ambition and helps enforce and build not only treaty law but also the decisional law being created by Mercosur institutions (Opertti 2004). The ASEAN Protocol on Enhanced Dispute Settlement Mechanism of 2004 calls for the ASEAN Economic Ministers to establish a seven-person Appellate Body patterned on the WTO Appellate Body. As of early 2011, this had not yet taken place. Labor, Environment, Financial Services, and Other Special Sectors As noted in earlier chapters of this volume, many PTAs provide special dispute settlement procedures for particular


482

Amelia Porges

Box 22.1. The Protocol of Olivos The Mercosur Protocol of Olivos established a new five-person Permanent Appeals Tribunal (Tribunal Permanente de Revisión, TPR). It consists of one arbitrator (with an alternate) appointed for a renewable two-year term by each of the four Mercosur members, plus a fifth arbitrator appointed for one three-year term by agreement between the members. The TPR’s permanent headquarters is in Asunción. Disputes between Mercosur members are normally first heard by an ad hoc arbitral tribunal, which provides its award within 60 days (extendable to a total of 90 days). Within 15 days after the award, any party to the dispute may bring a motion for review to the TPR. The TPR may consider only the legal issues dealt with in the dispute and the legal interpretations in the award, not issues of fact. It renders its decision within 30 days. If the dispute involves two members, it is heard by three judges, and if more, by five judges. (Whitelaw 2004). The TPR has heard two appeals. In one, it reversed the panel decision, and in the other, it ruled the request inadmissible. Under the Protocol of Olivos, parties to a dispute may also, by agreement, submit their dispute directly and in a single instance to the TPR; in that case, the TPR acts like a panel and issues a nonappealable award in 60 days, which may be extended by 30 days. The TPR also may rule on appeals by disputants regarding failure to comply with tribunal awards, or regarding the extent of suspension of concessions after a failure to comply, and it may provide opinions to the Mercosur Common Market Group on request.

subject matter. Special procedures may refer particular disputes to a political process for settlement, but even in the context of binding third-party dispute settlement, the parties may wish to bring to bear special expertise, to provide special opportunities to participate, to provide particular forms of redress, or to limit the possible scope of sanctions by a prevailing party. The key examples are labor, environment, and financial services. Labor and environment. Chapters 19 and 20 of this volume describe the substantive obligations, including dispute settlement, in those PTAs that deal with environment and labor issues. Such obligations exist in all U.S. PTAs concluded since NAFTA, in some Canadian PTAs, in New Zealand’s PTA with Thailand, in the Trans-Pacific SEP, in the EU–CARIFORUM EPA, and in the chapter on trade and sustainable development of the EU–Korea agreement. As Bartels (2009) observes, the treatment of these issues in North American PTAs has changed over time. These dispute settlement provisions can be grouped into four categories. 1. The side agreements to NAFTA—the North American Agreement on Labor Cooperation (NAALC) and the North American Agreement on Environmental Cooperation (NAAEC)—represent one model. They establish institutional frameworks for cooperation, require that domestic legislation adhere to high standards, and obligate each party to enforce and strive to improve its own legislation. Panel proceedings require a two-thirds vote of the three NAFTA parties. They are to be preceded by consultations and a report by a committee of experts, and they are only available in cases of persistent, traderelated patterns of failure to effectively enforce worker

safety, child labor, or minimum wage standards that are covered by mutually recognized labor laws (a failure that violates the NAALC), or to effectively enforce domestic environmental law relating to production of traded goods or services (a breach of the NAAEC). The panelists must be from a specialized labor or environment roster. If the panel agrees that such an enforcement failure exists, and if no remedial action is taken, the panel may ultimately set a monetary assessment, to be paid by the losing party into a fund to promote (depending on the sector) labor law enforcement or improvement of the environment or of environmental enforcement in the party complained against. The Canada–Chile PTA contains similar provisions (Bartels 2009). The side agreements also provide for citizen submissions claiming that a party is not enforcing its own laws. The NAFTA governments received 37 submissions on labor issues in 1994–2010, of which 24 concerned conditions in Mexico, 13 pertained to the United States, and 2 were against Canada (U.S. DOL 2010). The NAFTA Commission on Environmental Cooperation received 77 citizen submissions from 1995 through early 2011; of these, 39 focused on Mexico, 9 on the United States, 27 on Canada, and 1 on a cross-border Canada–U.S. issue (CEC 2011). The Canada–Costa Rica FTA also provides for citizen submissions, as well as government-government dispute settlement without fines or trade measures (Bartels 2009). 2. Under the Jordan–U.S. agreement, parties must not fail, through a sustained or recurring course of action or inaction, to effectively enforce domestic environmental or labor laws in a manner affecting trade between the parties. These labor and environmental obligations are


Dispute Settlement

enforceable through the same procedures as the rest of the agreement, but a side letter provides that they will not be enforced so as to block trade (Bartels 2009). 3. Seven other U.S. PTAs negotiated in 2000–07, with Australia, Bahrain, CAFTA–DR, Chile, Morocco, Oman, and Singapore, adopt the same standard as in the Jordan agreement. They also provide that parties may not weaken, reduce, or waive environmental or labor protections to encourage trade or investment. These obligations are enforceable through the same dispute settlement procedures as the rest of the agreement, but no trade retaliation is possible—only fines capped at US$15 million (adjusted for inflation). Fines are collected through suspension of concessions, if necessary, and are spent on labor or environmental initiatives in the territory of the party complained against. These agreements also create cooperative institutions and provide for receipt of input from the public. 4. In May 2007 the Bush administration agreed with the leadership of Congress (then controlled by Democrats) on elements that future free trade agreements must have in order to be considered by Congress. These elements include increased substantive standards for labor rights provisions and an enforcement standard like that in the Jordan agreement. The provisions are subject to the same dispute settlement mechanisms and penalties as in other provisions, but dispute settlement must be preceded by consultations in a specialized labor or environment council. The Peru–U.S. FTA and pending FTAs with Colombia, Korea, and Panama all follow this pattern (Bolle 2009). On July 30, 2010, the United States initiated the first formal PTA labor complaint, under the labor chapter of CAFTA–DR. In a letter signed by U.S. Trade Representative Ron Kirk and Secretary of Labor Hilda Solis, the United States formally requested consultations with the Guatemalan government regarding (a) failure by the Guatemalan Ministry of Labor to investigate alleged labor law violations or to take enforcement action when the ministry had identified a violation, and (b) failure by the Guatemalan courts to enforce Labor Court orders in cases involving labor law violations. The complaint expressed concerns about the Guatemalan government’s alleged failure to protect those attempting to exercise labor rights against violence and threats. It followed a submission by U.S. and Guatemalan unions and informal consultations that had been going on since January 2009 (Kirk and Solis 2010; USTR 2010). New Zealand has negotiated labor and environment side agreements to the Thailand–New Zealand FTA and the

483

Trans-Pacific SEP. In both, the labor obligations are only enforced through consultations. Dispute settlement provisions in the environment agreements provide for referring a dispute to the interested parties for a report. Those affected are obligated to implement the report’s recommendations (Bartels 2009). Historically, most EU PTAs have treated labor and environment as “matters for cooperation” (Bartels 2009). However, the EU’s Global Europe policy, announced in late 2006, calls for environment and labor to be part of the trade agreement negotiations. For instance, the chapter on trade and sustainable development in the EU–Korea FTA calls for high levels of protection in both areas and obligates both parties not to fail to effectively enforce environmental and labor laws “through a sustained or recurring course of action or inaction” and not to waive or derogate from its environmental or labor laws, regulations, or standards in a manner affecting trade or investment between the parties. Enforcement, however, consists exclusively of bilateral consultations and an advisory report by a group of experts. In the EU–CARIFORUM EPA, the labor and environment obligations in Chapters 4 and 5 of Title IV are enforceable through the agreement’s regular dispute settlement procedures, but only after separate procedures in the labor or environment chapters are pursued for at least nine months. These procedures call for bilateral consultations, possibly including advice from relevant international environmental bodies or the International Labour Organization (ILO), and may also include a report by a threemember committee of experts. In any ensuing dispute, at least two of the three arbitrators must have specific expertise on the subject matter and must be drawn from a special roster. The panel report must recommend how to ensure compliance with the EPA’s trade or environment obligations, and measures taken in case of noncompliance may not include suspension of EPA trade concessions. Separately, the agreement’s investment chapter (Article 72) obligates the parties to ensure that investors act in accordance with core labor standards and do not behave in a manner that circumvents international environmental or labor obligations in agreements to which the EU and the CARIFORUM states are parties. This obligation is subject to the agreement’s regular dispute settlement procedures. Financial services. As Stephanou (2009) observes, PTA parties have been particularly cautious about covering financial services because of regulatory sensitivities and strategic considerations. Countries that follow the GATS approach for services in their PTAs have used it for financial services as well, with special adaptations or a separate chapter expanding on the GATS Annex on Financial


484

Amelia Porges

Services. Others follow the NAFTA model, in which investment to provide services is treated like any other type of investment and has access to investor-state dispute settlement. Stephanou (2009) points out that an increasing number of countries prefer a dedicated chapter on financial services because it facilitates customizing the application of services disciplines in this area and allows financial sector policy makers to control negotiation and implementation of the obligations. Governments have demonstrated in their PTAs that they want special procedures for settling financial services disputes. As in the WTO, PTA provisions often require that panels for such disputes have specific regulatory or other financial sector expertise, and they prohibit trade retaliation against financial services in any dispute in any other sector. In NAFTA-model PTAs that have a separate financial services chapter, that chapter limits the scope of investor-state dispute settlement to claims regarding expropriation or transfer of payments. National treatment claims, for instance, are only subject to state-state dispute settlement, giving a host state additional flexibility to discriminate in favor of domestic financial services providers if its PTA partners agree (Sauvé and Molinuevo 2008). NAFTA-model financial services chapters also refer claims regarding prudential or monetary or exchange-rate measures for a consensus decision by a financial services committee composed of financial services regulators; if the committee agrees, its decision binds the tribunal. Other sectors. PTA negotiators can provide specialized dispute settlement for any subject they wish, or they can require that arbitrators for disputes on technical subjects have specialized expertise. For instance, the EU–Chile FTA contains a chapter on trade in wine that includes provisions on regulation of labeling and oenological practices. The chapter requires the parties to establish a roster of arbitrators with oenological expertise for disputes regarding obligations under the agreement. Participation in PTA Dispute Settlement and Enforcement This section reviews participation in PTA dispute settlement, including qualification and selection of decision makers, third-party participation, use of experts, and participation by civil society in the dispute settlement process. Qualifications and Selection of Decision Makers Selection of decision makers is a key issue for international dispute settlement; if governments are to give a third-party decision maker (a standing tribunal or an ad hoc panel)

power to make binding decisions that matter, the tribunal must be composed of people who are perceived as trustworthy, impartial, and confidence-inspiring. Negotiators solve this problem by specifying criteria for decision makers such as neutrality, geographic distribution, and professional expertise. They may also try to expedite panel formation by agreeing in advance on a roster of persons who meet the criteria. Standing tribunals. In a standing tribunal, judges are selected on the basis of certain criteria and some form of geographic distribution. The governments bound will need to agree on the judges’ terms of service, their payment, and the funding of the necessary infrastructure. The original model, the International Court of Justice (ICJ), consists of 15 judges elected to nine-year terms by the United Nations (UN) General Assembly and the UN Security Council. The Statute of the International Court of Justice requires that its judges be persons of high moral character who possess the qualifications required in their countries for appointment to the highest judicial office or who are lawyers of recognized competence in international law. Each judge participates in all cases. The Statute also requires that in the ICJ as a whole “the representation of the main forms of civilization and of the principal legal systems of the world should be assured.” If a state party to an ICJ case does not have a judge of its nationality on the Court, it may appoint an ad hoc judge for that case only. The European Court of Justice has one judge for each of the 27 member states and normally hears cases in panels of 3, 5, or 13. The judges must have the qualifications or competence needed for appointment to the highest judicial positions in their home countries. Both the ICJ and the ECJ are backed by an elaborate and expensive infrastructure of buildings, legal and support staff, libraries, and translators. The four judges of the Andean Tribunal (one per member state) also serve full time. Other standing tribunals, for ECOWAS, COMESA, and the EAC, are composed of member-state judges who serve part-time (Banjo 2007). The WTO Appellate Body consists of seven part-time members, appointed by consensus for a renewable term of four years, who must be “persons of recognized authority, with demonstrated expertise in law, international trade and the subject matter of the covered agreements generally” (DSU Article 17.3). They are geographically balanced through informal agreement. Members have included public international lawyers, trade lawyers, and diplomats with no formal legal training. A division of three members, determined randomly, considers each case. The Appellate Body has a small staff and shares in the infrastructure provided by the WTO.


Dispute Settlement

Ad hoc panels. The DSU requires that WTO dispute settlement panels be composed of impartial, “well-qualified governmental and/or non-governmental individuals” and lists types of acceptable experience (WTO litigation; service as a delegate, or in the WTO Secretariat, or as a senior trade policy official; teaching or publishing on trade law or policy). Many PTA dispute settlement mechanisms modeled on the DSU specify similar characteristics of impartiality and expertise. Some, such as the China–New Zealand PTA, also require that the panelists comply with the WTO DSU’s rules of conduct for panelists. NAFTA and other U.S. FTAs require compliance with a code of conduct to be established by the parties. Another issue is citizenship or nationality. In the WTO, citizens of parties or third parties to a dispute cannot serve on the panel, unless the parties agree otherwise. The most common model in PTAs is for each party in a bilateral dispute to select an arbitrator, who can be (and usually is) a national of that party. The parties to the dispute then select a neutral chair by agreement, with a fallback to selection by lot or by an appointing authority, as discussed below. Ad Hoc Panels and the Blockage Problem Ad hoc panels, as bodies created to settle a particular dispute, present particular moral hazard problems that the text of a PTA can and should anticipate and prevent. The central problem arises when a defending party refuses to cooperate with the process by declining to name its arbitrators or to cooperate with the panel selection process. The WTO’s DSU procedures have successfully overcome this problem. The WTO Secretariat takes the initiative to nominate panelists to the parties. If a panel has not been completed by agreement within 20 days from the decision by the Dispute Settlement Body (DSB) to establish the panel, then, if either party so requests, the WTO DirectorGeneral can and will select the missing panelists, in consultation with the WTO’s political leadership. Some PTAs deal with the failure-to-appoint situation by designating an appointing authority, such as the WTO Director-General, the Secretary-General of the Permanent Court of Arbitration in the Hague, or a regional secretariat.16 Other PTAs provide for the missing arbitrator or neutral to be selected by lot; this is the method chosen by the Japan–Mexico, Japan–Chile, and Japan–Thailand PTAs and by NAFTA and other U.S. FTAs. If negotiators choose selection by lot, the selection should be conducted by a body that is not controlled by the defending party. In practice, governments may wish a PTA panel, and its decision, to have the legitimacy that flows from consent. They may therefore be reluctant to actually use these

485

fallback mechanisms. But the existence of a fallback mechanism does provide an incentive to reach agreement. Panel selection can take considerable time. The panel selection process has been a significant obstacle for NAFTA disputes, according to Gantz (2006), who observes that the NAFTA dispute on cross-border trucking services was delayed for 15 months by panel formation and that in the NAFTA sugar dispute, the U.S. authorities declined for more than four years to appoint panelists. Rosters A roster can speed panel selection by providing a preapproved list of persons who are qualified and willing to serve. Since 1907, arbitral institutions, which now include the International Centre for Settlement of Investment Disputes (ICSID), the Permanent Court of Arbitration, and many others, have maintained rosters of arbitrators to facilitate dispute resolution (Schreuer 2001). In the WTO, DSU Article 8.4 provides for the maintenance of a roster of governmental and nongovernmental individuals qualified to serve on panels (WTO 1996b, 724). For special obligations in agreements (on labor, environment, financial services, or other designated topics), PTAs may require specialized rosters to ensure that the decision makers in a dispute have the necessary expertise. A roster of panelists can be open or closed. The WTO has an open roster; disputing parties may choose any panelists they wish. The WTO’s DSB accepts practically all names nominated by members. At the other extreme is a closed roster, like that provided for in the EU–Chile FTA. As required by that agreement, the EU–Chile Association Committee has established a list of 15 persons. Of these, five are Chilean, five are from the EU, and five, of neither nationality, are identified as possible chairpersons (European Commission 2007). The FTA provides that within three days of any panel request, the chair of the Association Committee must select by lot two arbitrators, one each from the EU and Chilean sublists, as well as a chair from the list of individuals identified as potential chairs. Panel selection takes days instead of months. (The initial list was not finalized until two years after the FTA entered into force, however.) Similarly, panelists for ad hoc tribunals for Mercosur disputes are selected from sections of a Mercosur roster; if a disputant fails to appoint its arbitrator, or if there is no agreement on the presiding arbitrator, the arbitrator in question is appointed by Mercosur’s Administrative Secretariat from the roster. The PTA rules can also favor panel selection from the roster—for instance, by barring any veto of panelists selected from the list—without excluding nonroster candidates. If


