Socialism sucks two economists drink their way through the unfree world robert lawson - Own the eboo

Page 1


Socialism Sucks Two Economists Drink Their Way Through the Unfree World

Visit to download the full and correct content document: https://textbookfull.com/product/socialism-sucks-two-economists-drink-their-way-throu gh-the-unfree-world-robert-lawson/

More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant download maybe you interests ...

The Bayesian way: introductory statistics for economists and engineers First Edition Nyberg

https://textbookfull.com/product/the-bayesian-way-introductorystatistics-for-economists-and-engineers-first-edition-nyberg/

Chasing Phil the world s greatest con man two undercover FBI agents and their amazing around the world adventure Brennan

https://textbookfull.com/product/chasing-phil-the-world-sgreatest-con-man-two-undercover-fbi-agents-and-their-amazingaround-the-world-adventure-brennan/

In Europe s Shadow Two Cold Wars and a Thirty year Journey Through Romania and Beyond Robert D. Kaplan

https://textbookfull.com/product/in-europe-s-shadow-two-coldwars-and-a-thirty-year-journey-through-romania-and-beyond-robertd-kaplan/

The Cashflow Way to Invest in Real Estate Robert Kiyosaki

https://textbookfull.com/product/the-cashflow-way-to-invest-inreal-estate-robert-kiyosaki/

Eco-Socialism For Now and the Future: Practical Utopias and Rational Action

https://textbookfull.com/product/eco-socialism-for-now-and-thefuture-practical-utopias-and-rational-action-robert-albritton/

Food and Drink in Antiquity: A Sourcebook: Readings from the Graeco-Roman World John F. Donahue

https://textbookfull.com/product/food-and-drink-in-antiquity-asourcebook-readings-from-the-graeco-roman-world-john-f-donahue/

Food and Drink in Antiquity: Readings from the GraecoRoman World: A Sourcebook John F. Donahue

https://textbookfull.com/product/food-and-drink-in-antiquityreadings-from-the-graeco-roman-world-a-sourcebook-john-f-donahue/

The New Way of the World On Neoliberal Society Dardot

https://textbookfull.com/product/the-new-way-of-the-world-onneoliberal-society-dardot/

Working Two Way Stories of Cross cultural Collaboration from Nyoongar Country Michelle Johnston

https://textbookfull.com/product/working-two-way-stories-ofcross-cultural-collaboration-from-nyoongar-country-michellejohnston/

PRAISE FOR SOCIALISM SUCKS

“What a captivating idea Socialism Sucks embraces! A worldwide tour guide written in plain English by two high-end economists. An invasion of the world’s most highly regulated hot spots where they can’t even efficiently produce or distribute something as simple and lovable as beer A down-to-earth, almost fable-like lesson showing socialism’s failures for all the world to see. And it even has some sidesplitting hilarity thrown in. I knew these guys were great; but I didn’t know this side of them. Buy this book. Give it to your children and grandchildren, and to anyone who touts the nonsense now fashionable in some American circles—that government power somehow produces more happiness than personal liberty.”

“Every country that enters socialism gets more miserable; every country that leaves it prospers: that’s the lesson of history so far. Robert Lawson’s and Ben Powell’s light-hearted book drives home this message in a refreshingly readable way. From Venezuela’s immiseration to Georgia’s liberation, the authors sample every socialist, ex-socialist, semisocialist and supposedly socialist experiment, beer by beer.”

, author of e Evolution of Everything

“Professors Robert Lawson and Benjamin Powell do a yeomen ’ s job in proving that socialism sucks, the apt title for their new book. ey show why there’s no stampede into countries like Venezuela and Cuba and other socialist darlings of the U.S. leists. What’s more, over a couple of drinks, Lawson and Powell prove that Sweden is not as socialistic as portrayed by our leists.”

“In theory, socialism sucks and economists know why. Here are two economists who ventured far beyond the ivory tower to discover that in practice, the theory is right. is is the tragic story of mass suffering in the name of an insane idea, told with sympathy, insight, and no small amount of black humor. Read it and weep; read it and laugh; read it and learn.”

—STEVEN LANDSBURG, professor of economics, University of Rochester, and author of the Armchair Economist

“What is ‘socialism’? And do countries that overindulge in it wake up with bad hangovers? You bet they do. Robert Lawson and Benjamin Powell give you the hair-of-the-dog cure.

ey provide a dose of political economy knowledge mixed with an understanding of the benefits of economic freedom, add a strong dash of humor, and top it off with a cold beer. Have a Bob & Ben Eye-Opener and you’ll feel like (and live in a place where you can make) a million dollars!”

—P. J. O’ROURKE, author of #1 New York Times bestseller Parliament of Whores and Holidays in Hell

For Tracy, Lisa, Keri & Raymond

In appreciation for your patience with our travels

FOREWORD

In 2013, Venezuela was the poster child for socialism.

It was the standard against which celebrities and politicos alike measured the United States’ economy, which they found wanting.

At Salon, David Sirota let us know that yes, this was socialism, and yes, it should incite envy in Americans. Venezuelan president Hugo Chávez, said Sirota, with his “full-throated advocacy of socialism,” had “racked up an economic record that . . . American president[s] could only dream of achieving.”

Fashionable opinion couldn’t say enough about Venezuela and its president. Sean Penn, Danny Glover, Oliver Stone, and Michael Moore were the tip of the iceberg.

And then, by 2017, Venezuela the very country these commentators had been lecturing everyone about, and which Sirota had praised for its “full-throated advocacy of socialism” suddenly became not real socialism, even though nothing about it had changed.

Well, I guess at least one thing changed: by 2016 nearly three out of four Venezuelans lacked a diet that researchers considered optimal (that’s a generous way of putting it), and nearly 16 percent had resorted to eating garbage.

Oh, we don’t want Venezuela, say our “democratic socialists” today. Why, we want Sweden!

is kind of claim might be more believable had so many of the people making it not cheered Venezuela right up to the moment that starvation and

chaos were everywhere.

ere ’ s plenty to say regarding Sweden: (1) its “socialist” policies were made possible by wealth created under an essentially capitalist economy (as recently as the 1950s, remember, government spent less as a percentage of GDP in Sweden than in the U.S.); (2) Swedes earn about 50 percent more in the U.S., in our supposedly wicked economy; and (3) since Sweden’s explosion of social welfare spending there have been zero jobs created on net in the private sector.

No, thanks.

In recent years, sympathy for socialism in the U.S. has grown rapidly. No doubt one reason was the financial crisis of 2008. Critics felt certain that this episode revealed a profound sickness at the heart of American capitalism. Yet the crisis would certainly not have happened without the twin evils of government policy and Federal Reserve intervention, both of which are something like the opposite of capitalism.

And there’s another, more fundamental reason: it’s an easy argument to follow. (1) ose people over there have lots of money. (2) You would like some money. (3) We are happy to facilitate the transfer.

e rich,” meanwhile, are caricatured and despised as a matter of routine. And while it’s true that some people have come by their wealth in disreputable ways, made possible by government, socialist critics are not making fine distinctions like this. It is wealth per se, no matter how acquired, that is to be condemned.

Not a moment’s thought is applied to wondering what the rich might actually do for the economy. We are to believe that they roll around in their cash until it sticks to their sweaty bodies.

Not a word about investment in capital goods, which make the economy more physically productive and increase real incomes. Nothing about capital maintenance, which keeps the structure of production up and running. Nothing about saving at all, since most popular critics of capitalism appear to think consumption is what really contributes to economic health as if simply using things up could make us rich.

From this standpoint, socialism seems to make sense. ere are no unintended consequences of government intervention worth thinking about. We have rich people over there, and things we’d like to do with their money over here, so what’s the problem? If there’s an outcome we want, why, we simply legislate it into existence! Want higher wages? Just pass a law!

If this were true, poverty could have been conquered anytime, anywhere. We ought to call the folks in Bangladesh and let them know: poverty is over! You just need to pass some laws!

Now were we to impose the American regulatory apparatus, and American labor laws and wage requirements, on Bangladesh, virtually the entire country would become instantly unemployable and poverty would only intensify.

It’s almost as if there’s something other than regulation and redistribution that accounts for economic progress.

Among the great merits of Socialism Sucks are that it’s short, engaging, and easily digested which is precisely what the anti-socialist, pro-freedom side needs right now.

Your guides on the tour of the unfree world you are about to embark upon could scarcely be better chosen, I might add. Bob Lawson, who has done extensive research on the economic freedom of the various countries of the world, has important insight into what works and what doesn’t. Ben Powell’s book on sweatshops, published by Cambridge University Press, explains what needs to be done (and what needs to be avoided) for the developing world to prosper as well as the various ways that ignorant, if sometimes well-intentioned, Westerners retard that process.

Turn the page, and your journey begins. e good news: when it’s all done, you can close the book and be back in semi-capitalist America.

At least for now, that is.

INTRODUCTION

NOT SOCIALISM: SWEDEN

SEPTEMBER 2009

“If I’ve got one major bitch about Sweden,” I said as I sat across the table from Bob at the Duvel Café in Stockholm, “it’s the alcohol prices.”

e Duvel Café isn’t a dive, but it’s not a swanky, high-end bar either. Behind its plain, black, street-front exterior is a five-seat bar with highalcohol Belgian beers on tap, a few booths, and the uncomfortable wooden window seat that was causing a major pain in my ass. Yet, despite the relative geographic proximity to Belgium, our Belgian beers cost far more than what we were accustomed to paying in the U.S.

“Fucking taxes,” he answered. “Sweden has to pay for its welfare state.” He was right. Sweden taxes alcohol at rates higher than most countries. In fact, Sweden taxes everything. A lot.

Sweden is the first stop on our tour of socialist countries, even though it’s not a socialist country. Wait. What? You heard Sweden was an example of how socialism works? ough lots of people believe Sweden is a socialist country, and some of our politicians try to use that misunderstanding to advance their own agendas, we ’ re going to present evidence to the contrary. But first, let me give you a little background about Bob and me, so you’ll know where we ’ re coming from.

Bob grew up in Cincinnati, Ohio. His background is working-class, and he’s a lifelong fan of Cincinnati’s subpar professional sports teams. While earning his PhD at Florida State University in the early 1990s, Bob became

involved in a project analyzing quantitative data that would finally settle a question that has long been a point of disagreement among social scientists: whether a more capitalist government or a more socialist government creates conditions that translate to a better quality of life for its citizens.

e idea for Bob’s economic freedom index, published in the Fraser Institute’s annual Economic Freedom of the World report, started with Milton Friedman, the Nobel Prize–winning economist, and Michael Walker, the executive director of the Fraser Institute in Vancouver. Since the mid-1990s, Bob has worked with Professor James Gwartney of Florida State to put out the Fraser Institute’s annual economic freedom index. We’ll talk about the index a lot in this book. Bob was a professor at Shawnee State and Capital University, both in Ohio, and Auburn University in Alabama, before he landed his current gig in Dallas where he is the director of the O’Neil Center for Global Markets and Freedom at the Cox School of Business at Southern Methodist University.

I come from a similar working-class background in Haverhill, Massachusetts, about thirty miles north of Boston, and remain an avid fan of Boston’s decidedly superior sports franchises. Our differing allegiances don’t hurt our friendship. In fact, Bob’s a loyal enough fan of his Bengals to bet me a bottle of liquor, without the benefit of a spread, each time they play the Patriots. I’ve enjoyed drinking those bottles, though I suspect he’s regiing me the booze he’s won from another friend of his who insists on rooting for the Browns.

I earned my PhD at George Mason University and went on to be a professor at San Jose State University in California and Suffolk University in Boston before taking a position as an economics professor and director of the Free Market Institute at Texas Tech University six years ago.

Bob and I became friends at a Mont Pelerin Society meeting in Salt Lake City in 2004. e economist Friedrich Hayek founded the society in Mont Pelerin, Switzerland, in 1947, bringing together accomplished academics from around the world concerned with the spread of socialism and totalitarianism. Over the years, eight members of the Mont Pelerin Society

have won Nobel Prizes, including Hayek and Friedman. Today, the society has more than five hundred members not just academics, but business, political, and intellectual leaders who share a commitment to defending freedom.

Salt Lake City was dry back in 2004, except for “private clubs,” essentially bars that sold short-term memberships as a cover charge. Bob and I became members and drinking companions at one such club near our hotel, and we climbed our first mountain together in the nearby Wasatch Range. We’ve since shared countless drinks, attended dozens of economics conferences, and climbed many mountains.

Bob and I also share a devotion to freedom and free markets. But our devotion is not mere ideology, it is also informed by economic theory and evidence. Nobel prize–winning economist James Buchanan believed understanding economic principles allows “the average man . . . to command the heights of genius,” but that without these principles “he is a jibbering idiot.”1 In many ways we ’ re fairly regular guys, but our training in economic theory and our analysis of economic data allow us to see, understand, and explain the world a little differently than most people—and, we hope, help us to avoid being “jibbering idiots.”

is book is a truthful accounting of our travels, and so includes our sometimes excessive drinking, low-grade misogyny, and salty language. We are white, middle-aged, American males who are not “woke” and don’t even know what “intersectionality” means. If that offends you, you can put this book down and read one of our boring academic journal articles instead. It will make the same points but without the local color.

In this book, though, we ’ re aiming for a popular audience that will appreciate not just our economic insights but our down-to-earth honesty. We wrote this book because too many people seem to be dangerously ignorant of what socialism is, how it functions, and its historical track record. We also wanted to get drunk in Cuba, and this was a great way to write off our expenses.

In the spring of 2016, a Harvard survey found that a third of eighteen- to twenty-nine-year-olds supported socialism.2 Another survey, from the Victims of Communism Memorial Foundation, reported that millennials supported socialism over any other economic system.3

e Young Democratic Socialists of America, which had only twelve chapters on college campuses at the end of 2016, burgeoned to nearly fiy chapters by fall 2017.4 Twenty-year-old Michelle Fisher, the national co-chair of the organization, said, “I think people in my generation people who grew up post-Cold War I don’t think socialism is as much a scarlet S as it is for older folks. . . . e taboo for me was never there.”5

Obviously not. e Victims of Communism survey found that 31 percent of millennials had a favorable view of Che Guevara; 23 percent thought well of Vladimir Lenin; and 19 percent approved of Mao Zedong, so at least two out of ten millennials apparently think that mass murder in the interest of socialism isn’t so bad. at’s one of the taboos that’s fallen.