486

Amelia Porges

a roster is used, it is advisable that it remain valid until it is replaced. NAFTA provides for each party to select panelists from the roster who are not its citizens (“cross-selection”) but this innovation has not been picked up in any other PTA, including later U.S. FTAs. Some other PTAs, such as the ASEAN Enhanced DSM, provide for indicative lists modeled on that of the WTO. Many do not use a roster for panel selection at all, however, permitting governments to select the candidates that they prefer when the dispute arises. Panelist Ethics PTA provisions on the qualifications of panelists often include qualitative requirements designed to ensure impartiality. In December 1996 the WTO’s DSB adopted a code of conduct for panelists (WTO 1996b) that is also applied by the WTO Appellate Body. This code requires that panelists be independent and impartial, avoid direct and indirect conflicts of interest, and respect the confidentiality of WTO proceedings. The disclosures required by this code have become a routine aspect of panel disputes in the WTO. Influenced by the WTO example and by the requirement for a code of conduct in NAFTA, a number of PTAs call for panelists to adhere to a code of conduct to be agreed by the parties. These PTAs include the Singapore– GCC, Mexico–Northern Triangle, Chile–Colombia, Chile– Australia, Canada–Peru, and Chile–EU agreements; NAFTA; and all later U.S. PTAs. In addition, following the example of Article 18.1 of the DSU, PTA model rules of procedure or codes of conduct may prohibit ex parte contact with panelists, as do the ASEAN Enhanced DSM and the Singapore–GCC PTA. Plurilateral PTAs and Multiparty Disputes, Joinder and Consolidation, and Other Third-Party Participation When a dispute arises in a plurilateral PTA, another party to the PTA may wish to join the complaint or merely to observe and submit views. The reasons for wanting to do so may include commercial competition in the markets concerned, a desire to prevent discriminatory settlements, an interest in the interpretation of common PTA rules such as rules on market access or rules of origin, and concern for endeavors such as regional public goods. Third-party participation can also be a useful way for developing countries to build capacity in dispute settlement. Similar motives have built a rich practice of joinder and consolidation of disputes, multiparty cases (as in the EU banana import regime dispute), and third-party participation, under the

GATT (WTO 1996a) and the WTO. Rules for multiparty disputes also exist in, for example, NAFTA, CAFTA–DR, the Trans-Pacific SEP, and PTAs involving EFTA. NAFTA permits a third party to join as a complaining party as of right, if it delivers a timely notice to the disputing parties and the NAFTA Secretariat. The third party can then participate in the consultations, but if it fails to join the dispute, it is “normally” precluded from initiating or continuing a NAFTA or WTO dispute on the same matter, in the absence of a significant change in circumstances. The NAFTA Commission must consolidate two or more pending NAFTA disputes regarding the same measure and may consolidate other cases that are appropriately considered jointly. Similar provisions exist in the CAFTA–DR and Chile–Central America PTAs. The Trans-Pacific SEP Agreement requires consolidation of disputes on the same measure, and the Colombia–EFTA, China–ASEAN, and ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand PTAs express preference for consolidation or use of common arbitrators. Where there are multiple complaining parties, the panel selection procedure may be adjusted accordingly, as is done in NAFTA and the CAFTA–DR, Chile–Central America, and Mercosur agreements. Most plurilateral PTAs permit another PTA member to participate in dispute settlement consultations as of right; some make such participation conditional on consent by the disputing parties. Many also permit another PTA member to attend panel hearings, to make written and oral submissions to the panel, and to receive some or all written submissions of the disputing parties (as in WTO panel proceedings).17 Broader participation is not cost-free, of course. It involves costs for the third party or extra complainant and for the defending party, and it decreases the likelihood of early settlement (Busch and Reinhardt 2003). Transparency and Civil Society Participation One of the parties to a PTA negotiation may seek to have the PTA dispute settlement provisions incorporate elements of procedural transparency. WTO practice has been evolving since 1995 in the direction of increased transparency in dispute settlement, but views are still divided within the WTO as to whether to mandate such transparency. PTA practice varies widely, but it too has evolved substantially in recent years. Some U.S. PTAs now mandate considerably more dispute settlement transparency than the WTO. The WTO’s dispute settlement rules largely codify the informal, diplomatic, nontransparent practice under the GATT, which treated dispute settlement as a private negotiating process between the parties. The DSU provided that


Dispute Settlement

disputing parties could make their submissions and nonconfidential summaries public but made no other changes. Since 1998, the United States has advocated that all panel submissions be available to the public; that panel hearings be open to public observation, except where there is a need to protect confidential business information; and that panels accept amicus curiae submissions from the public or from nongovernmental organizations (NGOs). These proposals have gained at least partial support from the EU, Canada, and others, to help strengthen public support for trade liberalization. The United States has made all of its dispute settlement submissions since 1995 public; other members have made some of their submissions public; amicus briefs have been submitted and even considered; and in a number of WTO disputes, at the request of the parties, the panel or Appellate Body hearing has been open for public observation via closed-circuit television. Not all governments agree. As described by Mercurio and LaForgia (2005), some WTO delegations have argued that openness would undermine the character of the WTO as a forum for confidential discussion between governments, that it would burden members’ ability to participate effectively in disputes, and that allowing observers at hearings would lead to trials by media. Although almost all WTO members strongly criticized the Appellate Body for accepting amicus submissions in the asbestos dispute in 2000, later panels and the Appellate Body have continued to accept such submissions. Many developing countries continue to oppose amicus submissions as a resource burden. Direct participation by stakeholders and civil society. No government opposes all participation by civil society in dispute settlement. On the contrary, governments usually welcome stakeholder input and guidance on facts, commercial data, and negotiating priorities. WTO studies (Tussie and Delich 2005; Xuto 2005) illustrate the critical role played by developing-country stakeholders in disputes. Governments also have put in place organized structures for receiving stakeholder complaints.18 Moreover, PTA provisions on labor and environment have provided for receipt of public submissions on these issues; the first PTA labor dispute ever, initiated by the United States against Guatemala in July 2010, followed an April 2008 public submission by the AFL-CIO labor group in the United States and by Guatemalan unions, under the labor chapter of the CAFTA–DR PTA (USTR 2010). Practically all governments involved in trade disputes now expect stakeholders to hire or pay for legal counsel to assist the government. A few PTAs (Canada–Israel, EU–Chile, Canada–Chile, Chile–Central America) explicitly guarantee the right of parties to be assisted by counsel and impose conditions regarding the counsel’s conduct.

487

Complaints by stakeholders against governments. Articles 39–44 of the Mercosur Protocol of Olivos permit individuals or juridical persons to bring complaints against any Mercosur party for applying legal or administrative measures that have a restrictive, discriminatory, or unfairly competitive effect, in violation of the Treaty of Asunción or the associated agreements and legal instruments. Such complaints must be filed with the national section of the Common Market Group of the country in which the claimant resides or has its headquarters. If the national section supports the complaint, it must negotiate directly for 15 days to resolve the matter with the defending country’s national section. If the complaint is not resolved, it must be brought to the Common Market Group. Unless the Common Market Group rejects the complaint summarily by consensus, it must convene a group of three neutral experts, who are to report in 30 days. If the panel unanimously agrees with the complaint, any Mercosur party can demand that corrective measures be adopted, or that the dispute measure be annulled, and can then proceed to Mercosur state-state dispute settlement if the defending state does not comply within 15 days. If the panel’s report is not unanimous, the claim terminates. Any Mercosur party can bring the same complaint. Amicus curiae submissions. Civil society groups have argued that panels should consider not just the arguments presented by governments but also facts and arguments presented by others, even those who may be at odds with the governments participating in dispute settlement. If dispute settlement provisions are neutral regarding amicus submissions, presumably a panel could consider them. Some PTAs go further and explicitly favor consideration of amicus submissions. U.S. FTAs after NAFTA have required that panels consider requests from nongovernmental entities in the parties’ territories to provide written views that may assist the panel in evaluating the submissions and arguments of the parties. A number of other recent PTAs explicitly authorize the panel to accept and consider amicus submissions under certain conditions. For instance, the Trans-Pacific SEP and the EU–Chile, EU–Korea, Chile–Panama, Canada–Colombia, and Canada–Peru PTAs all permit amicus submissions, but only if timely (submitted within 10 days of panel composition), concise (not over 15 typed pages, including annexes), and directly relevant to the factual and legal issues before the panel. The submission must also describe the submitter, its activities, its source of funding, and the nature of its interest in the proceeding. The Canada–Peru PTA adds more requirements: in deciding whether to permit an NGO to make a submission, a panel must consider, among other matters, whether there is a public interest in the


488

Amelia Porges

proceeding, whether the NGO has a substantial interest in the proceeding, and whether the written submission would add a perspective, particular knowledge, or insight that is different from that of the parties. (A footnote clarifies that an interest in jurisprudence, in the interpretation of the PTA, or in the subject matter of the dispute is not enough to establish an NGO’s substantial interest.) An NGO submission may not introduce new issues to the dispute, must stay within the dispute’s terms of reference, and must avoid disrupting the proceeding. It must preserve the equality of the disputing parties, who must have an opportunity to respond. Transparency in the dispute settlement process. All U.S. PTAs after NAFTA have required that any dispute settlement submission (including written submissions, texts of oral statements, and other documents) must be made public within 10 days. Other PTAs authorize, but do not require, their parties to make their own submissions public; these include the Canada–Colombia, Canada–Peru, ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand, and Japan–ASEAN agreements. All U.S. PTAs after NAFTA have required that hearings in disputes are to be open to the public; the recent Canada–Colombia, Canada–Peru, and EU–Korea PTAs also require open hearings. The 2009 Japan–Switzerland PTA provides for open hearings unless either disputing party objects. In some other PTAs (the Trans-Pacific SEP and the EU–Chile agreement), hearings are closed unless the disputing parties agree otherwise. Alternative Enforcement and Dispute Settlement Methods Formal disputes take place only in exceptional cases; the universe of large and small trade disputes in a PTA is much larger. Statistics on dispute settlement, which record formal disputes, systematically understate the total number of disputes and the proportion of disputes that is settled. Most PTAs set up an institution or institutions to maintain the PTA, to address practical problems of PTA implementation and market access, and to provide a framework for further negotiations. These institutions may include joint committees or councils at the ministerial or senior official level to oversee the operation of the PTA. As Donaldson and Lester (2009) note, most such committees meet annually (and more often, as required), and a few meet biennially. They may be ad hoc or standing committees at the working level, or even joint public-private working groups. Maintaining these institutions requires a commitment of resources and personnel but can be economical and effective in resolving problems.

PTA institutions can provide a cost-effective channel for gathering information. Governments, and particularly those of resource-poor developing countries, normally do not know the details of a PTA partner’s trade or regulatory regime and may not have access to foreign legislation. Institutional contacts provide a way to obtain those facts. Cooperation within PTA institutions, and the regular contact that it implies, offer a means of building mutual confidence at the personal level, resolving routine trade irritants and minor issues, and negotiating further trade liberalization. Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC), for instance, has provided useful settings for dialogue and regulatory harmonization on customs and trade facilitation, chemical regulation, SPS measures, and automotive standards. Specialized Institutions PTA institutions can be particularly helpful for regional integration in complex issue areas or regulated industries. PTAs may establish specialized committees composed of regulators from each country. Contacts between regulators build trust in each other’s judgments, facilitating market access for regulated products or services. Some agreements provide an incentive to consult about issues in these technical committees by providing that such discussions will satisfy the usual requirement for consultations before recourse to a dispute settlement panel. The CAFTA–DR agreement, for instance, establishes committees on agricultural trade (Article 3.19), market access for goods, rules of origin, and customs issues (Article 3.30), SPS measures (Article 6.3), TBTs (Article 7.8), and financial services (Article 12.16). Each committee is able to consider routine market access issues. Consultations that have taken place in the TBT Committee may substitute for the first step in the dispute settlement process. The Chile–EU FTA establishes special committees on rules of origin (Article 81); standards, technical regulations, and conformity assessment (Article 88); and financial services (Article 128), as well as special consultation processes on SPS requirements, trade in wine, and trade in spirits; these can substitute for the consultation stage of dispute settlement proceedings (Articles 89, 129, Annex 5). Collective Enforcement Procedures The adversary process used in panel-based dispute settlement procedures, and triggered only if one PTA party brings a formal complaint against another, is not the only possible structure for enforcement of PTA obligations. In the EU, for instance, the predominant method of enforcement is through action by the supranational European


Dispute Settlement

Commission, which actively monitors member states’ actions and can bring enforcement actions before the EU’s courts even in the absence of any stakeholder or member state complaint. The secretary-general of the Andean Community has similar enforcement powers, as do the secretaries-general of COMESA and the EAC. Enforcement of this type is typically coupled with a standing tribunal empowered to adjudicate cases and impose sanctions. Where PTA members have pooled their sovereignty, as in the EU, such enforcement is strong, but where the members are less ambitious, it is not (Alter and Helfer 2011). As another example, ASEAN formally agreed in 2004 to establish an ASEAN Compliance Body (ACB), modeled on the WTO Textiles Monitoring Body. The optional compliance procedures (Yoshimatsu 2006) provide for group peer review of measures on a 90-day timeline. The ACB’s findings, drawn up by countries not party to the dispute, would not be binding but could serve as inputs for formal dispute settlement. However, the ACB does not appear to be operational at present. True multilateral sanctioning mechanisms (such as the UN Security Council) are quite rare, but collective persuasion mechanisms exist, including the specialized institutions described in the preceding subsection. The Montreal Protocol on the Protection of the Ozone Layer has such a mechanism in its Implementation Committee of 10 treaty parties, which regularly examines the treaty parties’ compliance reports, can receive other parties’ submissions, and can investigate and provide reports and recommendations to the Meeting of the Parties. But accounts indicate that it is ineffective at stopping even intentional and continuing violations (Yang 2007). Alternative Dispute Resolution: Good Offices, Mediation, and Conciliation Good offices, mediation, and conciliation all are traditional, widely recognized means of dispute settlement in public international law, as well as means of alternative dispute resolution (ADR) used in commercial situations. In each case, the parties cooperate voluntarily with a neutral, uninvolved third party. The third party, which, in a public international law context, could be an individual, an international organization, or a state, offers to assist the parties in settling their differences by negotiation and agreement, without arbitrating the merits of the legal claims concerned. The three types of ADR overlap but are distinguished by the extent and nature of the neutral party’s involvement. Article 5 of the WTO DSU provides for the possibility of good offices, mediation, or conciliation, if agreed to by the

489

“parties to a dispute.” The implication is that a dispute exists, but Article 5 has never been used during a dispute. The only known WTO mediation, in 2002 on European Community tariff preferences for canned tuna, was used in place of dispute settlement proceedings. Good offices may include using shuttle diplomacy, restoring contact between the parties, inviting them to meetings, or offering suggestions for settlement. In public international law, good offices can also include supervision of plebiscites or armistices. The UN Secretary-General, the Swiss government, and the Holy See have provided good offices in international conflicts. When an organization is called on to provide good offices, a senior official is often appointed to take charge of the issue. The Director-General of the GATT, through a designated representative, provided good offices in a number of instances, notably in the GATT dispute between Latin American countries and the EU regarding banana trade (WTO 1996a, 765–67). Gathii (2010) reports a recent dispute in COMESA over the Kenya Sugar Board’s nontransparent auctioning of import licenses for sugar, which affected import trade from COMESA members. In September 2009 COMESA sent to Kenya a Sugar Sector Safeguard Assessment Mission, which recommended elimination of auctioning as a nontariff barrier but apparently did not characterize the auctioning as a treaty violation. The intervention successfully persuaded Kenya to eliminate the auctioning. In mediation, the neutral party actively proposes options for settlement. The success of mediation depends very much on the mediator and on the willingness of the parties to make concessions (Merrills 1991, 29, 39–41). There are few widely reported cases of such mediation within a PTA. An example involving the EU is the 2002 WTO tuna mediation. Its success is attributable to a number of factors: the complainants’ ability to use leverage (a threat to block an EU waiver and indirectly prevent the launch of the Doha Round) as a means of obtaining the EU’s political commitment to the process; skilled mediation by a veteran, neutral dealmaker who suggested a practical solution; EU goodwill in promptly implementing a solution that increased the complainants’ market access; and the fact that the problem was framed not in terms of legal rights but as a question of impairment of interests (Porges 2003). In conciliation, the parties set up a permanent or ad hoc commission, or refer a dispute to a conciliator that is to impartially examine the dispute and suggest an acceptable settlement. Historically, conciliation has worked best when the main issues in a dispute are legal but the parties wish to settle (Merrills 1991, 77). For instance, conciliation was used to wind up the defunct original East African Community in