But it isn’t just young people who ignore or deny socialism’s pernicious past. In 2017, the New York Times ran a weekly column, “Red Century: Exploring the history and legacy of Communism, 100 years aer the Russian Revolution.”6 While the columnists and topics varied from week to week, there was little focus on the intentional mass killings carried out by socialist regimes. Nor was there much mention of the economic insanity of socialist governments that resulted in millions of people starving to death. In an entire year ’ s worth of columns, only one discussed how socialism led to economic stagnation. Overwhelmingly, the Times treated us to columns about how socialism was merely an advanced form of liberalism, highlighting the allegedly green policies of “Lenin’s Eco-Warriors” and instructing us on “Why Women Had Better Sex Under Socialism.”

At about the same time, Bernie Sanders, a self-proclaimed democratic socialist, made a strong run for the Democratic Party nomination for president, getting 43 percent of the vote in the 2016 Democratic primaries.

How can so many Americans view socialism so favorably, when in practice it has led to misery and mass murder? e answer is that, like the New York Times, many people assume that socialism is merely a more generous form of liberalism.

e Victims of Communism survey found that only a third of millennials could define socialism correctly. In the first Democratic Party debate, Sanders was asked how a socialist could win a general election in the United States. He pointed to “countries like Denmark, like Sweden and Norway,” as examples of his version of socialism.7 But those countries aren’t socialist.

Sweden does have a big welfare state, government-provided health care, and generous unemployment benefits, and the drinks at Duvel Café were indeed highly taxed. But welfare and entitlement programs, however highly prized by socialism’s acolytes, are not the defining components of socialism.

e economic freedom index that Bob helped create is probably the best way to measure whether a country has a more capitalist or socialist system. e index uses a zero-to-ten scale, with higher scores indicating a more capitalist system. If a country earns a high score on the index, that generally means that country keeps government taxation low, respects private property rights, maintains the value of its currency, lets people trade freely, and keeps regulations to a minimum.

So how does Sweden stack up? Overall, Sweden gets a 7.54 rating, which is good enough for twenty-seventh place out of the 159 countries in the study. Sure, Sweden taxes the bejesus out of its citizens. Its tax-and-spend score is very low indeed 3.64 out of 10. It regulates labor markets quite a lot (6.81) as well, but overall it does a good job protecting property rights (8.35), avoiding inflation (9.71), allowing free trade (8.28), and only lightly regulating credit markets (9.90) and businesses more generally (8.08). Of the other Nordic countries Comrade Bernie mentioned, Denmark rates 8.0 and Norway 7.62. All three rank in the top fih of the most economically free countries in the world.

Bottom line: Sweden is a prosperous, mostly capitalist country. When we were there we could see this with our own eyes. e Swedes were obviously

wealthy, their buildings were well maintained, and their beer was good and cold. In fact, what we saw was consistent with the research that uses the economic freedom index to measure the impact of economic freedom on living standards. In a recent review of nearly two hundred academic studies, Bob and his co-author Joshua Hall concluded, “Over two-thirds of these studies found economic freedom to correspond to a ‘good’ outcome such as faster growth, better living standards, more happiness, etc. Less than four percent of the sample found economic freedom to be associated with a ‘bad’ outcome such as increased income inequality.”8

Although Sweden is still mostly free today, it used to be even freer. Our Swedish friend, Johan Norberg, has told the story of how laissez-faire economic reforms made Sweden rich.9 In his telling, back in the early 1860s his ancestors were so poor that they had to mix tree bark into their bread recipe when they were short on flour. Incomes in Sweden at that time were on par with those in the Congo today. Meanwhile, life expectancies were half as long and infant mortality rates three times as high as they are in many modern poor countries.

But nineteenth-century economic reformers liberalized Sweden’s economy and created a prosperous, capitalist country. Our personal favorite reformer, Lars Johan Hierta, is honored with a copper statue about a kilometer from the Duvel Café. We like Lars because he championed free speech, equal rights for women, business freedom, free trade, small government, and the repeal of public drunkenness laws (as long as the drunk didn’t threaten anyone). Cheers to that!

Ben and Bob, along with fellow economist Brad Hobbs, enjoy some excellent but highly taxed Belgian beer in Sweden

Hierta and other reformers eventually implemented many of their policies, and Sweden grew rapidly. Between 1850 and 1950 incomes

increased eightfold, life expectancy rose twenty-eight years, and infant mortality fell from 15 to 2 percent. By 1950 Sweden was one of the richest countries in the world, and it still had a small government. Its total tax burden, at 19 percent of gross domestic product (GDP), was lower than that of the United States and other European countries.

It’s only relatively recently that Sweden’s tax burden and size of government have ballooned. Government spending exploded from 31 to 60 percent of GDP in the twenty years between 1960 and 1980. High taxes and big government spending alone don’t constitute socialism, but they do have consequences. As Sweden’s government grew, its economy stagnated. It was the fourth-richest country in the OECD (a group of rich countries) in 1970, but by 2000 it had fallen to fourteenth place. Sweden grew most when it was freer than it is today. But even today, it remains relatively economically free and prosperous, and its policies are far from socialist.

If Sweden isn’t socialist, then what is? is is where Americans seem to be confused. Propagandists like Michael Moore don’t help when they tweet out things like “Most polls now show young adults (18-35) across America prefer socialism (fairness) to capitalism (selfishness).” Socialism doesn’t simply equal “fairness.” What it really equals is the abolition of private property; in a socialist economy, the government decides what will be produced, how, and for whom.

Most countries are neither purely capitalist nor purely socialist. All capitalist economies allow, for good or ill, some government ownership of resources and centralized economic planning. Likewise, most socialist countries allow some degree of economic freedom or they would suffer even worse economic consequences.

e Soviet Union during its period of War Communism (1918–21) and China during the Great Leap Forward (1958–62) came closest to abolishing private property. Aer each of these massive failures, the Communist governments offered limited private ownership of some means of production and allowed small markets to operate, though socialism predominated.

Today, there are only three countries that remain nearly entirely socialist: North Korea, Venezuela, and Cuba. Other officially socialist countries, like China, are only nominally so, but actually allow for so much private ownership and control that they qualify as mixed economies.

We’ll visit these places and also three former Soviet countries that are trying to reform Russia, Ukraine, and Georgia. We’ll combine our firsthand travel observations with economic theory, history, and empirical social science to try and understand what’s going on in these places.

For us, as travelers, socialist economic policies can be an inconvenience, but for those who live under them, they can impose brutal and unnecessary suffering, which makes us angry and might make you angry too.

So, with that warning, pack your carry-on, order a stiff drink from the flight attendant, and let’s embark on our tour of the unfree world.

CHAPTER

ONE

STARVING SOCIALISM: VENEZUELA

JANUARY 2017

“You guys need to go to Venezuela,” our old friend, Marshall Stocker, told us over lobster and beer in New Hampshire in late July 2016. Marshall is a sort of “adventure capitalist.” He was in Egypt doing real estate deals during the Arab Spring before he had to cut his losses and get out of town. Now he runs an emerging markets mutual fund for a big firm in Boston. Bob and I enjoy following his Facebook page, which highlights his travels to exotic locales like the jungles of Myanmar or the Mongolian desert as he looks for countries to invest in.

We agreed. Venezuela was on our list, but Venezuela is a complete fucking mess. Our wives, Lisa and Tracy, had already laid down the law we weren’t allowed to get killed or end up in prison while working on this book. I suppose bigger life insurance policies would’ve appeased them somewhat, but hey neither of us has a death wish, either.