490

Amelia Porges

the 1980s. In response to a request by Kenya, Tanzania, and Uganda, a Swiss diplomat, Victor Umbricht, acted as conciliator to locate and value the EAC’s assets and liabilities, propose a formula for dividing them among the member states, and assist in an agreement winding up the organization (Merrills 1991, 65–72). A number of WTO-model dispute settlement systems in PTAs provide for these alternative dispute resolution mechanisms—because of a preference for consensual settlements, because negotiators view ADR as potentially fruitful and as free or low cost, or as a reaction against the time the WTO takes to determine rights and obtain compliance.19 For instance, Annex 14-A of the EU–Korea FTA sets out a mediation procedure for nontariff measures affecting industrial products. The parties can appoint a single mediator who is a subject matter expert and who would use an informal, confidential process to help the parties clarify the problem and its trade effects and reach a mutually agreed solution. The process is agnostic regarding rule violations. The mediation process, and the positions taken in the process, are confidential and would not be admissible in dispute settlement. The EU–CARIFORUM EPA similarly provides for nonbinding, confidential mediation by agreement between the parties to a dispute and for keeping a roster of mediators. As the COMESA example discussed above illustrates, ADR can serve as a useful channel through which the other members of a PTA can focus efforts in a practical, timeeffective way on removing a PTA member’s illegal trade barriers; the benefits of providing for ADR in a PTA are speculative but are very likely to exceed any cost. Formal ADR mechanisms may also offer a pathway for less formal diplomatic settlement. Further empirical research would be useful to determine the extent to which the parties to existing PTAs use ADR in practice, the disputes they use it for, the solutions produced by ADR, and factors leading to the success or failure of ADR. The use of ADR may well be underreported in the existing literature because it may not be characterized as dispute settlement and because the internal records of ADR proceedings are usually not publicly available. Implementation, Compliance, and Sanctions in PTA Dispute Settlement When an ad hoc panel, arbitral tribunal, or other third party produces its decision, the process of rights determination may be complete, but trade agreement enforcement is far from done. The WTO DSU procedures recognize this by outlining an organized compliance process. WTO compliance procedures begin by requiring the party found in breach of the agreement to set a deadline for

compliance, through negotiations or an arbitration process, with a 15-month benchmark for the compliance deadline. During the period before the deadline, the complying party must report on its actions, and after the deadline elapses, if compliance has not occurred, the Dispute Settlement Body will authorize the complainant to suspend concessions or other obligations under the WTO, in an amount equivalent to the nullification or impairment (trade damage) caused by the breach of the rules. If there is a dispute regarding compliance, it must be settled under the DSU by recourse (whenever possible) to the original panel; a dispute regarding the amount of the suspension of concessions must be arbitrated (whenever possible) by the original panel. PTAs’ approaches toward compliance vary. PTAs based on diplomatic or political settlement of disputes rely on settlement by agreement, not sanctions, and a failure to comply with an agreement settling a case simply means the start of another negotiation. In PTAs with standing tribunals, the tribunal remains available to enforce its judgments on a continuing basis, and a strong tribunal may have the power to impose sanctions on a noncomplying government. When the European Commission considers that an EU member state has not complied with a judgment by the ECJ, under Article 260 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the EU, the Commission may issue a reasoned opinion and then bring the case before the ECJ, specifying an appropriate fine; the Court may impose a fine on the member state as a lump sum or on a continuing basis during the period of noncompliance. In the Andean Community, Article 27 of the 1996 treaty establishing the Andean Tribunal requires a member state to comply within 90 days with any tribunal judgment of noncompliance with its Andean Community obligations, and authorizes the tribunal to determine suspension of benefits against a noncomplying state by the claimant state or any other member; the tribunal may decree other measures if such a suspension would be ineffective or would make the situation worse. Under Article 30 of the same treaty, private persons may use the tribunal’s verdict as sufficient basis for claiming compensation in domestic courts for damage caused to them by the noncompliance. Because member states have often responded with changes that did not bring them into compliance, the tribunal often mandates that a member state comply and refrain from employing any measure that is contrary to the tribunal’s judgment (SIEL 2010). A PTA ad hoc panel is convened for the limited purpose of deciding a dispute, or making recommendations and rulings to the parties. For this reason, it generally is not given the power to enforce its own decisions; either the PTA itself or the parties to the PTA authorize enforcement-related


Dispute Settlement

actions such as suspension of concessions. U.S. FTAs currently take the following approach, exemplified by the Peru–U.S. FTA. After the panel report, the parties are to agree on the resolution of the dispute. If they cannot agree on elimination of the noncompliance, they must negotiate on compensation. If they cannot agree on compensation, or if the complaining party considers that the defending party has failed to carry out a settlement agreement, the complaining party may notify the defending party that it will suspend concessions, and at what level, and may suspend concessions 30 days later. The defending party can then ask the panel to reconvene to rule on whether it has actually complied or whether the suspension is manifestly excessive. The same approach to compliance and suspension appears in a number of other PTAs—for instance, the Canada–Colombia, Canada–Peru, Canada–Israel, and Thailand–Australia agreements. Since 2001, U.S. FTAs have provided that concessions may not be suspended if the defending party provides timely notice that it will pay an annual monetary assessment to the complaining party. The assessment amount is set by agreement between the parties, with a fallback to 50 percent of the trade damage determined by the panel or by the complaining party. When the circumstances warrant, the PTA’s supervisory body can direct that the assessment be paid into a fund to be spent on initiatives to facilitate trade between the parties. This provision responds to criticism that trade retaliation damages the economies of both parties and harms innocent exporters in the other party, without achieving compliance. Some countries are unable to accept the U.S. approach to compliance and suspension of concessions because that approach affords very little flexibility regarding the period for compliance and relies in the first instance on the complaining party’s unilateral determination regarding compliance. These countries have adopted a different approach patterned on the DSU and on proposals tabled for DSU reform. The ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand agreement, for instance, provides for a DSU-like process for determining the postpanel compliance period by negotiation or by arbitration by the panel. Any disagreement about compliance must be resolved by the original panel, reconvened for this purpose, which hands down a quick ruling. If the defending party states that it will not comply, or if the panel has found a failure to comply, the defending party must negotiate on compensation, and if there is no agreement, the complaining party has the right to suspend concessions equivalent to the nullification or impairment. The defending party can ask the panel to reconvene again if it believes it has complied or that the level of the suspension is excessive (in some agreements, “manifestly excessive”). This pattern

491

is followed in, for example, the Chile–Japan, EU–Korea, India–Korea, Japan–Indonesia, Japan–Switzerland, and China–New Zealand agreements. In another variation, the original panel determines the level of the suspension when it rules on compliance (e.g., the ASEAN–India Framework Agreement on Dispute Settlement and the Australia–Singapore and China–Singapore PTAs). Some recent PTAs also provide explicitly for arbitration by the original panel if the defending party believes it has complied with the panel decision after concessions were suspended; examples are the China–New Zealand, EU–Korea, Korea–U.S., and Peru–U.S. agreements. The WTO DSU does not make explicit provision for this situation. PTA Disputes: The Experience We now examine disputes brought using PTA dispute settlement procedures and the written decisions that have resulted from them. A survey of PTA dispute settlement experience presents a mixed picture, complicated by a shortage of organized information and by a definitional question: at what point does a bilateral trade irritant ripen into the status of being a dispute? It is difficult to know the full extent of dispute settlement activity under any PTA, particularly those featuring settlement of disputes by negotiation or by ad hoc panels. Comparison with the WTO is useful and demonstrates that to some extent, disputes are being brought not in PTAs, but in the WTO. For PTAs with diplomatic or political dispute settlement, the true level of dispute activity is unknown and perhaps unknowable. Disputes do exist: for instance, the longrunning, legally focused dispute in the EC–Israel Association Agreement regarding the status of products made in the West Bank, East Jerusalem, the Golan Heights, and the Gaza Strip (see Harpaz 2004; Broude 2007). Because these agreements treat dispute settlement as a diplomatic issue, they do not systematically require that panel decisions (if any) or dispute outcomes be public. As Broude (2007) observes, the EU has no official list of disputes under its association agreements, and (at least at the time of that article) there is no group within the European Commission whose job is PTA dispute settlement. The true level of formal disputes in these agreements may also be low. In the EU’s association agreements, either party can block a panel proceeding. Moreover, the lack of detail in the agreements means that the disputing parties must agree on procedures before they can convene a panel, further increasing the burden on a would-be disputant. A dispute may simmer for years as a diplomatic issue without going through any formal process. Garcia Bercero (2006) mentions a long-standing dispute between Turkey and the


492

Amelia Porges

EU over nonadoption of the EU acquis on pharmaceuticals, and a dispute between the EU and Ukraine was blocked because of disagreement on how to split the costs of the arbitration. In a PTA with no third-party dispute settlement procedures at all—for instance, the Closer Economic Partnership Agreement between China and Hong Kong SAR, China—no dispute can even be considered unless both parties recognize it exists. There are also selection effects at work; as Broude (2007) observes, the EU’s partners in its association agreements have not even litigated much in the WTO. Thus, PTAs with diplomatic or political dispute settlement arrangements may attract governments that do not place a high value on enforcement. And in the EU context, some issues that might have been litigated in bilateral dispute settlement, such as the application to PTA members of rules of origin or border trade measures, have instead been litigated in the EU courts (see, e.g., ECJ 2010b). Tribunal-based PTA dispute settlement has an extremely broad range. The ECJ and its related supranational court system, benefiting from abundant resources at the EU level and linking to the domestic court systems in EU member states, have handled thousands of cases since 1952. By contrast, some African PTA tribunals, struggling with lack of infrastructure or resources, have little or no reported activity. The Andean Tribunal falls somewhere in the middle; 85 tribunal cases against members for noncompliance were initiated during the period 1987–2006, although much of the Andean Tribunal’s work focuses on relatively narrow intellectual property issues (Helfer and Alter 2009). The República Bolivariana de Venezuela’s 2006 withdrawal from the Andean Community eliminated a significant number of pending disputes about Venezuelan trade measures.20 Panel-based dispute settlement has also been quite variable, but there have been relatively few panel decisions or arbitral awards. There have been 25 known decisions in PTA formal proceedings, relating to 16 disputes, as listed in annex B. By comparison, in the WTO (1995 through March 3, 2011) there have been 423 WTO complaints; 136 panel reports; 78 Appellate Body reports; 28 panel reports and 18 Appellate Body reports in compliance proceedings; and 45 arbitration awards of various types.21 As in the WTO, the disputes formally raised under PTAs may substantially exceed the number of panel reports. Information available on dispute settlement under Chapter 20 of NAFTA indicates that whereas there have been only 3 reports of Chapter 20 panels from 1994 through March 1, 2011, at least 11 disputes in this period were settled or were abandoned after formal consultations. Why are PTA dispute levels so low? The first, and primary, reason is that so many PTAs are very new, and bene-

fits are still being phased in. It is natural for a PTA to postpone implementation for difficult sectors to the latest point possible (as for sugar and Mexican corn in NAFTA, for instance). If implementation is postponed, so are disputes about failure to implement. The implication is that an upsurge can be expected in the future. Second, PTA institutions, and the repeated contacts they involve, provide opportunities to avoid or proactively resolve disputes, diminishing the amount of trade conflict. Third, where a market access dispute can be brought either in the WTO or in a PTA, the WTO may be a more attractive forum for complainants for several reasons: the WTO’s familiar institutions and unblockable dispute settlement; the desire to be able to mobilize greater pressure against illegal denial of market access by suspending MFN tariffs and other WTO obligations (particularly where the PTA’s margin of preference is low); the larger pool of neutral panelists in the WTO; the broader issue scope of the WTO compared with some PTAs; the possibility of forming alliances; access to technical assistance such as the Advisory Centre for WTO Law; and the price tag. (The system cost of WTO dispute settlement is included in a member’s annual assessment, but in most PTAs the parties pay the panelists or pay for the cost of the tribunal.) The list of disputes in annex B, however, shows that some real issues can only be dealt with through PTA dispute settlement. Among them is denial of rights that are only created by the PTA agreement, such as preferential market access, or application of preferential rules of origin. Because Mercosur creates a right of free circulation, Uruguay brought and won a dispute in Mercosur against Argentina’s toleration of blockades on international bridges. Moreover, where the MFN tariff rate is high (35 percent for all the Mercosur countries), the PTA, and the enforcement of PTA rights, may be essential for obtaining real market access, as is shown by the high number of Mercosur panel proceedings listed in annex B. The Mercosur partners have fully litigated 12 disputes in the Mercosur forum, but they have only litigated three disputes against each other in the WTO, and two of those concerned antidumping measures not covered by Mercosur. Conclusions Since the beginning of the world economic crisis in 2008, protectionist measures have increased. PTA negotiation has increased as well, both as an economic life raft and in reaction to the lack of progress in multilateral trade liberalization. Reports on Mercosur, for instance, indicate an increase in pure border protection measures such as nonautomatic import licensing by Argentina, sectoral


Dispute Settlement

private voluntary restraints on exports to Argentina precipitated by import licensing, and up-valuation of imports using reference prices, which have affected almost 11 percent of Argentina’s imports from Brazil and 22 percent of its imports from China (INTAL 2010). And Mercosur is not the only jurisdiction involved: elsewhere there are also tariff increases, valuation issues, new preshipment inspection requirements, buy-local or buynational requirements, export restrictions on strategic materials, and other restrictions on trade in goods and services (Evenett 2010). All these measures have been put in place with no great apparent upsurge in PTA dispute settlement. Periods of sustained unemployment are a difficult time to push back against protection, but a rollback will be needed when recovery occurs—and in order for recovery to occur. Both WTO and PTA dispute settlements and institutions will have a part to play, and it will be a considerable challenge. Only time will tell whether these institutions will do their job in helping move governments away from crisis protectionism. Some practical conclusions of use to negotiators emerge from the discussion in this chapter. • Every PTA has to have a way of settling disputes, and a PTA that promotes growth needs enforcement provisions. Economic projections of the gains from a PTA are based on the assumption of 100 percent compliance with the PTA’s obligations. Ensuring compliance through enforcement is essential if the projected gains are to materialize. Even if no disputes are anticipated, enforcement provisions in a PTA reinforce the precommitment of the governments, make their promises more credible, and signal that the PTA is a solid platform for investment that will create jobs and economic growth. • PTAs create public goods, in the form of economic growth, transparency, and stability in the trading regime and an environment for trading goods and services based on the rule of law. They also promote open regionalism by strengthening institutions to make trade liberalization more transparent, less exclusionary to traders outside the PTA, and more accessible to firms investing in the PTA area. • The best time to reach agreement on fair rules to settle disputes is during the PTA negotiation, and in advance of any known dispute. • Even if the parties start with low ambitions, experience demonstrates that stronger, more ambitious rules can evolve later. • Most PTA dispute settlement procedures are now based on those in the WTO, but negotiators remain free to add

493

to, subtract from, or vary those procedures. There is no reason not to borrow from other PTAs’ creative and constructive ideas for addressing dispute settlement. Annex A. Dispute Settlement in CUSFTA and NAFTA Since the early 1990s, almost all dispute settlement procedures in preferential trade agreements have been based on referral of disputes for decision by ad hoc panels. This “NAFTA model” started with the Canada–U.S. Free Trade Agreement (CUSFTA) in 1988 and underwent minor revisions in NAFTA. The choices made in 1988 and 1993 remain influential today, and so it is useful to examine some key decisions and the rationales described by negotiators. The CUSFTA negotiations took place against a background of increasing trade conflict, particularly over U.S. trade remedies. According to Canada’s dispute settlement negotiator, Canada’s overarching goal for the negotiation was to obtain secure access to the U.S. market, which meant obtaining agreement to binding dispute settlement (von Finckenstein 2000). Canada sought a permanent tribunal that could bind both parties and issue remedial orders. The United States preferred ad hoc panels; it wanted to avoid creating a new bureaucracy or a tribunal that might see itself as an independent player in bilateral relations and might be perceived as telling the U.S. government what to do, and it wished to preserve a right to retaliate for noncompliance (Hart, Dymond, and Robertson 1994, 302). The FTA eventually included two dispute settlement procedures: binational review (Chapter 19) for antidumping and countervailing duty decisions, and government-government procedures for other disputes (Chapter 18). Chapter 18 was designed to address both sides’ objections about GATT dispute settlement procedures: the GATT process was too lengthy and could be delayed; it involved panelists from other countries who might not have the required expertise; and it provided no certainty regarding adoption or implementation of panel reports (von Finckenstein 2000). Chapter 18 provided a specific timetable, a standing roster of panelist candidates, and procedures designed to prevent most ways of blocking dispute settlement. It established a ministerial-level commission to oversee the functioning of the agreement and to administer disputes. In a provision sought by Canada, disputes could address not just actual measures but also proposed measures such as pending legislation. The dispute process included consultations, referral to the commission, and then referral to a panel for arbitration. Arbitration would be binding only if


494

Amelia Porges

the parties agreed (or if the disputes concerned safeguards). In CUSFTA disputes, as it turned out, the parties never chose nonbinding arbitration (von Finckenstein 2000). As for panel composition, CUSFTA called for fiveperson panels composed of two citizens from each side, chosen wherever possible from a standing roster. If a party failed to appoint its panelists, they would be selected from the roster by lot. The fifth panelist would be selected jointly and, in the absence of agreement, would be chosen by the four already selected panelists, or by lot. In practice, the two sides initially decided by lot (by coin flip) which party would choose the panel chair, and they then discussed candidates (Winham 1993). The panel then provided an initial report and a final report responding to any objections by the parties. If, after receipt of a final panel report, the commission was not able to reach agreement on a settlement within 30 days, and a party considered that its fundamental rights or benefits under CUSFTA would be impaired by implementation or maintenance of the measure at issue, that party would be free to suspend CUSFTA benefits of equivalent effect. At the time, the GATT did not automatically authorize suspension of concessions. Because CUSFTA incorporated by reference the GATT provisions on national treatment and quantitative trade restrictions, the negotiators also included a choice of forum provision. Article 1801(2) provided that disputes arising under both CUSFTA and the GATT could be settled in either forum, at the discretion of the complaining party, but that once an election of forum had been made by initiation of dispute settlement, the procedure initiated would be used to the exclusion of any other. This provision gave the complaining party the option to choose the strongest substantive and procedural rules, while duplicative proceedings were ruled out. NAFTA’s Chapter 20 continues the framework of CUSFTA Chapter 18, with a few changes. • Because NAFTA is trilateral, Chapter 20 gives intervention rights to a NAFTA party not involved in a dispute, including rights to attend hearings and to receive and make submissions; the procedures also allow for twocomplainant cases. • Chapter 20 makes provision for a consensus roster of 30 individuals experienced in law, international trade, and dispute settlement. Each party selects two panelists who are citizens of the other disputing country. The selection cannot be blocked if a panelist is on the agreed roster. • Because panels under Chapter 18 had visibly split on national lines, views in Chapter 20 panel reports are anonymous.