Marshall had a suggestion that made the trip sound safer and more practical. “Just fly into Colombia and travel to the Venezuelan border. You can check out what’s going on from there and maybe venture across. at’ll be safe enough. Besides, there’s a lot of crazy economic activity on the border.”

e more we thought about it, the better the idea sounded. Venezuela, the most recent darling of socialism’s proponents, isn’t tarnished with the same long history of political repression as other countries. Venezuela was

an example of “democratic” socialism. At least until recently, it was the model that Western intellectuals admired and held up for emulation as a socialist paradise. Now things are falling apart, but the apologists still insist the country’s problems have nothing to do with socialism.

Western intellectuals, whom Lenin called “useful idiots,” tend to overlook or make excuses for socialist regimes’ economic failures and humanitarian atrocities. Today, the idiots are running out of places to admire. Almost no sane person holds up North Korea as a model state.1 While Castro apologists still tout Cuban health care and education, most everyone else recognizes that Cuba’s Communist regime is politically repressive and economically backward.

Venezuela was supposed to be different. In 1992, Colonel Hugo Chávez was jailed for two years aer a failed coup attempt. He then became a politician and won the 1998 presidential election with 56.2 percent of the vote, in what was viewed as a more or less fair election. Chávez established a new constitution in 1999 and was reelected a year later with 59.8 percent of the vote.

To many observers, Chávez’s brand of “Bolívarian Socialism” (named aer the nineteenth-century anti-colonialist revolutionary Simón Bolívar) seemed to be a success. In 2011, Bernie Sanders claimed, “ese days, the American dream is more apt to be realized in South America, in places such as Ecuador, Venezuela and Argentina, where incomes are actually more equal today than they are in the land of Horatio Alger. Who’s the banana republic now?”2

Similarly, upon Chávez’s death in 2013, the website Salon published an article titled “Hugo Chávez’s Economic Miracle” which claimed that “Chávez racked up an economic record that a legacy-obsessed American president could only dream of achieving.”3

We needed to experience this socialist paradise for ourselves. Aer following the news stories about trade on the Colombia-Venezuela border for a few months, we scheduled our trip. On January 2, 2017, still sporting

our respective New Year’s hangovers, we took a short overnight flight from Dallas to Bogotá and continued on to Cúcuta the next morning.

Cúcuta was a pleasant surprise. Colombia’s sixth-largest city, with a population of 650,000, Cúcuta boasted an impressive skyline, attractive architecture, and well-maintained office buildings. e streets, though sometimes congested, were in good condition. ere were a variety of restaurants and shopping options within a short walk of our downtown hotel. When we went out for drinks at night, we felt as safe as we would anywhere else in Latin America.

We weren’t there to see Cúcuta, though. We were there because Cúcuta is on the west bank of the shallow and muddy Río Táchira, where two bridges and other, unofficial river crossings connect Colombia with Venezuela. is was where Venezuelans, in their early socialist days, had once smuggled goods into Colombia to be sold for market prices, and thus a profit. Today, it’s where Venezuelans buy staple goods that are unavailable at home.

On our way to the Santander Bridge, which was the smaller of the two official crossings, we met up with Julian Villabona, a reporter with the PanAm Post. A mutual friend had introduced us to Julian, and he agreed to help us speak with people at the border while he wrote his own story for the Post’s website.

Aer a short drive, the four-lane, paved road terminated at a dusty intersection near the Santander Bridge, which was closed to vehicular traffic. ere were around a dozen small permanent roadside stores and at least twice as many temporary roadside stands, which offered a wide variety of basic goods and necessities flour, cooking oil, sugar, toilet paper, candy, beans as well as bigger-ticket items, like tires, that were in short supply in Venezuela.

e bridge swarmed with foot traffic. Every day, thousands of Venezuelans come with suitcases, bags, carts, backpacks, and crates, and load them with whatever they can afford and carry home. ese weren’t impoverished Venezuelans; these were members of the middle class who had the means to travel to the border and buy goods.

When we reached the Colombian checkpoint, halfway across the bridge, Julian asked what we wanted to do. e Colombian border police were checking passports only haphazardly; we could walk right into Venezuela if we wanted but could we come back into Colombia?

ousands crossed back and forth across this bridge between Venezuela and Colombia every day in search of basic necessities

Julian had a brief conversation with the guard, who shrugged his shoulders, convincing Julian that reentry was no hay problema for two gringo economists and their guide, and we crossed into Venezuela. e Venezuelan checkpoint had a lone man in uniform. He didn’t care about us either; he was too busy sorting through a woman ’ s bags and confiscating items for himself.

Compared with the hustle and bustle of the shops on the Colombian side of the river, the Venezuelan side was eerily quiet. e official duty-free store had long since been abandoned. e only other establishment was a large gas station that had an attendant dutifully waiting at every pump.

e Venezuelan government subsidizes gasoline prices so that, at about fiy cents a gallon, Venezuela enjoys some of the world’s cheapest gas. But even with fuel that cheap, there were no customers for the well-staffed gas station; Venezuela’s socialist planners apparently hadn’t foreseen that a bridge closed to vehicles might not have many customers.

As we walked toward the village of Ureña, Julian became visibly uncomfortable. ough we didn’t have bags of goods to steal, Bob and I were the only Americans in sight, making us targets for robbery or kidnapping. We agreed it was best not to hang around too long in Venezuela, and technically, without visas, we were there illegally. We eventually switched directions, joined the Venezuelans heading west, and returned to Colombia without incident.

Aer perusing a few shops, we found what we required Bahia, a Colombian cerveza. e shop fronted the dirt road and sported a few plastic chairs and a table. e music was loud, but the beer was cold and we had a good view of the comings and goings.

What we observed was a damned shame. Venezuela once boasted one of the freest economies in the world, according to Bob’s index. In 1970, Venezuela scored 7.2, making it the world’s tenth-freest economy. And when Venezuela’s economy was free, the country was relatively prosperous. According to the World Bank, in 1967 the average Venezuelan was $1,995 richer than the average Spaniard.

But by 2014, the average Venezuelan earned only about $200 more than he had in 1967. In nearly fiy years, Venezuelans experienced essentially zero economic growth, while Spaniards had seen their average income more than double. And by some estimates, Venezuelan incomes have dropped 50 percent since 2014 so the economy has moved from stagnation to collapse. Today, Venezuela ranks dead last in the economic freedom index, with a score of about 3.4

As economists, Bob and I know that economic freedom almost inevitably leads to good economic outcomes, because free people have both the incentive and the ability to improve their own lives, and, in the process, the lives of others. Adam Smith put it best in his book e Wealth of Nations when he wrote of an “invisible hand” that guided individual economic selfinterest to a greater good. As Smith put it: “Every individual . . . neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it . . . he intends only his own security; and by directing that

industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention.”5

is “invisible hand” requires two things: freedom and the rule of law. Law is needed to secure property rights, and people need freedom to voluntarily trade goods and services at freely set prices.

Sitting in a market in Colombia, you can see in practice what economists can explain in theory. Free markets and market prices convey important information. ey tell consumers whether a good is plentiful (and therefore cheap) or scarce (and therefore expensive). In turn, what consumers are willing to pay informs producers and entrepreneurs what goods are most valuable—something that can vary by time, place, and customer. e goal of the entrepreneur is to make money, not to promote economic efficiency or economic development. But by meeting customer demand, entrepreneurs inevitably make an economy more efficient and successful, provided that the pricing system is accurate, which is what a free and open market ensures. Anything that impedes free trade also impedes the accuracy of prices.

Even more fundamental is private property, which makes it possible to own, and therefore buy and sell, goods. Other factors are at play too, of course. Inflation, caused by the government’s reckless printing of money, distorts prices. Taxes and regulations do the same by placing additional costs on trade.

When Venezuela was a freer economy, it was relatively prosperous. But as the government became more involved in regulating the economy, it became progressively less free, less efficient, and less productive. When Chávez came to power, this process was already well underway; he only doubled down on it and turned economic regression into economic disaster. Venezuela’s insecure property rights, nationalized industries, punitive taxes, monetary inflation, and business-stifling regulations resulted in what we saw in vivid and heartbreaking detail at the Santander Bridge on the ColombianVenezuelan border: impoverished middle-class Venezuelans, lugging home

bundles of sugar, rice, beans, and diapers. We saw what economic theory can mean in economic fact.

Desperate Venezuelans line up trying to get an entry visa to Colombia. An estimated four million Venezuelans have fled the country since the crisis began

e next morning, we went to the Simón Bolívar Bridge. Again, the Colombian side was alive with commerce, only more so: a chaotic jumble of people, delivery vehicles, buses, cabs, motorcycles, and push carts, maneuvering through a labyrinth of clogged, dusty roads lined with shops.

Vendors called out to Venezuelans coming into Colombia, and one woman ’ s cry in particular “ ¡Compramos pelo!” caught our attention.

“Let’s talk to her,” I said. “I read about this.”

Denise was known as a “dragger” a middleman. She explained that she was finding Venezuelan women who wanted to sell their hair. She would bring them to a makeshi barbershop where their hair would be cut and used to make extensions.

“ ¿Cuánto cuesta?”

I wanted to know what she paid women for their hair. She shook her head, saying something I didn’t understand. Julian explained, “She thinks you want to sell your hair. She doesn’t want it. It’s too short and red to be marketable.”

Julian told her what I meant to say in Spanish, and she said the price varied depending on the quality and the length, but for very good, long hair, maybe as much as eighty U.S. dollars.

According to a Reuters article I’d read, mid-length hair fetched around sixty thousand Colombian pesos, which, at the time, was about twenty U.S. dollars. at might not sound like much, but it’s about what a Venezuelan with a minimum wage job and food rations earns in a month. Here at the border, even twenty bucks would help bring home valuable necessities.

We ventured briefly into Venezuela again, but all the action was on the Colombian side of the border, so we came back and talked to Venezuelans lugging their heavy bags in the hot sun. Most seemed nervous and on guard robberies are prevalent and spoke only briefly and warily, telling us they came to buy necessities; they were generally more talkative entering Colombia than leaving it.

One obviously middle-class couple, Paulo and Ana María, talked at length with us. ey had come from Ciudad Bolívar in far eastern Venezuela to buy supplies. According to Google Maps, Ciudad Bolívar is about 780 miles to the east, an estimated eighteen hours by car. e journey took them three days, they said, because it was too dangerous to drive at night.

Paulo told us, “We’ve come to buy rice, medicine, soap, shampoo, and other things, like car parts, unavailable at home.” ey had been coming to Colombia every three months, he added, but this was their last trip because “the danger from bandits is getting too great.”

ey had to make these journeys in the first place because of Venezuela’s socialist policies, which had destroyed domestic production of basic goods and limited the availability of imports. In the early days of Chávez’s presidency, annual food imports to Venezuela averaged about $75 per person. Aer Chávez confiscated more than ten million acres of private farmland, food production collapsed and food imports soared. By 2012, shortly before Chávez’s death, food imports had reached an average of $370 per person each year. Today, the Venezuelan government can’t afford to

subsidize food imports, so the people have to find food on the black market or in Colombia.

Julian told us about Sabrina Martin, a reporter working on a story about new bakery regulations in Venezuela. She told him that bakeries are supposed to buy imported flour from the government (which has a monopoly on imported flour). e government, however, does not have enough flour to meet demand; government-imposed price controls make it impossible for the bakeries to turn a profit; and government regulations that require bakeries to offer bread throughout the business day mean that bakery owners have to break the law either by buying flour on the black market or by having bare shelves and in either event they are expected to run their businesses at a loss.

We had read a similar story, in which the government confiscated millions of toys from a toy company and arrested its executives because the price of toys was allegedly too high! ese stories are not uncommon in Venezuela. Sabrina interviewed Víctor Maldonado, executive director of the Chamber of Commerce, Industry, and Services of Caracas.6 Maldonado reported that in 2016 alone, more than 30,000 Venezuelan companies closed. Venezuela had 800,000 companies before Hugo Chávez came to power in 1999, but only about 230,000 remain today.

e Confederation of Farmer Associations (Fedeagro) reported that the production of rice, corn, and coffee in Venezuela has fallen by 60 percent over the last decade. Similarly, the number of beef cattle in the country has decreased by 38 percent over the past five years according to Vicente Carrillo, the former president of Venezuela’s cattle ranchers’ association.

e collapse of private businesses has forced people to rely on the government for handouts, but there is never enough to go around. People line up early in the morning to get government-rationed food and supplies, but the lines are long, the items are few, and the recipients are targets for thieves.

at brings us back to the bridges near Cúcuta, where there are no government-monopoly wholesalers, no arbitrary price controls, no limits on

profits, and where markets can provide what the Venezuelan government cannot.

e stores in Colombia were well stocked. ere were three or four pharmacies near the bridge selling a wide variety of medicines and supplies. Bulk food was everywhere, and pallets of bags of rice were constantly being off-loaded from trucks and into the storefronts. Phone cards, cooking oil, diapers, pre-packaged snacks, juice drinks, and many other basic goods were widely available. ere were roadside stands selling food and ice cream. According to Julian, prices were cheap, even by local standards. A pound of rice went for less than a dollar.

e only thing we couldn’t find was beer. It was available for takeaway from stores, but we were looking for a place to sit and people-watch. Eventually we found a small, dusty place with a few beat-up plastic chairs that had a beer cooler. It wasn’t on one of the main shopping alleys, but it was the only option around. We grabbed a couple Bahias, which cost about thirty-three cents each.

Not only were the beers cheap, but we counted ourselves fortunate because, to Venezuelans, beer had become something of a luxury. In Venezuela, six months earlier, there was no beer at all. at’s right they ran out of beer. Empresas Polar, the country’s largest brewer, which produces 70 to 80 percent of Venezuela’s beer, had closed all four of its breweries the previous April when they ran out of malted barley.

More accurately, the company ran out of foreign exchange necessary to buy imported barley.7 Barley isn’t grown in Venezuela’s tropical climate. In a market economy, Empresas Polar would have traded domestic currency in the foreign exchange market to buy whatever imported ingredients it needed. But Venezuela’s planners control access to foreign exchange and didn’t allocate enough to the company to import the needed barley. Yet according to the government, the problem is that Lorenzo Mendoza, Polar’s CEO, is a “thief and a traitor” trying to undermine the socialist regime.8 Meanwhile, Venezuelans went thirsty.

As horrifying as a shortage of beer sounds, it’s nowhere near the worst of Venezuela’s problems. Venezuelans aren’t just thirsty. ey ’ re hungry. Most Venezuelans don’t have access to a market like the one we were at. As a result, according to a survey done by universities in Venezuela, threequarters of adults had lost an average of nineteen pounds during 2016. Caritas, a Catholic humanitarian organization, found that among children under five years old, more than 11 percent suffered from moderate or severe malnutrition. e situation has only become worse since our visit. Venezuelans lost an average of twenty-four pounds in 2017.9 Venezuela’s socialist policies are literally starving the country.