• The provision on choice of forum remains, and before a NAFTA party initiates a WTO dispute against another party on grounds substantially equivalent to those available to it under NAFTA, it must consult with the third party. If the three cannot agree, the dispute must normally be settled under NAFTA. A few changes responded to environmental concerns. NAFTA’s Article 103 gives precedence to obligations under five environmental treaties. In a WTO dispute between NAFTA parties, if the responding party claims that its measures are subject to Article 103, the complaining party can only bring a NAFTA dispute. Similarly, if a dispute between NAFTA parties concerns sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS) measures or environmental standards, the responding party can insist that the dispute be pursued only under NAFTA. A panel or a party can request a scientific review board on factual issues concerning environmental, health, safety, or other scientific matters. All of these changes responded to criticism that GATT panels and GATT rules were hostile to environmental regulation.

Annex B. PTA Dispute Settlement: Ad Hoc Panel Decisions In comparison with experience in the GATT and the WTO, ad hoc panel proceedings under preferential trade agreements (PTAs) have yielded relatively few completed decisions. The known panel decisions are listed and briefly described here. The sources for this annex are Davey (1996); Reich (1996; Grebler (2003); Tussie and Delich (2005); Gantz (2006); Barral (2007); SIEL (2010); Mercosur arbitral awards on the Organization of American States (OAS) website at http://www.sice.oas.org/Dispute/mercosur/ ind_s.asp; and newspaper reports.

Canada-U.S. FTA (1988–93), Chapter 18 1. Canada’s landing requirement for Pacific Coast salmon and herring, final report, October 16, 1989. At issue was a Canadian landing requirement that replaced GATTinconsistent export restrictions on certain fish. 2. Lobsters from Canada, final report, May 21, 1990. The case involved a U.S. ban on interstate transport or sale of whole live lobsters smaller than a minimum size. 3. Article 304 and the definition of direct cost of processing or direct cost of assembling, final report, June 8, 1992. The complaint concerned a U.S. rule that did not allow certain nonmortgage interest payments to count toward meeting CUSFTA rules of origin.


Dispute Settlement

4. The interpretation of and Canada’s compliance with Article 701.3 with respect to durum wheat sales, final report, February 8, 1993. The United States claimed that sales of durum wheat by the Canadian Wheat Board for export to the United States violated a CUSFTA ban on a government entity’s selling products for export at a loss (that is, at a price below the acquisition price of the goods, plus storage, handling, and other costs incurred with respect to those goods). 5. Puerto Rico regulations on the import, distribution and sale of ultra-high-temperature (UHT) processed milk from Quebec, final report, June 3, 1993. The case concerned milk standards in Puerto Rico.

495

(United States v. Canada, 1994); import restrictions on sugar (Canada v. United States, 1995); restrictions on small-package delivery (United States v. Mexico, 1995); restrictions on tomato imports (Mexico v. United States, 1996); the Helms-Burton Act (Mexico and Canada v. United States, 1996); Mexican rebalancing for U.S. safeguards on broom-corn brooms (United States v. Mexico, 1996); restrictions on sugar imports (Mexico v. United States, 1998); farm products blockade (Canada v. United States, 1998), bus service (Mexico v. United States, 1998); sport fishing laws (United States v. Canada, 1999); and restrictions on potatoes (Canada v. United States, 2001). Mercosur (Since 1998)

Israel–U.S. FTA Machine tools from Israel, settled informally after the panel report. The dispute concerned the U.S. decision to count imports of machine tools assembled by Sharnoa Ltd., in Israel, from parts from Taiwan, China, against the U.S. import quota for machine tools from Taiwan, China. NAFTA (Since 1994) 1. Tariffs applied by Canada to certain U.S.-origin agricultural products, final report, December 2, 1996. The dispute was brought by the United States against Canada’s maintenance of tariff-rate quotas on certain dairy and poultry products after full tariff elimination. Examining the relationship between the CUSFTA chapter on agricultural trade, the Uruguay Round tariffication of agricultural import quotas, and NAFTA, the panel found no breach by Canada. 2. U.S. safeguard action taken on broom-corn brooms from Mexico, final report, January 30, 1998. The dispute brought by Mexico concerned the application of global safeguard action on broom-corn brooms to imports of such brooms from Mexico. The panel found the measure in breach. 3. Cross-border trucking services, final report, February 6, 2001. In a dispute brought by Mexico, the panel found a U.S. breach of the NAFTA commitment to permit operation of Mexican trucking firms in four U.S. border states. After U.S. congressional action terminating the pilot program for Mexican trucking, Mexico, on March 19, 2009, announced suspension of NAFTA concessions (i.e., an increase in tariffs to most favored nation, or MFN, levels) on imports of 90 products from the United States. Other matters settled or abandoned after consultations but before panel proceedings concerned uranium exports

1. Application by Brazil of restrictive measures to trade with Argentina, award, April 28, 1999. The panel found that Brazilian import-licensing requirements on imports from Argentina breached the Mercosur treaty and recommended compliance by December 31, 1999. 2. Subsidies on production and export by Brazil of pork to Argentina, award, September 27, 1999. The panel rejected claims by Argentina regarding a system for corn stocking and Brazil’s advances on exchange contracts. It found that use of the PROEX export-financing program by Brazil was only acceptable for capital goods. 3. Application by Argentina of safeguard measures on textiles from Brazil, award, March 10, 2000. The panel found that Argentina’s application of safeguards to textiles was incompatible with the Mercosur legal regime and ordered revocation of the safeguard measure within 15 days. Brazil brought a complaint about the same textile safeguard to the WTO Textiles Monitoring Body and requested a WTO panel (WT/DS190), which was established on March 20, 2000. The parties notified a settlement to the WTO in June 2000. 4. Application of antidumping measures on imports of whole chickens from Brazil, award, May 21, 2001. The panel found that Mercosur law did not regulate the application of antidumping measures and rejected the claim by Brazil. Brazil then took the same dispute to the WTO (WT/DS241) and prevailed there. 5. Market access restrictions in Argentina on bicycles imported from Uruguay, award, September 23, 2001. Argentina treated Uruguayan bicycles made by one company as non-Mercosur in origin and therefore subject to the common external tariff. The panel ruled that this measure violated Argentina’s Mercosur obligations and ordered its revocation and the restoration of market access.


496

Amelia Porges

6. Brazilian import ban on remolded tires from Uruguay, award, January 9, 2001. The panel found that Brazil’s ban on imports of remolded tires was incompatible with the Mercosur standstill on new trade restrictions. Brazil later defended related measures in the WTO, raising environmental defenses not mentioned in the Mercosur proceedings. 7. Barriers to entrance of Argentine phytosanitary products into the Brazilian market, award, April 9, 2002. The panel found that Brazil had failed to implement in its domestic law five Mercosur Common Market Group resolutions designed to create a streamlined phytosanitary system for evaluating and registering food. It found that Brazil was obligated to implement these measures within a reasonable period of time and that six years was not reasonable; the panel ordered enactment within 120 days. 8. Application of Uruguay’s specific internal taxes on the sale of cigarettes, award, May 21, 2002. The panel found that Uruguay’s method of calculating taxes on imported cigarettes discriminated against Paraguayan cigarettes, denying national treatment. It ordered Uruguay to cease discrimination within six months. 9. Uruguayan subsidies for processing of wool, award. April 3, 2003. The panel found that Uruguayan export subsidies for processed wool products exported to Mercosur were inconsistent with Mercosur law and had to be eliminated within 15 days. 10. Discriminatory and restrictive measures by Brazil on trade in tobacco and tobacco products, award, August 5, 2005. Uruguay brought a complaint concerning a Brazilian decree raising tariffs on tobacco and tobacco products to 150 percent. Brazil repealed the decree during the proceedings. 11. Argentine ban on imports of remolded tires, award, October 25, 2005. In the first case under the Protocol of Olivos, the panel found that the Argentine ban was consistent with Mercosur law. 12. Appeal by Uruguay of award on Argentine ban on imports of remolded tires, award, December 20, 2005. The appellate tribunal reversed the award, finding that the Argentine measure was incompatible with Mercosur laws. 13. Request for ruling regarding excess in compensatory measures in the dispute between Uruguay and Argentina on the prohibition of imports of remolded tires from Uruguay, award, June 8, 2007. The appellate tribunal found that the Uruguayan compensatory measure was proportional and lawful. 14. Review of tribunal decision regarding Argentine compliance with the tribunal award on remolded tires, award,

April 26, 2008. The tribunal found that Argentina had not brought itself into compliance and that until it did, Uruguay had the right to maintain compensatory measures. 15. Failure by the Argentine state to adopt appropriate measures to prevent and/or cease impediments to free circulation caused by blockages in Argentine territory of access roads to the international bridges General San Martín and General Artigas, which connect Argentina and Uruguay, award, September 6, 2006. Uruguay challenged Argentina’s failure to act against environmental groups that blocked international bridges between Uruguay and Argentina from December 2005 to May 2006 to protest the construction of pulp mills in Uruguay. Uruguay argued that the blockage injured imports, tourism, and transport, in violation of Mercosur guarantees of free circulation of goods, services, and factors of production via the elimination of quantitative restrictions and measures of equivalent effect. The panel largely agreed. The underlying dispute concerned Argentina’s objections to the construction of pulp mills in Uruguay, which Argentina separately appealed to the International Court of Justice. 16. Interlocutory appeal by Argentina objecting to selection of the panel chairman in the free circulation dispute, award, July 6, 2006. The tribunal rejected Argentina’s appeal as inadmissible under Mercosur rules and assessed all costs and expenses of the proceeding against Argentina. Other Chilean price bands (application of price-band tariffs on imports of vegetable oils). (a) Bolivia brought a dispute against Chile in 2000 under Chapter XIII of the Bolivia–Chile (LAIA/ALADI) Economic Complementation Agreement 22, which provides that a dispute settlement panel decision is fully binding on the parties. Chile then reimbursed the safeguard duties collected. (b) Argentina brought a complaint in 2000 under the Administrative Commission of the Mercosur–Chile (LAIA/ALADI) Economic Complementation Agreement 35, which provides that a panel decision is nonbinding. After Argentina prevailed but Chile failed to comply, in October 2000 Argentina brought a dispute in the WTO (WT/DS207, Chile–Price Band System and Safeguard Measures Relating to Certain Agricultural Products), and prevailed in 2002. Argentina later prevailed in WTO compliance proceedings in 2007 but has not suspended concessions.


Dispute Settlement

Notes The views expressed herein do not represent those of any present or past client or employer. 1. CUSFTA and NAFTA panel decisions are available from many sources, including the NAFTA Secretariat website, http://www.nafta-secalena.org/. Panel decisions of CUSFTA, NAFTA, and Mercosur, as well as the texts of PTAs involving Western Hemisphere countries, are available at the website of the Organization of American States (OAS) Foreign Trade Information System, http://www.sice.oas.org/. 2. During the period 1996–2000, the OAS Trade Unit prepared an inventory of dispute settlement in the Western Hemisphere (FTAA 2000), as an input for the Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) Negotiating Group on Dispute Settlement. The FTAA negotiations have been stalled since 2003, but the inventory remains a useful snapshot of these provisions as they stood in 2000. Considerable information on dispute settlement and institutions in Latin America and the Caribbean is available at the websites of Mercosur, the Andean Community (CAN), the Central American Court of Justice, the Caribbean Court of Justice, and regional institutions, including the OAS, the Inter-American Development Bank (IADB), the secretariat of the Latin American Integration Association/ Asociación Latinoamericana de Integración (LAIA/ALADI), and the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean/Comisión Económica para América Latina (ECLAC/CEPAL). The last-named organization maintains a database on trade agreement dispute settlement, “Base de Datos Integrada de Controversias Comerciales de América Latina y el Caribe/Integrated Database of Trade Disputes for Latin America and the Caribbean,” http://badicc.eclac.cl/. 3. CAN, “Procesos del Tribunal de Justicia: Acciones de Incumplimiento” (updated list of all Andean Tribunal noncompliance proceedings), http://www.comunidadandina.org/canprocedimientosinternet/ListaEx pedientes11.aspx?CodProc=7&TipoProc=%27S%27. 4. Ibid. 5. Andean Community Decision 680 of 2007 (authorizing ATJ budget for fiscal year 2008), http://www.comunidadandina.org/norma tiva/dec/D680.htm. 6. Investir en Zone Franc (IZF) website, http://www.izf.net/pages/ institutions-afrique---zone-uemoa-et-cemac/2199. The site contains information on trade and investment in the Central and West African franc zones, including the legislation and jurisprudence of WAEMU/ UEMOA and CEMAC. Information on legal systems in francophone Africa is also found at http://www.archive.org. 7. African International Courts and Tribunals (AICT), http://www .aict-ctia.org/. 8. The term “nonviolation nullification or impairment” comes from the pioneering work by Robert E. Hudec, The GATT Legal System and World Trade Diplomacy (Hudec 1975). 9. Nonviolation remedies apply as follows in the PTAs studied: Chile–Japan, only for the chapters on trade in goods; India–Korea, Korea–Singapore, Panama–Singapore, Canada–Costa Rica, Canada–Chile, Canada–Colombia, and Chile–Peru, goods and services; Panama– Taiwan, China, goods, services, and TBTs; El Salvador–Honduras– Taiwan, China, goods, services, SPS measures, and TBTs; Chile–Central America, goods, services, TBTs, and aviation; Chile–Colombia and the Trans–Pacific SEP, goods, services, TBTs, and procurement; Nicaragua– Taiwan, China, goods, services, TBTs, SPS measures, and IPRs; and Chile–Australia, goods, services, TBTs, procurement, and IPRs. 10. Examples include the general cooperation chapters in the following PTAs: China–New Zealand, Japan–Mexico, Japan–Malaysia, Japan– Philippines, Japan–ASEAN, ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand, Australia– Thailand, and Korea–Singapore. 11. Examples include intellectual property cooperation provisions in the Japan–Philippines and Japan–Thailand PTAs and the competition policy cooperation obligations of the Australia–Chile, Australia– Thailand, ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand, Australia–U.S., Peru–U.S., and SACU–EFTA PTAs.

497

12. This is the case for the Japan–Mexico, Japan–Chile, Australia– Chile, ASEAN–Australia–New Zealand, Chile–U.S., and Singapore–U.S. agreements. 13. Res judicata is the legal doctrine that once a case has been determined, neither party can bring the same claims regarding the same subject matter against the other in another court. Lis alibi pendens is the legal doctrine that proceedings regarding the same facts cannot be commenced in a second court if the lis (i.e., action) is already pendens (pending) in another court. 14. The two disputes brought under CUSFTA rather than the GATT were those on Canada’s landing requirement for Pacific Coast salmon and herring (final report October 16, 1989) and on lobsters from Canada (final report May 21, 1990). 15. PTAs that require model rules of procedure include NAFTA and all later U.S. PTAs; the Mercosur Protocol of Olivos; the Singapore–GCC, Chile–EU, Chile–Australia, Chile–Colombia, Chile–Central America, ASEAN–China, and Korea–Singapore PTAs; the ASEAN Enhanced DSM; and the Trans–Pacific SEP. 16. Appointing authorities named in PTAs include the WTO Director-General (e.g., the China–New Zealand, ASEAN–Japan, Japan– Malaysia, Japan–Vietnam, and New Zealand–Singapore PTAs and the Trans-Pacific SEP), the Secretary-General of the Permanent Court of Arbitration in the Hague (e.g., the Japan–Switzerland and Canada–EFTA PTAs), or a regional secretariat (the Mercosur Administrative Secretariat for disputes under the Mercosur Protocol of Olivos, and the ASEAN Secretary-General for the ASEAN Enhanced DSM). 17. Participation by another PTA member is permitted by NAFTA, the ASEAN Enhanced DSM, the Trans-Pacific SEP, and the ASEAN– Australia–New Zealand, Canada–EFTA, Colombia–EFTA, Japan–ASEAN, China–ASEAN, Chile–Central America, and CAFTA–DR agreements. 18. Examples of provisions for stakeholder input are the EU Trade Barriers Regulation, U.S. Section 301, and China’s analogous legislation. 19. Examples of PTAs with provisions for alternative dispute resolution include China–New Zealand (Article 187), Thailand–Australia (Article 1803), Singapore–Australia (Article 16.3), the Trans-Pacific SEP (Article 15.5), NAFTA (Article 2007) and later U.S. FTAs, and the ASEAN Enhanced DSM, which authorizes good offices, mediation, or conciliation by the ASEAN secretary-general (Article 4). 20. CAN, “Procesos del Tribunal de Justicia: Acciones de Incumplimiento.” 21. “Facts and Figures on WTO Dispute Settlement,” http://www .worldtradelaw.net.

Bibliography ACWL (Advisory Centre on WTO Law). 2007. “Decision 2007/7 Adopted by the Management Board on 19 November 2007: Billing Policy and Time Budget.” ACWL/MB/D/2007/7, ACWL, Geneva. http://www .acwl.ch/e/documents/ACWL-MB-D-2007-7.pdf. Alter, Karen J., and Laurence R. Helfer. 2011. “Legal Integration in the Andes: Law-Making by the Andean Tribunal of Justice.” SSRN: http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1757772. Forthcoming in European Law Journal 17 (5). Apaza, Pamela. 2006. “The Interaction between the Dispute Settlement Mechanisms of the American Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO.” Master’s thesis, World Trade Institute, Bern. APEC (Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation). 2004. “Best Practices for RTAs/FTAs in APEC.” 2004/AMM/003, 16th APEC Ministerial Meeting, Santiago, Chile, November 17–18. ———. 2008. “Managing the Noodle Bowl: The Fragility of East Asian Regionalism.” Singapore Economic Review 53 (3): 449–78. Banjo, Adewale. 2007. “The ECOWAS Court and the Politics of Access to Justice in West Africa.” Africa Development 32 (1): 69–87. Barral, Welber. 2007. “The Brazilian Experience in Dispute Settlement.” ECLAC Project Documents Collection, UN Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean, Santiago.


498

Amelia Porges

Bartels, Lorand. 2009. “Social Issues: Labour, Environment and Human Rights.” In Bilateral and Regional Trade Agreements: Commentary and Analysis, ed. Simon Lester and Brian Mercurio. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Blackwood, Robin. 2008. “Report on International Organizations: Mercado Comúndel Sur/Southern Common Market.” Report on Mercosur PTR Decision of April 2008 on Argentina Remolded Tires Dispute, American Society of International Law, Washington, DC. http://www .asil.org/rio/mercosur.html. Bolle, Mary Jane. 2009. “Overview of Labor Enforcement Issues in Free Trade Agreements.” Report Rs22823, Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress, Washington, DC. Bolle, Mary Jane, and M. Angeles Villarreal. 2009. “Peru Trade Promotion Agreement: Labor Issues.” Report Rs22521, Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress, Washington, DC. Bown, Chad, and Bernard Hoekman. 2007. “Developing Countries and Enforcement of Trade Agreements: Why Dispute Settlement Is Not Enough.” CEPR Discussion Paper 6459. Centre for Economic Policy Research, London. http://www.cepr.org/pubs/dps/DP6459.asp. Broude, Tomer. 2007. “From Pax Mercatoria to Pax Europea: How Trade Dispute Procedures Serve the EC’s Regional Hegemony.” In Economics of European Union Law, ed. Paul B. Stephan, 319–34. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar. Also available as bepress Legal Series Working Paper 650, http://law.bepress.com/expresso/eps/650. ———. 2009. “Regional Economic Integration in the Middle East and North Africa: A Primer.” Research Paper 12–09, Hebrew University of Jerusalem. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1333292. Busch, Marc, and Eric Reinhardt. 2003. “The Evolution of Dispute Settlement.” In Trade Policy Research 2003, ed. John M. Curtis and Dan Ciuriak. Ottawa: Department of Foreign Affairs and International Trade. Cameron, Maxwell, and Brian Tomlin. 2002. The Making of NAFTA: How the Deal Was Done. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. CAN (Comunidad Andina/Andean Community). 2008a. “Manual de Procedimientos del Sistema Andino de Solución de Controversias.” Secretaría General de la Comunidad Andina, Lima. http://www.comu nidadandina.org/public/libro_Manual.pdf. ———. 2008b. “Decision 680: Presupuesto del Tribunal de Justicia de la Comunidad Andina para el año 2008.” CAN Commission, Lima. http://www.comunidadandina.org/normativa/dec/dectema_inst_pres .htm. Cárdenas, Emilio J., and Guillermo Tempesta. 2001. “Arbitral Awards under Mercosur’s Dispute Settlement Mechanism.” Journal of International Economic Law 4 (2, March): 337–66. CCJ (Caribbean Court of Justice). 2008. “Annual Report 2007–2008. Appendix: Financial Statements of the Caribbean Court of Justice.” CCJ, Port of Spain. http://www.caribbeancourtofjustice.org/annualre port0708.html. CEC (Commission on Environmental Cooperation). 2011. “Registry of Citizen Submissions.” NAFTA Commission on Environmental Cooperation, Montreal, Quebec. http://www.cec.org. Accessed February 7, 2011. CEPAL/ECLAC (Comisión Económica para América Latina/Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean). 2006. “Reducir la Incertidumbre Juridica, Un Desafio de la Integración Subregional en America Latina y el Caribe.” Boletin FAL (Facilitatión del Comercio y el Transporte en America Latina y el Caribe)” 235 (March 2006). Santiago: CEPAL/ECLAC. Choi, Won Mog. 2004. “Making a Better Dispute Settlement Mechanism for Regional Trade Agreements: Lessons of Integration Efforts in East Asia.” In WTO and East Asia: New Perspectives, ed. Mitsuo Matsushita and Dukgeun Ahn. London: Cameron May. ———. 2007. “Legal Analysis of Korea: ASEAN Regional Trade Integration.” Journal of World Trade 41 (3): 581–603. COMESA (Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa). 2000. “Official Gazette of COMESA.” COMESA, Lusaka. http://about.comesa.int/ attachments/062_2000%20Gazette%20Vol.%206%20No5.pdf.

———. 2009. “COMESA Court of Justice.” COMESA, Lusaka. http:// about.comesa.int/lang-en/institutions/court-of-justice. Daily Independent (Lagos). 2011. “Ecowas Court Rules on Oil Pollution: Says FG, NNPC Can Be Sued.” January 19. Damro, Chad. 2006. “The Political Economy of Regional Trade Agreements.” In Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO Legal System, ed. Lorand Bartels and Federico Ortino. New York: Oxford University Press. Davey, William. 1996. Pine & Swine: Canada–United States Trade Dispute Settlement. The FTA Experience and NAFTA Prospects. Ottawa: Centre for Trade Policy and Law. Donaldson, Victoria, and Simon Lester. 2009. “Dispute Settlement.” In Bilateral and Regional Trade Agreements: Commentary and Analysis, ed. Simon Lester and Brian Mercurio. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. EAC (East African Community). 2009. “East African Court of Justice: Information, Documentation, Rulings, Judgments and Advisory Opinions.” EAC, Arusha, Tanzania. http://www.eac.int/eacj.html. ———. 2010. “EALA Passes Budget Estimates for FY 2010/2011.” Press release, May 3, EAC, Arusha, Tanzania. http://www.eac.int/compo nent/content/article/1-latest-news/449-press-release-eala-passes-eacbudget-estimates-of-us-59963040-for-financial-year-20102011.html. East African (Nairobi). 2006. “COMESA Court Faces Legal, Funding Woes.” March 29. Echandi, Roberto. 2004. “Settlement of Trade Disputes between States: The Experience of Central American Countries.” In Inter-Governmental Trade Dispute Settlement: Multilateral and Regional Approaches, ed. Julio Lacarte and Jaime Granados. London: Cameron May. ECJ (European Court of Justice). 2010a. Annual Report 2009 of the Court of Justice of the European Communities. Luxembourg: ECJ. http://curia.europa.eu/jcms/jcms/Jo2_7000/. ———. 2010b. Brita GmbH v. Hauptzollamt Hamburg-Hafen, Case C-386/08, OJ C 100/4, April 17, Luxembourg. EFTA (European Free Trade Association) Court. 2009. “Financial Statements for 2008.” EFTA Court, Luxembourg. http://www.eftacourt.int/ index.php/court/mission/financial_statement/. Essien, Victor. 2006. “Regional Trade Agreements in Africa: A Historical and Bibliographic Account of ECOWAS and CEMAC.” Hauser Global Law School Program, New York University, New York. http://www .nyulawglobal.org/globalex/CEMAC_ECOWAS.htm. EU (European Union). 2010. “Budget on Line.” EU, Brussels. http://eurlex.europa.eu/budget/www/index-en.htm: Draft 2011 Budget, Section 4 on Court of Justice, at http://eur-lex.europa.eu/budget/data/DB_ 2011/EN/SEC04.pdf. European Commission. 2007. “Proposal for a Council Decision on a Community Position within the EU–Chile Association Committee on the Establishment of a List of Arbitrators as Required by Article 185 Paragraph 2 of the Agreement Establishing an Association between the European Community and its Member States, of the One Part, and the Republic of Chile, of the Other Part.” COM(2007)47, February 7, OJ C 138/9, June 22, 2007, Brussels. ———. 2009. “26th Annual Report on the Monitoring and Application of Community Law.” COM(2009) 675, European Commission, Brussels. http://ec.europa.eu/community_law/infringements/infringements_a nnual_report_26_en.htm. Evenett, Simon J., ed. 2010. “Will Stabilisation Limit Protectionism? The 4th GTA Report. A Focus on the Gulf Region.” Global Trade Alert, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London. Fiorentino, Roberto V., Luis Verdeja, and Christelle Toqueboeuf. 2006. “The Changing Landscape of Regional Trade Agreements: 2006 Update.” Discussion Paper 12, World Trade Organization, Geneva. Foroutan, Faezeh. 1992. “Regional Integration in Sub-Saharan Africa: Experience and Prospects.” Policy Research Working Paper 992, World Bank, Washington, DC. Francois, Joseph, and Miriam Manchin. 2009. “Economic Impact of a Potential Free Trade Agreement (FTA) between the European Union and the Commonwealth of Independent States.” CASE (Center for


Dispute Settlement

Social and Economic Research), Warsaw. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1393697. FTAA (Free Trade Area of the Americas). 2000. “Inventory of Dispute Settlement Mechanisms, Procedures and Legal Texts Established in Existing Trade and Integration Agreements, Treaties and Arrangements in the Hemisphere and in the WTO.” FTAA ngds/w/08/Rev.4, February 7. http://www.ftaa-alca.org/ngroups/NGDS/publications/dsw8r4_e.asp. Gama Sá Cabral, Jeanine, and Gabriella Giovanna Lucarelli de Salvio. 2008. “Considerations on the Mercosur Dispute Settlement System and the Impact of Its Decisions on the WTO Dispute Settlement System.” Journal of World Trade 42 (6): 1013–40. Gantz, David. 2006. “The United States and NAFTA Dispute Settlement: Ambivalence, Frustration and Occasional Defiance.” Arizona Legal Studies Discussion Paper 06-16, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=918542. Garcia Bercero, Ignacio. 2006. “Dispute Settlement in European Union Free Trade Agreements: Lessons Learned?” In Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO Legal System, ed. Lorand Bartels and Federico Ortino. New York: Oxford University Press. Gathii, James Thuo. 2010. “African Regional Trade Agreements as Flexible Legal Regimes.” North Carolina Journal of International Law and Commercial Regulation 35 (3, Spring). SSRN: http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1622274. Gómez, R., Hernando Jose, and Javier Gamboa.2007. “Cambios institucionales para la negociación del TLC de Colombia con los EEUU y derivados de su implementación.” Colección de documentos de proyecto, LC/W.146, Comisión Económica para América Latina/ Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEPAL/ECLAC), Santiago. Gonzalez, Anabel. 2006. “La solución de controversias en los acuerdos regionales de America Latina con paises desarrollados.” Serie Comercio Internacional 68, Division de Comercio Internacional y Integracion, LC/L.2525-P, Comisión Económica para América Latina/Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEPAL/ECLAC), Santiago. Goode, Walter. 2005. Negotiating Free-Trade Agreements: A Guide. Canberra: Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade, Australia. http://www.dfat.gov.au/publications/negotiating_ftas/index.html. Granados, Jaime, and Ann Casanova. 2004. “Treatment of Asymmetries in Size and Development in Trade Agreements: Some Suggestions for Regional North-South Dispute Settlement Negotiations.” In Inter-Governmental Trade Dispute Settlement: Multilateral and Regional Approaches, ed. Julio Lacarte and Jaime Granados. London: Cameron May. Grebler, Eduard. 2003. “Dispute Settlement: Regional Approaches, 6.2 Mercosur.” Module for the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) Course on Dispute Settlement in International Trade, Investment, and Intellectual Property, UNCTAD/EDM/ Misc.232/Add.28, United Nations, New York and Geneva. Guira, Jorge. 2000. “Mercosur: The Emergence of a Working System of Dispute Resolution.” NAFTA Law and Business Review Americas 6: 255–75. Harpaz, Guy. 2004. “The Dispute over the Treatment of Products Exported to the European Union from the Golan Heights, East Jerusalem, the West Bank and the Gaza Strip: The Limits of Power and the Limits of the Law.” Journal of World Trade 38 (6): 1049–58. Hart, Michael, Bill Dymond, and Colin Robertson. 1994. Decision at Midnight: Inside the Canada–US Free Trade Negotiations. Vancouver, Canada: UBC Press. Helfer, Laurence R., and Karen J. Alter. 2009. “The Andean Tribunal of Justice and Its Interlocutors: Understanding Preliminary Reference Patterns in the Andean Community.” Vanderbilt University Law School Law and Economics Research Paper 09-01, Vanderbilt University Law School, Nashville, TN. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1334733. Hessbruegge, Jan Arno. 2011. “ECOWAS Court Judgment in Habré v. Senegal Complicates Prosecution in the Name of Africa.” American Society of International Law, Insights (February 3). http://www.asil .org/insights110203.cfm.

499

Hicks, Raymond, and Soo Yeon Kim. 2009. “Credible Commitment through PTAs and Their Effects on Trade: A Study of Asia’s Reciprocal Trade Agreements.” Prepared for the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, September. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1449204. Horn, Henrik, Petros C. Mavroidis, and André Sapir. 2010. “Beyond the WTO? An Anatomy of EU and US Preferential Trade Agreements.” World Economy 33 (11): 1565–88. House Committee on Ways and Means. 2007. “Congressional-Administration Agreement on a New Trade Policy for America.” U.S. House of Representatives, Washington, DC. http://waysandmeans.house.gov/ News.asp?FormMode=release&ID=513. Hudec, Robert E. 1975. The GATT Legal System and World Trade Diplomacy. New York: Praeger. ICJ (International Court of Justice). 1950. Interpretation of Peace Treaties with Bulgaria, Hungary and Rumania, Advisory Opinion, First Phase [1950] ICJ Rep., 65; Second Phase [1950] ICJ Rep. 221. Luxembourg, ICJ. Inama, Stefano. 2005. “The Association of South East Asian Nations– People’s Republic of China Free Trade Area: Negotiating beyond Eternity with Little Trade Liberalization?” Journal of World Trade 39 (3): 559–79. INTAL (Institute for the Integration of Latin America and the Caribbean). 2005. “CARICOM Report No. 2.” INTAL, Inter-American Development Bank, Buenos Aires. _____. 2006. “MERCOSUR: The Permanent Review Tribunal Issued Its First Award.” INTAL Monthly Newsletter 114 (January). ———. 2009. “MERCOSUR Report No. 13, 2007 (Second Semester)–2008 (First Semester).” INTAL, Inter-American Development Bank, Buenos Aires. ———. 2010. “MERCOSUR Report No. 14, 2008 (Second Semester)– 2009 (First Semester).” INTAL, Inter-American Development Bank, Buenos Aires. Karli, Mehmet. 2008. “Assessing the Development Friendliness of Dispute Settlement Mechanisms in the Economic Partnership Agreements and an Analytical and Comparative Guide to the Dispute Settlement Provisions in the EU’s FTAs.” European Studies Centre, Occasional Paper, University of Oxford, Oxford, U.K. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/ abstract=1270111. Kawai, Masahiro, and Ganeshan Wignaraja. 2009. “The Asian Noodle Bowl: Is It Serious for Business?” ADBI Working Paper 136, Asian Development Bank Institute, Manila. Keck, Alexander, and Roberta Piermartini. 2005. “The Economic Impact of EPAs in SADC Countries.” Staff Working Paper ERSD-2005-04, World Trade Organization, Geneva. Keck, Alexander, and Simon Schropp. 2007. “Indisputably Essential: The Economics of Dispute Settlement Institutions in Trade Agreements.” Staff Working Paper ERSD-2007-02, World Trade Organization, Geneva. Kirk, Ron, and Hilda Solis. 2010. Consultation request addressed to Minister of Economy and Minister of Labor and Social Protection of Guatemala, July 30, USTR, Washington, DC. Kreinin, Mordechai, ed. 2000. Building a Partnership: The Canada–United States Free Trade Agreement. Lansing, MI: Michigan State University. Kwak, Kyung, and Gabrielle Marceau. 2006. “Overlaps and Conflicts of Jurisdiction between the WTO and Regional Trade Agreements.” In Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO Legal System, ed. Lorand Bartels and Federico Ortino. New York: Oxford University Press. Lacarte, Julio, and Jaime Granados, eds. 2004. Inter-Governmental Trade Dispute Settlement: Multilateral and Regional Approaches. London: Cameron May. Loungnarath, Vilaysoun, and Céline Stehly. 2000. “The General Dispute Settlement Mechanism in the North American Free Trade Agreement and the World Trade Organization System: Is North American Regionalism Really Preferable to Multilateralism?” Journal of World Trade 34 (1): 39–71. Luo, Yan. 2005. “Dispute Settlement in the Proposed East Asian Free Trade Agreement: What We Can Learn from the EU and the NAFTA.”