Two months aer our visit, the Ministry of Health released statistics showing that infant mortality rates had shot up 30 percent in 2016, and the minister who released the statistics was promptly fired. So much for Article 83 of Venezuela’s constitution, which declares: “Health is a fundamental social right and the responsibility of the State, which shall guarantee it as part of the right to life.” I guess no one told Chávez that writing down a “right” to something on a piece of paper doesn’t magically make it materialize.

But it was certainly enough to fool the Hollywood Le. When Chávez died in 2013, Sean Penn wrote, “Today the people of the United States lost a friend it never knew it had. And poor people around the world lost a champion.” Similarly, Oliver Stone, the chief idiot among the useful idiots, who produced a farce of a documentary on Chávez, Mi Amigo Hugo, that even Foreign Policy found “disgraceful,” wrote, “I mourn a great hero to the majority of his people and those who struggle throughout the world for a place.”10 e ever-obnoxious Michael Moore tweeted, “Hugo Chávez declared the oil belonged 2 the ppl. He used the oil $ 2 eliminate 75% of extreme poverty, provide free health & education 4 all. at made him dangerous.”

No, what made him dangerous to the Venezuelan people—was that high oil prices disguised how he was destroying the country’s economy. Aer Venezuela became an unmistakable economic basket case, the

Hollywood sycophants and leies like Bernie Sanders suddenly went quiet. But when pressed, the useful idiots blamed Venezuela’s collapse on falling oil prices, as if it were a natural calamity that could afflict any country.

But the truth is, not only had prices fallen, so had Venezuela’s oil production. Despite sitting on the world’s largest known oil reserves, oil production was at a twenty-three-year low, because of socialism. Nationalized oil companies hadn’t maintained their pipelines and refineries, because they had no profit motive to do so.

Kevin Grier, an economist colleague of mine at Texas Tech, co-authored a cool, empirical study that compared the performance of Venezuela’s economy during the oil boom against the economies of similar, but nonsocialist, countries. Guess what? Venezuela’s economy had improved, but by less than that of the other countries; in fact, Kevin says that if Venezuela had not followed socialist policies, Venezuelan incomes would have been 20 to 30 percent higher. What high oil prices had done was hide that Venezuela was falling behind its neighbors economically and just keeping pace when it came to measurements of poverty and infant mortality. Once oil prices fell, the mask was off.

So with production cratering and oil revenues drying up, where is the Venezuelan government getting its money? at’s easy. ey ’ re running a printing press, and you don’t have to be a drunk economist to know that results in inflation. Prices are rising faster and faster every year from over 30 percent in 2008 to as high as 1,600 percent in 2016, according to media reports. Today it is even worse. Inflation was estimated at 18,000 percent in March and April 2018 alone.11 e reality is it’s almost impossible to measure inflation properly in a country with such massive shortages and controlled prices.

Hyperinflation is one of the most destructive things a government can do to an economy. It devastates the balance sheets of banks and other lenders, and as a result, borrowing and lending grind to a halt. Virtually every house, factory, and business you ’ ve ever seen was created with borrowed funds, and failing banks mean no new houses, factories, or businesses. Inflation

Another random document with no related content on Scribd:

CHAPTER XI DOSTOIEVSKY’S ANNIVERSARY

S. P, February 24th.

They are celebrating the 25th anniversary of the death of Dostoievski, and this fact has brought back to my mind, with great vividness, a conversation I had with the officers of the battery at Jentzen-tung last September, and which I have already noted in my diary.

We were sitting in the ante-room of the small Chinese house which formed our quarters. This ante-room, which had paper windows and no doors, a floor of mud, and a table composed of boards laid upon two small tressels, formed our dining-room. We had just finished dinner, and were drinking tea out of pewter cups. Across the courtyard from the part of the dwelling where the Chinese herded together, we could hear the monotonous song of a Chinaman or a Mongol singing over and over to himself the same strophe, which rose by the intervals of a scale more subtle than ours and sank again to die away in the vibrations of one prolonged note, to the accompaniment of a single-stringed instrument.

The conversation had languished. Somebody was absorbed in a patience, we were talking of books and novels in a vague, desultory fashion, when suddenly Hliebnikov, a young Cossack officer, said: “Who is the greatest writer in the world?” Vague answers were made as to the comparative merits of Homer, Dante, Shakespeare, and Molière, but Hliebnikov impatiently waived all this talk aside. Then turning to me he said: “He knows; there is one writer greater than all of them, and that is Dostoievski.”

“Dostoievski!” said the doctor. “Dostoievski’s work is like a clinical laboratory or a dissecting-room. There is no sore spot in the human

soul into which he does not poke his dirty finger. His characters are either mad or abnormal. His books are those of a madman, and can only be appreciated by people who are half mad themselves.”

The young Cossack officer did not bother to discuss the question. He went out into the night in disgust. We continued the argument for a short time. “There is not a single character,” said the doctor, “in all Dostoievski’s books who is normal.” The doctor was a cultivated man, and seeing that we differed we agreed to differ, and we talked of other things, but I was left wondering why Hliebnikov was so convinced that Dostoievski was the greatest of all writers, and why he knew I should agree with him. I have been thinking this over ever since, and in a sense I do agree with Hliebnikov. I think that Dostoievski is the greatest writer that has ever lived, if by a great writer is meant a man whose work, message, or whatever you like to call it, can do the greatest good, can afford the greatest consolation to poor humanity. If we mean by the greatest writer the greatest artist, the most powerful magician, who can bid us soar like Shelley or Schubert into the seventh heaven of melody, or submerge us like Wagner beneath heavy seas until we drown with pleasure, or touch and set all the fibres of our associations and our æsthetic appreciation vibrating with incommunicable rapture by the magic of wonderful phrases like Virgil or Keats, or strike into our very heart with a divine sword like Sappho, Catullus, Heine, or Burns, or ravish us by the blend of pathos and nobility of purpose with faultless diction like Leopardi, Gray, and Racine, or bid us understand and feel the whole burden of mankind in a thin thread of notes like Beethoven or in a few simple words like Goethe, or evoke for us the whole pageant of life like Shakespeare to the sound of Renaissance flutes, or all Heaven and Hell like Dante, by “thoughts that breathe and words that burn”?

If we are thinking of all these miraculous achievements when we say a great writer or the greatest writer, then we must not name Dostoievski. Dostoievski is not of these; in his own province, that of the novelist, he is as a mere workman, a mere craftsman, one of the worst, inferior to any French or English ephemeral writer of the day you like to mention; but, on the other hand, if we mean by a great writer a man who has given to mankind an inestimable boon, a priceless gift, a consolation, a help to life, which nothing can equal or

replace, then Dostoievski is a great writer, and perhaps the greatest writer that has ever lived. I mean that if the Holy Scriptures were destroyed and no trace were left of them in the world, the books where mankind, bereft of its Divine and inestimable treasure, would find the nearest approach to the supreme message of comfort would be the books of Dostoievski.