500

Amelia Porges

Presented at ILA British Branch Spring 2005 Conference, Edinburgh, Scotland, May. http://www.hss.ed.ac.uk/ila/Day2.htm. Mercosur (Southern Cone Common Market, Mercado Común del Sur), Tribunal Permanente de Revisión. 2006. “Laudo del Tribunal Permanente de Revisión Constituido en Plenario para Entender en el Recurso de Revisión Presentado por la República Argentina contra la Decisión del Tribunal Arbitral AD HOC de Fecha 21 de junio de 2006, Constituido para Entender en la Controversia Promovida por la República Oriental del Uruguay contra la República Argentina sobre: ‘Impedimientos a la Libre Circulación derivado de los Cortes en Territorio Argentino de Vías de Acceso a los Puentes Internacionales Gral. San Martín y Gral.Artigas.’” Award of July 6, 2006. http://www.sice.oas .org/Dispute/mercosur/Laudo002_006_p.pdf. Mercurio, Bryan, and Rebecca LaForgia. 2005. “Expanding Democracy: Why Australia Should Negotiate for Open and Transparent Dispute Settlement in Its Free Trade Agreements.” Melbourne Journal of International Law 6: 485–514. Merrills, J. G. 1991. International Dispute Settlement. 2nd ed. Cambridge, U.K.: Grotius Publications. Morgan, David. 2008. “Dispute Settlement under PTAs: Political or Legal?” In Challenges to Multilateral Trade: The Impact of Bilateral, Preferential and Regional Agreements, ed. Ross Buckley, Vai Io Lai, and Laurence Boulle. Alphen aan den Rijn, Netherlands: Kluwer Law International. Also available as University of Melbourne Legal Studies Research Paper 341, SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1203022. MOX Plant Case. 2006. Commission v. Ireland, Case No. C-459/03, Judgment in OJ C 165, July 15. http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/ LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:C:2006:165:0002:0003:EN:PDF. Nakagawa, Junji. 2007. “No More Negotiated Deals? Settlement of Trade and Investment Disputes in East Asia.” Journal of International Economic Law 10 (4): 837–67. Nyaungwa, Nyasha. 2010. “Zimbabwean Government Could Lose More Assets in SADC.” Namibia Economist (April 23). http://allafrica.com/ stories/201004230689.html. Opertti, Didier. 2004. “The New MERCOSUR Dispute Settlement Mechanism.” In Inter-Governmental Trade Dispute Settlement: Multilateral and Regional Approaches, ed. Julio Lacarte and Jaime Granados. London: Cameron May. Pauwelyn, Joost. 2004. “Going Global, Regional, or Both? Dispute Settlement in the Southern African Development Community (SADC) and Overlaps with the WTO and Other Jurisdictions.” Minnesota Journal of World Trade 13: 231–304. ———. 2006. “Adding Sweeteners to Softwood Lumber: The WTONAFTA ‘Spaghetti Bowl’ Is Cooking.” Journal of International Economic Law 9: 1–10. Peña, Felix. 2004. “Overview of New Trends in Dispute Settlement Mechanisms under Preferential Trade Agreements.” In Inter-Governmental Trade Dispute Settlement: Multilateral and Regional Approaches, ed. Julio Lacarte and Jaime Granados. London: Cameron May. Piérola, Fernando, and Gary Horlick. 2007. “WTO Dispute Settlement and Dispute Settlement in the ‘North-South’ Agreements of the Americas: Considerations for Choice of Forum.” Journal of World Trade 41 (5): 885–908. Porges, Amelia. 2003. “Settling WTO Disputes: What Do Litigation Models Tell Us?” Ohio State Journal on Dispute Resolution 19 (1): 141–84. Ramirez Robles, Edna. 2006. “Political and Quasi-Adjudicative Dispute Settlement Models in European Union Free Trade Agreements: Is the Quasi-Adjudicative Model a Trend or Is It Just Another Model?” Staff Working Paper ERSD-2006-09, WTO Economic Research and Statistics Division, Geneva. http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/reser_e/ersd 200609_e.pdf. Reich, Arie. 1996. “From Diplomacy to Law: The Juridicization of International Trade Relations.” Northwestern Journal of International Law & Business 17 (2/3): 775–849. Reuters. 2010. “Tribunal Wants SADC to Suspend Harare over Land Case.” July 17. http://www.polity.org.za/article/tribunal-wants-sadcto-suspend-harare-over-land-case-2010-07-17.

Rojas Penso, Juan. 2004. “New Dispute Settlement Perspectives in the Latin American Integration Association (ALADI).” In Inter-Governmental Trade Dispute Settlement: Multilateral and Regional Approaches, ed. Julio Lacarte and Jaime Granados. London: Cameron May. Sáez, Sebastian. 2007. “The Countries of Latin America and the Caribbean and Trade Disputes: An Analysis.” Boletin FAL (Facilitation del Comercio y el Transporte en America Latina y el Caribe) 249 (May). Also published in Spanish by Comisión Económica para América Latina/Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (CEPAL/ECLAC) as “América Latina y el Caribe en las Controversias Comerciales: Un Análisis Aplicando BADICC,” CEPAL/ECLAC, Santiago. Sauvé, Pierre, and Martin Molinuevo. 2008. “Does Architecture Matter? The Treatment of Trade and Investment in Financial Services in Selected Preferential Trade Agreements.” NCCR Trade Regulation Working Paper 2008/9, Swiss National Centre of Competence in Research, Bern. http://www.nccr-trade.org/nccr-publications/8.html. Schiff, Maurice, and L. Alan Winters. 2003. Regional Integration and Development. New York: Oxford University Press. Schreuer, Christoph. 2001. The ICSID Convention: A Commentary. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. SIEL (Society of International Economic Law). 2010. “Mercosur Award No. 1/2005.” SIEL Translation Project. http://www.sielnet.org/sieltranslationproject. Smith, James McCall. 2000. “The Politics of Dispute Settlement Design: Explaining Legalism in Regional Trade Pacts.” International Organization 54: 137–80. Snyder, Francis. 2009. “China, Regional Trade Agreements and WTO Law.” Journal of World Trade 43 (1): 1–57. Stephanou, Constantinos. 2009. “Including Financial Services in Preferential Trade Agreements: Lessons of International Experience for China.” Policy Research Working Paper 4898, World Bank, Washington, DC. Sucharitkul, Sompong. 2003. “Dispute Settlement: Regional Approaches, 6.3 ASEAN.” Module for the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) Course on Dispute Settlement in International Trade, Investment, and Intellectual Property, UNCTAD/ EDM/Misc.232/Add.29, United Nations, New York and Geneva. Szepesi, Stephen. 2004. “Comparing EU Free Trade Agreements: Dispute Settlement.” In Brief 6G (July). Maastricht, Netherlands: European Centre for Development Policy Management. http://www.ecdpm.org/ inbrief6g. Thorp, Teresa. 2010. “Challenges of Incorporating the Economic Acquis Communautaire of the East African Community in a New Common Market.” Society of International Economic Law (SIEL), Second Biennial Global Conference, University of Barcelona, July 8–10. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1632439. Tussie, Diana, and Valentina Delich. 2005. “Dispute Settlement between Developing Countries: Argentina and Chilean Price Bands.” In Managing the Challenges of WTO Participation: 45 Case Studies, ed. Peter Gallagher, Patrick Low, and Andrew L. Stoler. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Unzurrunzaga Valle, Maria Ester. 2005. “Trade Disputes Settlement in the European Union Agreements with Mexico and Chile.” Inter-American Development Bank (IADB), Washington, DC. http://www.iadb.org/ intal/aplicaciones/uploads/ponencias/Foro_ELSNIT_2005_02_Unzur runzaga.pdf. U.S. DOL (U.S. Department of Labor). 2007. “Status of Submissions under the North American Agreement on Labor Cooperation (NAALC).” List updated to September 2007, U.S. DOL, Washington, DC. http://www.dol.gov/ilab/programs/nao/status.htm. ———. 2010. “Status of Submissions under the NAALC.” Division of Trade Agreement Administration and Technical Cooperation, U.S. Department of Labor, Washington, DC. http://www.dol.gov/ilab/ programs/nao/status.htm. USTR (Office of the U.S. Trade Representative). 2010. “USTR Kirk Announces Labor Rights Trade Enforcement Case Against Guatemala.” Press release, July 30, USTR, Washington, DC.


Dispute Settlement

Victor, David G. 1998. “The Operation and Effectiveness of the Montreal Protocol’s Non-Compliance Procedure.” In The Implementation and Effectiveness of International Environmental Commitments, ed. David G. Victor, Kal Raustiala, and Eugene B. Skolnikoff. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Vigil Toledo, Ricardo. 2004. “Dispute Settlement in Andean Community Law.” In Inter-Governmental Trade Dispute Settlement: Multilateral and Regional Approaches, ed. Julio Lacarte and Jaime Granados. London: Cameron May. Vinuesa, Raul Emilio. 2005. “Enforcement of Mercosur Arbitration Awards within the Domestic Legal Orders of Member States.” Texas International Law Journal 40: 425–42. von Finckenstein, Konrad W. 2000. “Dispute Settlement under the Free Trade Agreement.” In Building a Partnership: The Canada–United States Free Trade Agreement, ed. Mordechai Kreinin. Lansing, MI: Michigan State University. Wang, Jiangyu. 2009. “ASEAN–China Free Trade Agreement.” In Bilateral and Regional Trade Agreements: Commentary and Analysis, ed. Simon Lester and Brian Mercurio. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Whitelaw, James. 2004. “The MERCOSUR Dispute Settlement System.” In Inter-Governmental Trade Dispute Settlement: Multilateral and Regional Approaches, ed. Julio Lacarte and Jaime Granados. London: Cameron May. Winham, Gilbert. 1993. “Dispute Settlement in NAFTA and the FTA.” In Assessing NAFTA: A Trinational Analysis, ed. Steven Globerman and Michael Walker. Vancouver, Canada: Fraser Institute. http://oldfraser .lexi.net/publications/books/assess_nafta/dispute.html.

501

Woolcock, Stephen. 2007. “European Union Policy towards Free Trade Agreements.” ECIPE Working Paper 03/2007, European Centre for International Political Economy, Brussels. World Bank. 2000. Trade Blocs. World Bank Policy Research Report. New York: Oxford University Press. WTO (World Trade Organization). 1996a. Analytical Index/Guide to GATT Law and Practice. 6th ed. Geneva: World Trade Organization. ———. 1996b. “Rules of Conduct for the Understanding on Rules and Procedures Governing the Settlement of Disputes.” WT/DSB/RC/1, WTO, Geneva. ———. 1999. “Canada–Measures Affecting the Importation of Milk and the Exportation of Dairy Products.” Panel Report, WTO, Geneva. ———. 2009. “2010–2011 Budget Proposals.” WT/BFA/W/189, WTO, Geneva. Xuto, Nilaratna. 2005. “Thailand: Conciliating a Dispute on Tuna Exports to the EC.” In Managing the Challenges of WTO Participation: 45 Case Studies, ed. Peter Gallagher, Patrick Low, and Andrew Stoler. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Yang, Tseming. 2007. “International Treaty Enforcement as a Public Good: Institutional Deterrent Sanctions in International Environmental Agreements.” Michigan Journal of International Law 27: 1131–84. Yang, Yongzheng, and Sanjeev Gupta. 2005. “Regional Trade Arrangements in Africa: Past Performance and the Way Forward.” IMF Working Paper WP/05/36, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Yoshimatsu, Hidetaka. 2006. “Collective Action Problems and Regional Integration in ASEAN.” Contemporary Southeast Asia: A Journal of International and Strategic Affairs 28: 115–40.



INDEX

Notes are indicated with n following the page number.

A Absorption principle, 168 Abuja Treaty of 1991, 113 ACCC. See Australian Competition and Consumer Commission ACP. See African, Caribbean, and Pacific states Ad hoc panels, 485, 494–96 ADR. See Alternative dispute resolution Africa African Common Market, 113 African Economic Community, 113 African Growth and Opportunity Act, 149, 173–74 Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa, 24, 155, 169, 328, 361 dispute settlement, 470 European Union-South Africa Trade and Development Cooperation Agreement, 222–24 preferential trade agreement participation, 56–57 Southern African Customs Union, 223, 330, 358 Southern African Development Community, 155, 174–75, 223, 330 West African Economic and Monetary Union, 154–55 African, Caribbean, and Pacific states, 52 African Common Market, 113 African Economic Community, 113 African Growth and Opportunity Act, 149, 173–74 AFTA. See ASEAN Free Trade Agreement Agency for International Development, 436, 439 Agglomeration forces, 78–80 Agreement on Agriculture, 145–46 Agreement on Rules of Origin, 163 Agreement on Safeguards, 461n Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures, 210–13, 218 Agreement on the Technical Barriers to Trade, 210–13, 218 Agricultural trade bilateral preferential trade agreements, 153–75 domestic subsidies, 152–53 economic integration, 146–47 economics of, 144–47 European Union agreements, 154–55 evaluating trade preferences, 149–51 export subsidies, 152–53 institutions, 153 multilateral commitments, 144–46 preferential commitments, 144–46 public goods, 153 regional preferential trade agreements, 151–53 regional trade flows, 148 safeguards, 152

tariff cuts, 151–52 trade flows and preferences, 148–49 U.S. agreements, 155–57 World Trade Organization agreement, 146 AIA. See ASEAN Investment Agreement Aid for trade, 263 Alternative dispute resolution, 489 American National Standards Institute, 199 AMU. See Arab Maghreb Union Andean Community services trade, 270n Andean Tribunal of Justice, 472 ANSI. See American National Standards Institute Antidumping rules, 182–86, 194 ANZCERTA. See Australia-New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement ANZGPA. See Australia and New Zealand Government Procurement Agreement APEC. See Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation Arab Maghreb Union, 56 ASEAN. See Association of Southeast Asian Nations ASEAN Free Trade Agreement, 343 ASEAN Investment Agreement, 320 ASEAN Trade in Goods Agreement, 228–29 Asia. See also Association of Southeast Asian Nations Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation, 23, 205–206, 328, 343, 372 dispute settlement, 469 preferential trade agreement participation, 50–56 services trade, 262 Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation, 23, 205–206, 328, 343, 372 Association of Southeast Asian Nations certification and accreditation services, 109 liberalization strategy, 84 preferential trade agreements, 42, 55–56 Trade in Goods Agreement, 228–29 At-the-border policies, 18–19 ATIGA. See ASEAN Trade in Goods Agreement ATJ. See Andean Tribunal of Justice AUSFTA. See Australia-United States Free Trade Agreement Australia Australia and New Zealand Government Procurement Agreement, 373 Australia-New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement, 152, 357 Australia-United States Free Trade Agreement, 219–20 Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, 359 labor agreements with developing countries, 297–99, 303 labor mobility in preferential trade agreements, 283–84 Australia and New Zealand Government Procurement Agreement, 373

503


504

Index

Australia-New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement, 152, 357 Australia-United States Free Trade Agreement, 219–20 Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, 359 Auto Pact, 123, 132 Automobile tariffs, 83–84

B Barbados services trade, 266 Basel Committee, 98 Baucus, Max, 457 Behind-the-border policies, 18–19 Better Work, 429 Bilateral cumulation, 166 Bilateral investment impact of, 324 intellectual property rights and, 401–402 liberalization of, 313–15 Bilateral investment treaties, 108n, 155, 290 Bilateral labor agreements, 287–90 Bilateral safeguards, 182–84, 187 Bilateral trade agreements agricultural trade provisions, 153–75 differentiated from plurilateral agreements, 43–44 disadvantages of, 123 investment protection, 317 Bipartisan Agreement, 397 BITs. See Bilateral investment treaties BLAs. See Bilateral labor agreements Break-even curves, 74–76 Bush, George H. W., 431, 433 Bush, George W., 430, 457 Business visitors, 277

C CACJ. See Central American Court of Justice CACM. See Central American Common Market CAFTA. See Central American Free Trade Agreement Canada Canada-Costa Rica Trade Agreement, 328 Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement, 136, 153, 493–95 human rights provisions, 449–52, 462n labor agreements with developing countries, 294–95, 301 labor mobility in preferential trade agreements, 281–82 worker rights provisions, 433–34 Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement, 136, 153, 493–95 Capacity building agreement, 230 Caribbean Basin Initiative, 157 Caribbean Forum of African, Caribbean, and Pacific States cultural cooperation and aid for trade, 263 EU Economic Partnership Agreement, 328 services trade, 266–69 tourism liberalization, 260 Caribbean region Caribbean Basin Economic Recovery Act, 157 Caribbean Basin Initiative, 157 Caribbean Basin Trade Partnership Act, 157 Caribbean Community Regional Negotiating Mechanism, 154 Caribbean Court of Justice, 473 preferential trade agreement participation, 54–55 CARIFORUM. See Caribbean Forum of African, Caribbean, and Pacific States CBI. See Caribbean Basin Initiative CCC. See Community Competition Commission CEC. See Council for Environmental Cooperation CEFTA. See Central European Free Trade Agreement CEN. See Committee for Standardization Central America Central American Trade Dispute Resolution Mechanism, 473 preferential trade agreement participation, 54–55 Central American Common Market, 42, 55 Central American Court of Justice, 473

Central American Free Trade Agreement, 105, 150, 156–57, 230, 328, 438 Central Asia preferential trade agreement participation, 50–54 Central Corridor Transit Transport Facilitation Agency, 345n Central European Free Trade Agreement, 39 Centre d’Études Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales, 149 CEPAs. See Closer Economic Partnership Agreements CEPTs. See Common effective preference tariffs CET. See Common external tariff CEZ. See Common Economic Zone CGE. See Computable general equilibrium Chile Chile-China Free Trade Agreement, 229 Chile-United States Free Trade Agreement, 225–26 European Union-Chile Free Trade Agreement, 221–22, 328 free trade agreements, 156 patent-registration linkage, 394 trade agreements, 398–99 worker rights provisions, 434–35 China Chile-China Free Trade Agreement, 229 China-New Zealand Free Trade Agreement, 226–27 Closer Economic Partnership Agreements, 469 Clean Development Mechanism, 411 Clinton, Bill, 431 Closer Economic Partnership Agreements, 469 Cluster economics, 80 Cobden-Chevalier Treaties, 127 Codex Alimentarius Commission, 201, 213 COMESA. See Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa Committee for Standardization, 199, 201 Common Economic Zone, 53–54 Common effective preference tariffs, 84 Common external tariff collection of duties, 117 design and level of, 114–16 economic implications of, 113–14 ownership of collected duties, 116–17 Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa, 24, 155, 169, 328, 361 Community Competition Commission, 358 Competition curves, 74–75 Competition models, 89–92 Competition policy benefits of various types of agreement, 350–51 consumer policy, 359–60 consumer protection, 352 cost-benefit analyses, 353–54 development and, 347–49 economics of, 349–55 effects on third parties, 355 enforcement mechanisms, 351 hard versus soft law, 360 implementation costs, 352–53 implementation issues, 361–63 implications for open regionalism, 354–55 international cooperation, 356 models of regional competition regimes, 357 positive spillovers, 351–52 regional policy in practice, 355–63 scope, 358–59 Competitive liberalization, 133 Computable general equilibrium, 148, 150 Conciliation, 489–90 Conformity assessment, 200 Contractual services suppliers, 277, 283 Copyright protection, 395–96 Copyright Treaty, 395 Costa Rica Canada-Costa Rica Trade Agreement, 328 Cotonou Agreement, 154, 162, 453 Council for Environmental Cooperation, 415 Countervailing duties, 182–86 Country strategy paper, 224


Index

CU. See Customs unions Cumulation, 166–68 CUSFTA. See Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement The Customs Union Issue, 70 Customs unions agreements in force and planned, 112 collection of duties, 117 design and level of common external tariff, 114–16 economic implications of, 112–14 function of, 38, 111 ownership of collected duties, 116–17 reasons for choosing, 113

D DDA. See Doha Development Agenda De minimis rules, 168 Defragmentation, 74, 77 Demand-linked circular causality, 79–80 Department of Labor, 436–38 Developing countries agricultural trade, 143–58 capacity building for competitiveness, 104 designing successful reforms, 97 economic governance, 102–104 environmental issues, 412 labor agreements, 285–88, 293–04 promoting market access, 101–102 reform priorities, 96–97 trade liberalization strategies, 97–100 Diagnostic Trade Integration Study, 334 Diagonal cumulation, 166–67 Digital Millennium Copyright Act of 1998, 396 Digital trade, 259 Dispersion forces, 78–80 Dispute settlement ad hoc panels, 485, 494–96 Africa, 470 alternative enforcement methods, 488–90 amicus curiae submissions, 487–88 appeal, 481 civil society participation, 486–88 collective enforcement procedures, 488–89 complaints by stakeholders against governments, 487 compliance, 490–91 conciliation, 489–90 consultations, 478–79 correction, 481 defining grounds for complaint, 475–76 diplomatic, 470–71 duration of panel process, 481 East Asia, 469 enforcement, 470–75 environmental issues, 417–18, 421, 422 European Union, 468 formal phase, 479 good offices, 489 government procurement, 376–78 implementation, 490–91 infrastructure, 479–80 investment agreements, 311 Latin America, 469–70 mediation, 489–90 panel procedures, 480–81 panelist ethics, 486 participation in settlement and enforcement, 484–88 political, 470–71 preferential trade agreements disputes, 491–96 qualification and selection of decision makers, 484–85 referral to ad hoc panel, 473–74 remand, 481 rosters, 485–86 sanctions, 490–91 special sectors, 481–84

505

specialized institutions, 488 SPS and TBT provisions, 231 standing tribunals, 471–73, 484 structuring systems, 475–78 support for, 479–80 surveys, 468 targets of complaint, 476 third-party participation, 486 transparency, 486–88 United States, 468–69 Dispute Settlement Mechanism, 469 Dispute Settlement Understanding, 467 DMS. See Dispute Settlement Mechanism Doha Development Agenda, 257–58, 398 Doha Round trade negotiations, 39, 145–46 Dominican Republic Central American Free Trade Agreement, 150, 230, 328 services trade, 267 Double-taxation treaties, 290 DSU. See Dispute Settlement Understanding Duopoly, 91 Duty drawback, 168

E East Asia dispute settlement, 469 preferential trade agreement participation, 55–56 services trade, 262 EBA. See Everything But Arms preferences EBRD. See European Bank for Reconstruction and Development ECO. See Economic Cooperation Organization Economic and Monetary Community of Central Africa, 155 Economic Community of Central African States, 155 Economic Community of West African States, 154–55, 170–71, 286 Economic Cooperation Organization, 54 Economic integration agreement, 38, 50 Economic issues agglomeration forces, 78–80 agricultural trade, 143–58 conflicting priorities, 415–16 dispersion forces, 78–80 dynamic gains of regionalism, 74–78 financial assistance, 414–15 locational effects of liberalization, 80–81 new economic geography, 78–81 regional interindustry trade, 84–86 regionalism effects, 69–73 technical assistance, 414–15 trade arrangements, 81–84 Economic needs tests, 305n Economic partnership agreements, 52, 105, 174, 398, 453–54 EDI. See Electronic data interchange EEA. See European Economic Area EEC. See European Economic Community EEEMRA. See Electrical and electronic equipment mutual recognition agreement EFTA. See European Free Trade Area; European Free Trade Association EIA. See Economic integration agreement El Salvador human rights issues, 460 Electrical and electronic equipment mutual recognition agreement, 227 Electricity Regulatory Forum, 35n Electronic data interchange, 334 Electronic trade, 259 Emergency safeguard mechanisms, 249 Enabling Clause, 66n Enforce-your-own-laws standard, 431, 432 ENP. See European Neighborhood Policy ENTs. See Economic needs tests Environmental issues dispute resolution, 417–18, 421, 422 hard- and soft-law approaches, 416–18 implementation of provisions, 413–16


506

Index

Environmental issues (continued) preferential trade agreements and, 409–11, 420–22 regional policy, 411–13 trade and, 408–09 EPAs. See Economic partnership agreements Equivalence, 204 ESM. See Emergency safeguard mechanisms Euro-Mediterranean Conference, 154 Euro-Mediterranean free trade agreements, 154, 220–21 Europe European Coal and Steel Community, 23 European Court of Justice, 24, 471–72 preferential trade agreement participation, 50–54 European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 333, 345n European Economic Area, 151, 472 European Economic Community, 138n European Free Trade Area, 472 European Free Trade Association agricultural provisions, 151 human rights, 452–53 preferential trade agreement participation, 20, 52–53 European Neighborhood Policy, 105–106 European Union agricultural trade agreements, 154–55 Caribbean Forum of African, Caribbean, and Pacific States Economic Partnership Agreement, 328 cultural cooperation and aid for trade, 263 dispute settlement, 468 environmental issues in preferential trade agreements, 421–22 European Union-Chile Free Trade Agreement, 221–22, 328 European Union-Morocco preferential trade agreement, 220–21 European Union-South Africa Trade and Development Cooperation Agreement, 222–24 Everything But Arms preferences, 19–20 human rights provisions, 453–56 labor agreements with developing countries, 295–96, 302 labor mobility in preferential trade agreements, 282–83 market integration and economic development, 105–107 rules of origin in existing trade agreements, 168–71 services trade, 266–69 tourism liberalization, 260 trade facilitation, 341–42 Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, 397–400 worker rights provisions, 435 Everything But Arms preferences, 19–20, 52 Externalities, 22 Extra-preferential trade agreements, 59–63

F Factor-market competition, 79 Factory Asia, 85–86 FAO. See Food and Agriculture Organization FDA. See Food and Drug Administration FDI. See Foreign direct investment Federal Trade Commission, 359 Florence Forum, 35n Food and Agriculture Organization, 201 Food and Drug Administration, 198 Foreign Agricultural Resource Management Services, 305n Foreign direct investment, 318–19 Foundation of Enterprises for the Recruitment of Foreign Labor, 305n Frankel and Wei model, 128 Free trade agreements. See also specific agreement by name agriculture provisions, 156 customs unions, 111, 113–16 human rights provisions, 454–55 (See also specific countries by name) purpose of, 38 resource transfers, 24 Free trade area, 71–72 Free Trade Commission, 415–16 Frictional barrier liberalization, 72–73 FTA. See Free trade area FTAs. See Free trade agreements

FTC. See Federal Trade Commission Full cumulation, 167–68

G GAFTA. See Greater Arab Free Trade Area Galileo satellite system for global navigation, 334 Gambling, online, 262 GATS. See General Agreement on Trade in Services GATT. See General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade General Accountability Office, 437 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade Article III requirements, 19 effect of regionalism, 123–24 Enabling Clause, 42, 66n human rights, 445–48 preferential trade agreement notifications, 39–42 General Agreement on Trade in Services investment provisions, 308, 312 market access issues, 20 services standards, 248–49, 261–62, 266–69 General Secretariat of the Andean Community, 24 Generalized system of preferences, 19–20, 37, 145 Geographical indications, 398, 404n Global Forum on Migration and Development, 287 Global free trade, 124–25 GLOBAL-GAP, 229 Global multilateral tariff liberalization, 82 Global safeguards, 182–86, 191–92 Government procurement buy national provisions, 369 costs of implementing provisions, 378–79 dispute settlement, 376–78 economic and developmental dimensions of, 367–73 flexible provisions, 375 international instruments, 372 multilateral trade provisions, 380–82 policy options, 382 preferential trade agreements, 371–83 provisions in preferential trade agreements, 373–80 technical assistance, 379–80 thresholds, 374 trade negotiating strategy, 382 transparency, 370–71 Government Procurement Agreement, 249, 372–76 GPA. See Government Procurement Agreement Graduate trainees, 283 Gravity models, 150 Greater Arab Free Trade Area, 331 GSP. See Generalized system of preferences Guatemala human rights issues, 460

H Haberler, Gottfried, 69–70 Harmonization services trade, 247–49 standards, 204–206 Harmonized System, 162 Harmonized System-8 product level, 135 Human Resources and Skills Development Canada, 288 Human rights background, 447–49 knowledge gaps, 460–61 linkages, 460–61 obligations of trading nations, 444–45 preferential trade agreements and, 449–60 trade agreement provisions, 445–47

I ICCPR. See International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights ICESCR. See International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights ICSID. See International Center for the Settlement of Investment Disputes


Index

IFC. See International Finance Corporation ILO. See International Labour Organization Immigration and Naturalization Service, 438 Independent professionals, 277, 283 Information asymmetries, 22–23, 199 Information Technology Agreement, 139n Input-cost-linked circular causality, 80 INS. See Immigration and Naturalization Service Intellectual property rights bilateral investment rules, 401–402 enforcement of, 396–97 negotiating considerations, 388–90 preferential trade agreements, 17 Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, 18 TRIPS+ provisions, 390–401 Interindustry trade, 84–86 International Center for the Settlement of Investment Disputes, 311, 485 International Center for Trade and Sustainable Development, 403n International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, 444 International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, 444 International Finance Corporation, 345n, 429, 439 International Labour Organization, 305, 427, 429 International Organization for Migration, 287 International Organization for Standardization, 197–98 International Trade and Labour Grants and Contributions Program, 434 International Trade Organization, 445–47 Intra-preferential trade agreements, 59–63 Intracorporate transferees, 277 Investment economic impact, 317–20 impact of bilateral investment, 324 incorporation into preferential trade agreements, 307–309 international agreements, 315–16 liberalization of bilateral investment, 313–15 multilateralization of provisions, 316–17 nature and scope of provisions, 309–313 preferential trade agreements covering investment, 322–23 protection provisions, 317 types of preferential trade agreements, 311–13 typology of investment measures, 309–311 WTO rules, 308 IPRs. See Intellectual property rights ISO. See International Organization for Standardization Israel-U.S. Free Trade Agreement, 495 ITO. See International Trade Organization

J Jamaica services trade, 268 Japan labor agreements with developing countries, 296–97, 302 labor mobility in preferential trade agreements, 283 Trade and Investment Liberalization Fund, 340 worker rights provisions, 435 Johnson-Cooper-Massell proposition, 86–88 Johnson diagram, 86–88 Joint Initiative for Priority Skills Acquisition Act of 2004, 289 Jordan U.S.-Jordan preferential trade agreement, 437–38 workers rights, 439 Jordan standard, 431, 432 Juggernaut building block logic, 126–28, 138n

K Kemp-Wan theorem, 70, 128 Kennedy Round, 34n Korea-U.S. Free Trade Agreement, 157 KORUS. See Korea-U.S. Free Trade Agreement Krugman, Paul, 78, 85 Kyoto Protocol, 411

L Labor mobility agreements with developing countries, 293–99 bilateral labor agreements, 287–90 categories of labor included in trade agreements, 277 concept of, 276–77 distributional effects of Mode 4 liberalization, 278–81 economic benefits, 277–81 estimates of gains, 292–93 importance of, 275 natural persons definition, 276 preferential trade agreement provisions, 300–304 in preferential trade agreements, 281–87 recommendations, 290–92 Labor rights bipartisan agreement, 433 economics of, 428–29 implementation and enforcement of provisions, 435–39 International Labour Organization standards, 427 provisions in preferential trade agreements, 429–30 sanctions authorized for violations, 436 worker rights provisions, 430–35 Workers Rights Project, 438 LAIA. See Latin American Integration Association Latin America dispute settlement, 469–70 Latin American Integration Association, 55, 469–71 Liberalization global multilateral tariff liberalization, 82 locational effects, 80–81 multilateral liberalization, 121–38 of parts and components, 83–84 preferential, 83 regional, 76–78 unilateral, 82–83 welfare effects, 78 Local-market competition, 79

M Management systems, 198 Market fragmentation, 74 Mauritania human rights issues, 460 Meade, James, 70–71 Mediation, 489–90 Mediterranean countries Euro-Mediterranean free trade agreements, 154, 220–21 Mercosur, 136, 227–28, 339, 482, 495–96 Meta-standards, 198 Metrology, 200 Mexican migrant workers, 438 Mexico human rights issues, 460 trade agreements, 398–99 MFA. See Multifibre Arrangement MFN. See Most favored nation policies Middle East preferential trade agreement participation, 56–57 Migrant workers, 438 Milk Marketing Board, 153 MLAT. See Mutual legal assistance treaty MMB. See Milk Marketing Board MNEs. See Multinational enterprises Monopoly power, 21–22 Monopoly profit maximization, 89–90 Morocco European Union-Morocco preferential trade agreement, 220–21 Most favored nation policies imported liberalization, 130–31 investment provisions, 309–310, 316–17 labor agreements, 290 liberalization of, 27, 101 multilateral liberalization, 133–34