Dostoievski is not an artist; his stories and his books are put together and shaped anyhow. The surroundings and the circumstances in which he places his characters are fantastic and impossible to the verge of absurdity. The characters themselves are also often impossible and fantastic to the verge of absurdity; yet they are vivid in a way no other characters are vivid, and alive, not only so that we perceive and recognise their outward appearance, but so that we know the innermost corners of their souls. His characters, it is said, are abnormal. One of his principal figures is a murderer who kills an old woman from ambition to be like Napoleon, and put himself above the law; another is a victim to epileptic fits. But the fact should be borne in mind that absolutely normal people, like absolutely happy nations, have no history; that since the whole of humanity is suffering and groaning beneath the same burden of life, the people who in literature are the most important to mankind are not the most normal, but those who are made of the most complex machinery and of the most receptive wax, and who are thus able to receive and to record the deepest and most varied impressions. And in the same way as Job and David are more important to humanity than George I. or Louis-Philippe, so are Hamlet and Falstaff more important than Tom Jones and Mr. Bultitude. And the reason of this is not because Hamlet and Falstaff are abnormal—although compared with Tom Jones they are abnormal—but because they are human: more profoundly human, and more widely human. Hamlet has been read, played, and understood by succeeding generations in various countries and tongues, in innumerable different and contradictory fashions; but in each country, at each period, and in each tongue, he has been understood by his readers or his audience, according to their lights, because in him they have seen a reflection of themselves, because in themselves they have found an echo of Hamlet. The fact that audiences, actors, readers, and commentators have all interpreted Hamlet in utterly contradictory ways testifies not merely to the profound humanity of the character but to its

multiplicity and manysidedness. Every human being recognises in himself something of Hamlet and something of Falstaff; but every human being does not necessarily recognise in himself something of Tom Jones or Mr. Bultitude. At least what in these characters resembles him is so like himself that he cannot notice the likeness; it consists in the broad elementary facts of being a human being; but when he hears Hamlet or Falstaff philosophising or making jokes on the riddle of life he is suddenly made conscious that he has gone through the same process himself in the same way.

So it is with Dostoievski. Dostoievski’s characters are mostly abnormal, but it is in their very abnormality that we recognise their profound and poignant humanity and a thousand human traits that we ourselves share. And in showing us humanity at its acutest, at its intensest pitch of suffering, at the soul’s lowest depth of degradation, or highest summit of aspiration, he makes us feel his comprehension, pity, and love for everything that is in us, so that we feel that there is nothing which we could think or experience; no sensation, no hope, no ambition, no despair, no disappointment, no regret, no greatness, no meanness that he would not understand; no wound, no sore for which he would not have just the very balm and medicine which we need. Pity and love are the chief elements of the work of Dostoievski —pity such as King Lear felt on the heath; and just as the terrible circumstances in which King Lear raves and wanders make his pity all the greater and the more poignant in its pathos, so do the fantastic, nightmarish circumstances in which Dostoievski’s characters live make their humanness more poignant, their love more lovable, their pity more piteous.

A great writer should see “life steadily and see life whole.” Dostoievski does not see the whole of life steadily, like Tolstoi, for instance, but he sees the soul of man whole, and perhaps he sees more deeply into it than any other writer has done. He shrinks from nothing. He sees the “soul of goodness in things evil”: not exclusively the evil, like Zola; nor does he evade the evil like many of our writers. He sees and pities it. And this is why his work is great. He writes about the saddest things that can happen; the most melancholy, the most hopeless, the most terrible things in the world; but his books do not leave us with a feeling of despair; on the contrary, his own “sweet reasonableness,” the pity and love with which they are filled are like

balm. We are left with a belief in some great inscrutable goodness, and his books act upon us as once his conversation did on a fellow prisoner whom he met on the way to Siberia. The man was on the verge of suicide; but after Dostoievski had talked to him for an hour —we may be sure there was no sermonising in that talk—he felt able to go on, to live even with perpetual penal servitude before him. To some people, Dostoievski’s books act in just this way, and it is, therefore, not odd that they think him the greatest of all writers.

CHAPTER XII THE POLITICAL PARTIES

M, March 11th.

The political parties which are now crystallising themselves are the result of the Liberal movement which began in the twenties, and proceeded steadily until the beginning of the war in 1904, when the Liberal leaders resolved, for patriotic reasons, to mark time and wait. This cessation of hostilities did not last long, and the disasters caused by the war produced so universal a feeling of discontent that the liberation movement was automatically set in motion once more.

On the 19th of June, 1905, a deputation of the United Zemstva, at the head of which was Prince S. N. Troubetzkoi, was received by the Emperor. Prince Troubetzkoi, in a historic speech, expressed with the utmost frankness and directness the imperative need of sweeping reform and of the introduction of national representation. The coalition of the Zemstva formed the first political Russian party, but it was not until after the great strike, and the granting of the Manifesto in October, that parties of different shades came into existence and took definite shape. During the month which followed the Manifesto the process of crystallisation of parties began, and is still continuing, and they can now roughly be divided into three categories—Right, Centre, and Left, the Right being the extreme Conservatives, the Centre the Constitutional Monarchists, and the Left consisting of two wings, the Constitutional Democrats on the right and the Social Democrats and Social Revolutionaries on the left. Of these the most important is the party of the Constitutional Democrats, nicknamed the “Cadets.” “Cadets” means “K.D.,” the word “Constitutional” being spelt with a “K” in Russian, and as the letter “K” in the Russian alphabet has the same sound as it has in

French, the result is a word which sounds exactly like the French word “Cadet.” Similarly, Social Revolutionaries are nicknamed “S.R.’s” and the Social Democrats “S.D.’s.”

In order to understand the origin of the Constitutional Democrats one must understand the part played by the Zemstva. In 1876 a group of County Councillors, or Zemstvoists, under the leadership of M. Petrunkevitch devoted themselves to the task of introducing reforms in the economical condition of Russia. In 1894 their representatives, headed by M. Rodichev, were summarily sent about their business, after putting forward a few moderate demands. In 1902 these men formed with others a “League of Liberation.” M. Schipov tried to unite these various “Zemstva” in a common organisation, and some of the members of the Liberation League, while co-operating with them, started a separate organisation called the Zemstvo Constitutionalists. Among the members of this group were names which are well known in Russia, such as Prince Dolgoroukov, MM. Stachovitch, Kokoshkin, and Lvov. But these “Zemstvoists” formed only a small group; what they needed, in order to represent thinking Russia, was to be united with the professional classes. In November, 1904, the various professions began to group themselves together in political bodies. Various political unions were formed, such as those of the engineers, doctors, lawyers, and schoolmasters. Then Professor Milioukov, one of the leading pioneers of the Liberal movement, whose name is well known in Europe and America, united all professional unions into a great “Union of Unions,” which represented the great mass of educated Russia. Before the great strike in October, 1905, he created, together with the best of his colleagues, a new political party, which united the mass of professional opinion with the small group of Zemstvo leaders. He had recognised the fact that the Zemstvoists were the only men who had any political experience, and that they could do nothing without enrolling the professional class. Therefore it is owing to Professor Milioukov that the experienced Zemstvo leaders in October had the whole rank and file of the middle class behind them, and the Constitutional Democrats, as they are at present, represent practically the whole “Intelligenzia,” or professional class, of Russia. This party is the only one which is seriously and practically organised. This being so, it is the most important of the political parties.

Those of the Right have not enough followers to give them importance, and those of the Left have announced their intention of boycotting the elections. These various parties are now preparing for the elections.