507


508

Index

Most favored nation policies (continued) rules of origin and, 131–32 tariff rates, 20 trade services, 243 MRAs. See Mutual recognition agreements MTNs. See Multilateral trade negotiations Multiannual indicative program, 224 Multifibre Arrangement, 99, 429 Multilateral liberalization bargaining model, 132–33 Frankel and Wei model, 128 induced liberalization and protection, 130–32 juggernaut building block logic, 126–28 Kemp-Wan theorem, 128 most favored nation policies, 133–34 reciprocal trade agreements, 121–23 regionalism, 123–24, 134–35 rules for preferential trade agreements, 137–38 stumbling block logic, 124–26 unilateral liberalization, 130 veto avoidance, 128–29 welfare consequences of preferential trade agreements, 135–37 Multilateral trade agreements agricultural provisions, 144–46 Multilateral trade negotiations, 126–27 Multinational enterprises, 318 Mutual legal assistance treaty, 350 Mutual recognition agreements, 26–27, 207, 220, 247–49 Mutual recognition of standards, 204

N NAAEC. See North American Agreement on Environmental Cooperation NAALC. See North American Agreement on Labor Cooperation NACEC. See North American Commission for Environment Cooperation NAFTA. See North American Free Trade Agreement Nash tariffs, 132 National Labor Committee, 439 Natural persons defined, 276 Natural trade blocs, 136 NCTA. See Northern Corridor Transit Agreement NCTS. See New Computerized Transit System Negative integration, 18 New Computerized Transit System, 334 New economic geography, 78–81 New trade theory, 85 New Zealand Australia-New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement, 152 China-New Zealand Free Trade Agreement, 226–27 labor agreements with developing countries, 297–99, 303 labor mobility in preferential trade agreements, 283–84 NLC. See National Labor Committee No-trade-to-free-trade liberalization, 76–77 Nontariff measures, 47 North Africa preferential trade agreement participation, 56–57 North America preferential trade agreement participation, 54–55 North American Agreement on Environmental Cooperation, 409, 414 North American Agreement on Labor Cooperation, 431, 437, 482 North American Commission for Environment Cooperation, 414, 482 North American Free Trade Agreement agriculture provisions, 149, 156 creation of, 123 dispute settlement, 493–95 environmental issues, 414 investment provisions, 311–13 labor standards, 431–32, 437–38 rules of origin, 165 Northern Corridor Transit Agreement, 345n NTMs. See Nontariff measures

O Obama, Barack, 432–33, 436 OECD. See Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Oligopoly, 91–92 One-stop border posts, 330–31 Online gambling, 262 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 96, 198

P Pacific region preferential trade agreement participation, 55–56 Packaging requirements, 198 PAFTA. See Pan-Arab Free Trade Agreement Pan-Arab Free Trade Agreement, 56 Partial-scope agreement, 38 Patent-registration linkage, 391, 394 Patents protection, 391, 394 Performances and Phonograms Treaty, 395 Permanent Appeals Tribunal, 482 Permanent workers, 276–77 Peru U.S.-Peru Free Trade Agreement, 397 Pharmaceutical test data, 391, 394–95 Plurilateral trade agreements differentiated from bilateral agreements, 43–44 membership, 64–65 networks, 51–54 trade developments, 57–59 Pollutant release and transfer registry, 414, 420 Positive integration, 18 Preferential liberalization, 83 Preferential rules or origin absorption principle, 168 best-practice suggestions, 164 change of tariff classification, 162–63 cumulation, 166–68 defining origin, 161–64 duty drawback, 168 economic development and, 174–75 economic implications of, 171–75 in existing preferential trade agreements, 168–71 outward processing, 168 quantifying costs associated with, 173–74 restrictiveness index, 171, 173 specific manufacturing process, 163–64 substantial transformation determination, 162–64 tolerance rules, 168 trade preferences and, 164–71 utilization of trade preferences, 171–73 value added, 163 Preferential trade agreements. See also specific issues by name at-the-border policies, 18–19 behind-the-border policies, 18–19 benefits of, 1 composition of, 42–43 customized problem solving, 30–31 deep integration preference, 17–18, 33–34 disadvantages of, 1 economic benefits, 19–23 externalities, 22 flexibility, 30–31 geographic configuration, 43–45 geopolitical objectives, 23–24 global landscape, 49–57 impact on third parties, 26–27 impact on trade, 57–63 implementation, 31–33 information asymmetries, 22–23 institutions for reform, 24–25 monopoly power, 21–22 motivations for deep integration, 19–25 negative integration, 18 North-South agreements, 95–108


Index

policy anchoring, 25 policy complementarities, 28–30 political-economy benefits, 23–25 positive integration, 18 preferences, 26–28 product standards, 203–210 proliferation of, 39–42 regulatory objectives, 28–30 scope of, 45–49 societal benefits, 23 specificities of deep integration, 25–33 structural configuration, 43 systemic effects, 27–28 trade diversion, 26 trade remedy provisions, 179–95 trends, 37–39 Prisoners’ Dilemma, 132 Process standards, 198 Product standards cost effects, 201 designing and implementing, 199–200 economic rationale for, 198–99 economics of preferential standard liberalization, 203–204 externalities, 198–99 facilitating market access, 204 harmonization of standards, 204–206 information asymmetries, 199 inventory methods, 203 management systems, 198 meta-standards, 198 mutual recognition of, 206–207 preferential trade agreement provisions, 209–210 process standards, 198 regional and international dimensions, 200–201 regional standards, 210–13 review of, 207–208 trade and, 197–203 trade effects, 202 voluntary standards, 201 Protocol of Olivos, 482 PRTR. See Pollutant release and transfer registry PTAs. See Preferential trade agreements

R Reciprocal trade agreements, 121–23 Regional economic integration organization, 316 Regional interindustry trade, 84–86 Regionalism agricultural provisions, 151–53 dynamic gains of, 74–78 effects of, 69–73 environment and, 411–13 multilateral liberalization and, 123–24, 134–35 trade services regulatory cooperation, 239–42 REIO. See Regional economic integration organization Revised Kyoto Convention, 328–29 Revised Treaty of Chaguaramas, 353 Risk-sharing funds, 345n Roll-up principle, 168 ROOs. See Rules of origin Rules of origin, 27, 88, 131–32, 161–76

S SACU. See Southern African Customs Union SADC. See Southern African Development Community SAFTA. See Singapore-Australia Free Trade Agreement Sanitary and phytosanitary standards Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures, 210–13 dispute settlement, 231 environmental issues, 409, 421, 422 implementation costs, 229–31

international trade provisions, 217–19 preferential trade agreements provisions, 219–29 technical assistance needs, 229–31 trade facilitation, 329–30 WTO standards and guidelines, 218 SARS. See South African Revenue Service Seasonal Agricultural Workers Program, 288 Secure Trade in the APEC Region initiative, 343 SEP. See Strategic Economic Partnership Services trade assessing depth of preferential liberalization, 254–69 costs and benefits of preferential treatment, 237–39 digital trade, 259 domestic regulation, 247 dynamic economies of scale, 239 economics of, 236–42 emergency safeguard mechanisms, 249 fixed cost measures, 238 government procurement, 249 harmonization, 247–49 investment, 250 liberalization in preferential trade agreements, 242–54 market access, 247 modalities of liberalization, 251–54 most favored nation treatment, 243 mutual recognition, 247–49 negotiating approaches, 253 number of service providers restriction, 238 regulatory cooperation, 247–49 regulatory intensity, 240–41 rules of origin, 250–51 static economies of scale, 239 subsidy disciplines, 249 sunk costs, 238–39 third-country effects, 242 tourism sector, 260 transparency, 243, 247 variable cost measures, 237–38 SIAs. See Sustainability impact assessments Singapore Accreditation Council, 209 Singapore-Australia Free Trade Agreement, 224–25, 343 Single Market Economy, 285 “Small PTA” diagram, 88–89 Smith, Adam, 69–70 South Africa European Union-South Africa Trade and Development Cooperation Agreement, 222–24 South Africa Pesticide Initiative Program, 224 South Africa Strategic Partnership, 223 trade agreements, 398–99 South African Revenue Service, 340 South America preferential trade agreement participation, 54–55 South Asia preferential trade agreement participation, 55–56 South Asian Free Trade Area, 384n Southern African Customs Union, 223, 330, 358 Southern African Development Community, 155, 174–75, 223, 330 Southern Cone Common Market, 23, 169, 339 SPS Agreement. See Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures SPS standards. See Sanitary and phytosanitary standards Stagflation, 287 Standing tribunals, 471–73, 484 STAR initiative. See Secure Trade in the APEC Region initiative Stolper-Samuelson effect, 138n Strategic Economic Partnership, 42 Sub-Saharan Africa preferential trade agreement participation, 57 Sustainability impact assessments, 408 Sweatshops, 429, 439

509


510

Index

T TAFTA. See Thailand-Australia Free Trade Agreement Tariff-rate quotas, 145, 158n Tariff rates, 20 TBT. See Technical barriers to trade TBT Agreement. See Agreement on the Technical Barriers to Trade TDCA. See Trade and Development Cooperation Agreement Technical barriers to trade Agreement on the Technical Barriers to Trade, 210–13 dispute settlement, 231 environmental issues, 409, 421, 422 implementation costs, 229–31 international trade provisions, 217–19 nontariff barriers, 72–73 preferential trade agreements provisions, 219–29 technical assistance needs, 229–31 WTO standards and guidelines, 218 Temporary visa programs, 288 Temporary worker programs, 291 Temporary workers, 276–77 Terms-of-trade approach, 139n TFAP. See Trade facilitation action plan TFEU. See Treaty of the Functioning of the European Union Thailand human rights issues, 460 Thailand-Australia Free Trade Agreement, 225 Third-country fabric rule, 149, 173–74 TIFAs. See Trade and investment framework agreements TILF. See Trade and Investment Liberalization Fund Tinbergen, Jan, 18 TKC. See Trans-Kalahari Corridor Tolerance rules, 168 Tourism liberalization, 260 TPA. See Trade Promotion Act Trade Analysis and Information System, 203 Trade and Development Cooperation Agreement, 222–24 Trade and investment framework agreements, 155 Trade and Investment Liberalization Fund, 340 Trade diversion, 26 Trade facilitation cooperation for regional facilitation, 329–31 delivering regional public goods, 336–37 dynamic effects, 332–36 economic dimensions, 331 institutional arrangements, 337–41, 340–41 interplay between regional and multilateral trade, 335 provisions in preferential trade agreements, 341–43 regional initiatives, 327–31 static effects, 331 trade facilitation action plan, 343 transit corridors, 337–40 World Trade Organization facilitation, 329 Trade facilitation action plan, 343 Trade facilitation agenda, 28 Trade Facilitation Principles, 343 Trade liberalization regulatory objectives, 28–29 strategies, 97–100 Trade Policy Review Mechanism, 103–104 Trade Promotion Act, 408, 456 Trade Promotion Authority Act, 155 Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, 18, 390–401 Trade-Related Investment Measures Agreement, 20, 308 Trade remedy provisions antidumping measures, 182–86, 194 countervailing duties, 182–86 cross-regional pattern, 187–90 diversity among preferential trade agreements, 181–84 function of, 180 global safeguards, 182–86, 191–92 hub-and-spoke pattern, 187–90 incidence of actions, 181

prohibition of, 190–91 trade and protection diversion, 191–95 TradeMark Southern Africa, 330 TRAINS. See Trade Analysis and Information System Trans-European Networks on Transport, 334 Trans-Kalahari Corridor, 330, 345n Trans-Pacific Partnership, 155 Trans-Pacific Strategic Economic Partnership Agreement, 42, 209, 434 Transaction spillover, 22 Transit corridors, 337–40 Transparency Mechanism, 46 Transparency Mechanism for Regional Trade Agreements, 66n Treaty of the Functioning of the European Union, 356 Triangle trade, 85–86 TRIMS. See Trade–Related Investment Measures Agreement Trinidad and Tobago services trade, 269 TRIPS agreement. See Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights TRQs. See Tariff-rate quotas

U UDHR. See Universal Declaration of Human Rights UN International Convention on the Protection of the Rights of Migrant Workers and Their Relatives, 305n UNCITRAL. See United Nations Commission on International Trade Law UNCTAD. See United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Unilateral liberalization, 82–83, 130 United Nations Commission on International Trade Law, 311, 371–72 United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 167, 203, 315 United States agricultural trade agreements, 155–57 Australia-United States Free Trade Agreement, 219–20 Canada-U.S. Free Trade Agreement, 136, 153, 493–95 Chile-United States Free Trade Agreement, 225–26 dispute settlement, 468–69 environmental issues in preferential trade agreements, 420–21 human rights provisions, 455–59 Israel-U.S. Free Trade Agreement, 495 Korea-U.S. Free Trade Agreement, 157 labor agreements with developing countries, 293–94, 300 labor mobility in preferential trade agreements, 281–82 rules of origin in existing trade agreements, 168–71 trade facilitation, 342 Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, 390–97 U.S.-Canada Auto Pact, 131–32 U.S.-Jordan preferential trade agreement, 437–38 U.S.-Peru Free Trade Agreement, 397 worker rights provisions, 430–33 Universal Declaration of Human Rights, 443–46 Uruguay Round, 99, 133 U.S. Agency for International Development, 436, 439 U.S. Department of Labor, 436–38 U.S. Digital Millennium Copyright Act of 1998, 396 U.S. Federal Trade Commission, 359 U.S. Food and Drug Administration, 198 U.S. General Accountability Office, 437 U.S. International Trade Commission, 449 U.S. Trade Representative, 397 USAID. See U.S. Agency for International Development USITC. See U.S. International Trade Commission

V Veto avoidance logic, 128–29 Viner, Jacob, 70 Visas, temporary, 288

W Walrasian model, 70–71 Walvis Bay Corridor group, 330, 345n WCO. See World Customs Organization


Index

West African Economic and Monetary Union, 154–55 WIPO. See World Intellectual Property Organization Worker rights. See Labor rights Workers Rights Project, 438 World Bank Institute, 403n World Customs Organization, 328–29 World Health Organization, 403n World Intellectual Property Organization, 395 World Trade Organization Agreement on Agriculture, 145–46 Agreement on Rules of Origin, 163 Agreement on Safeguards, 461n chronological development of preferential trade agreements, 39–42 Codex Alimentarius Commission, 201 disciplines on regional standards, 210–13 dispute settlement model, 473–74 Dispute Settlement Understanding, 467 Government Procurement Agreement, 372–76

511

human rights, 445–48 labor rights, 430 rules on investment, 308 TBT and SPS standards and guidelines, 218 trade facilitation, 329 Trade Policy Review Mechanism, 103–104 Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, 18, 390–401 Transparency Mechanism for Regional Trade Agreements, 66n WTO+ agenda, 17, 241 WTO extra, 17, 241 WTO. See World Trade Organization

Y Yale Law School, 438

Z Zoellick, Robert, 455


ECO-AUDIT

Environmental Benefits Statement The World Bank is committed to preserving endangered forests and natural resources. The Office of the Publisher has chosen to print Preferential Trade Agreement Policies for Development: A Handbook on recycled paper with 50 percent postconsumer fiber in accordance with the recommended standards for paper usage set by the Green Press Initiative, a nonprofit program supporting publishers in using fiber that is not sourced from endangered forests. For more information, visit www.greenpressinitiative.org.

Saved: • 24 trees • 10 million BTUs of total energy • 2,430 pounds of net greenhouse gases • 10,959 gallons of waste water • 694 pounds of solid waste


tRAde

And

deVeloPMent

SeRieS

“The ongoing wave of preferential trade agreements (PTAs) strongly suggests a need to revise long-held conceptions about the multilateral trading system and to embrace a more complex world composed of networks of multilateral, plurilateral, regional, and bilateral arrangements. This handbook is a timely and much needed review of the analytical underpinnings and practice of modern PTAs, from the liberalization of agriculture trade to the promotion of human rights. I expect the handbook to be of particular relevance to trade specialists in the policy-making and academic communities confronted with these new and difficult policy challenges.” — RobeRt M. SteRn Professor emeritus of economics and Public Policy University of Michigan

“Preferential trade agreements are not only prevalent in today’s international trade system but most importantly have shaped the reform agenda of many developing countries in a number of behind-the-border areas. This handbook provides a comprehensive, systemic, and thorough analysis of PTAs by both addressing key conceptual issues underlying their negotiation and exploring their contents across several agreements around the world. The book makes a very valuable contribution for policy makers, practitioners, academics, and readers interested in further understanding the impact of deep integration PTAs from a development perspective.” — H.e. AnAbel González Minister of Foreign trade Costa Rica

“The impact of preferential trade agreements on development has been a priority policy issue for developing countries in recent years. This handbook gives a thoughtful and comprehensive overview of PTAs, their economics, and their implications for the multilateral trading system. It provides interesting reading for anyone concerned with the evolving international trade and development agenda.” — SUPACHAi PAnitCHPAkdi Secretary-General United nations Conference on trade and development (UnCtAd)

About our Program The World Bank’s International Trade Department produces and disseminates policy-oriented knowledge products and forges partnerships on trade to advance an inclusive trade agenda for developing countries and to enhance developing countries’ trade competitiveness in global markets. Learn more about the World Bank’s trade portfolio at: www.worldbank.org/trade.

ISBN 978-0-8213-8643-9

SKU 18643


Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.