We are experiencing now the suspense of an entr’acte before the curtain rises once more on the next act of the revolutionary drama. This will probably occur when the Duma meets in April. People of all parties seem to be agreed as to one thing, that the present state of things cannot last. There is at present a reaction against reaction. After the disorders here in December many people were driven to the Right; now the reactionary conduct of the Government has driven them back to the Left.

So many people have been arrested lately that there is no longer room for them in prison. An influential political leader said to me yesterday that a proof of the incompetence of the police was that they had not foreseen the armed rising in December, whereas every one else had foreseen it. “And now,” he said, “they have been, so to speak, let loose on the paths of repression; old papers and old cases, sometimes of forty years ago, are raked up, and people are arrested for no reason except that the old machine, which is broken and thoroughly out of order, has been set working with renewed energy.” The following conversation is related to me—if it is not true (and I am convinced that it is not true) it is typical—as having taken place between a Minister and his subordinate:—

The Subordinate: There are so many people in prison that there is no possibility of getting in another man. The prisons are packed, yet arrests are still being made. What are we to do? Where are these people to be put?

The Minister: We must let some of the prisoners out.

The Subordinate: How many?

The Minister: Say five thousand.

The Subordinate: Why five thousand?

The Minister: A nice even number.

The Subordinate: But how? Which? How shall we choose them?

The Minister: Let out any five thousand. What does it matter to them? Any five thousand will be as pleased as any other to be let out.

It is interesting to note that last November the Minister of the Interior was reported to have said that if he could be given a free hand to arrest twenty thousand “intellectuals,” he would stop the revolution. The twenty thousand have been arrested, but the revolution has not been stopped.

So far, in spite of the many manifestoes, no guarantee of a Constitution has been granted. The Emperor has, it is true, declared that he will fulfil the promises made in his declaration of the 17th of October, and it is true that if these promises were fulfilled, the result would be Constitutional Government. But at the same time he declared that his absolute power remained intact. At first sight this appears to be a contradiction in terms; but, as the Power which granted the Manifesto of October 17th was autocratic and unlimited, and as it made no mention of the future limiting of itself, it is now, as a matter of fact, not proceeding contrarily to any of its promises. The liberties which were promised may only have been meant to be temporary. They could be withdrawn at any moment, since the Emperor’s autocratic power remained. The Manifesto might only have been a sign of goodwill of the Emperor towards his people. It promised certain things, but gave no guarantee as to the fulfilment of these promises. The whole of Russia, it is true, understood it otherwise. The whole of Russia understood when this Manifesto was published that a Constitution had been promised, and that autocracy was in future to be limited. What Count Witte understood by it, it is difficult to say. Whether he foresaw or not that this Manifesto by its vagueness would one day mean much less than it did then, or whether he only realised this at the same time that he realised that the Conservative element was much stronger than it was thought to be, it is impossible to determine. The fact remains that the Emperor has not withdrawn anything; he has merely not done what he never said he would do, namely, voluntarily abdicate his autocratic power.

The Conservatives are opposed to any such proceeding; not in the same way as the extreme reactionaries, some of whom relegated the portrait of the Emperor to the scullery on the day of the Manifesto from sheer Conservative principle, but because they say that if the autocratic power is destroyed the peasant population will be convulsed, and the danger will be immense. To this Liberals—all liberal-minded men, not revolutionaries—reply that this supposed

danger is a delusion of the Conservatives, who have unconsciously invented the fact to support their theory and have not based their theory on the fact; that many peasants clearly understand and recognise that there is to be a constitutional régime in Russia; that if this danger does exist, the risk incurred by it must be taken; that in any case it is the lesser of two evils, less dangerous than the maintenance of the autocracy.

Count Witte’s opponents on the Liberal side say that the course of events up to this moment has been deliberately brought about by Count Witte; that he disbelieved and disbelieves in Constitutional Government for Russia; that he provoked disorder in order to crush the revolutionary element; that the Moderate parties played into his hands by not meeting him with a united front; that, Duma or no Duma, he intends everything to remain as before and the power to be in his hands. What his supporters say I do not know, because I have never seen one in the flesh, but I have seen many people who say that what has happened so far has been brought about with infinite skill and knowledge of the elements with which he had to deal. Further, they add that Count Witte has no principles and no convictions; that he has always accommodated himself to the situation of the moment, and worked in harmony with the men of the moment, whatever they were; that he has no belief in the force or the stability of any movement in Russia; that he trusts the Russian character to simmer down after it has violently fizzed; that he intends to outstay the fizzing period; that he has a great advantage in the attitude of the Moderate parties, who, although they do not trust him, play into his hands by disagreeing on small points and not meeting him with clear and definite opposition. They add, however, that he has miscalculated and wrongly gauged the situation this time, because the simmering down period will only be temporary and the fizzing will be renewed again with increasing violence, until either the cork flies into space or the bottle is burst. The cork is autocracy, the bottle Russia, and the mineral water the revolution. The corkscrew was the promise of a Constitution with which the cork was partially loosened, only to be screwed down again by Count Witte’s powerful hand.

Among all the parties the most logical seem to be the Extreme Conservatives and the Extreme Radicals. The Extreme Conservatives have said all along that the talk of a Constitution was nonsensical,

and the Manifesto of October 17th a great betrayal; that the only result of it has been disorder, riot, and bloodshed. They are firmly based on a principle. The Extreme Radicals are equally firmly based on a principle, namely, that the autocratic régime must be done away with at all costs, and that until it is swept away and a Constitution based on universal suffrage takes its place there is no hope for Russia. Therefore the danger that the Moderate parties may eventually be submerged and the two extremes be left face to face, still exists. As a great quantity of the Radicals are in prison they are for the time being less perceptible; but this era of repression cannot last, and it has already created a reaction against itself. But then the question arises, what will happen when it stops? What will happen when the valve on which the police have been sitting is released?

The influential political leader with whom I dined last night, and who is one of the leading members of the party of October 17th, said that there was not a man in Russia who believed in Witte, that Witte was a man who had no convictions. I asked why he himself and other Zemstvo leaders had refused to take part in the administration directly after the Manifesto had been issued, when posts in the Cabinet were offered to them. He said their terms had been that the Cabinet should be exclusively formed of Liberal leaders; but they did not choose to serve in company with a man like Durnovo, with whom he would refuse to shake hands.

He added that it would not have bettered their position in the country with regard to the coming Duma, which he was convinced would be Liberal. Talking of the Constitutional Democrats he said they were really republicans but did not dare own it.

CHAPTER XIII IN THE COUNTRY

S, G T, March 25th.

When one has seen a thing which had hitherto been vaguely familiar suddenly illuminated by a flood of light, making it real, living, and vivid, it is difficult to recall one’s old state of mind before the inrush of the illuminating flood; and still more difficult to discuss that thing with people who have not had the opportunity of illumination. The experience is similar to that which a child feels when, after having worshipped a certain writer of novels or tales, and wondered why he was not acknowledged by the whole world to be the greatest author that has ever been, he grows up, and by reading other books, sees the old favourite in a new light, the light of fresh horizons opened by great masterpieces; in this new light the old favourite seems to be a sorry enough impostor, his golden glamour has faded to tinsel. The grown-up child will now with difficulty try to discover what was the cause and secret of his old infatuation, and every now and then he will receive a shock on hearing some fellow grown-up person talk of the former idol in the same terms as he would have talked of him when a child, the reason being that this second person has never got farther; has never reached the illuminating light of new horizons. So it is with many things; and so it is in my case with Russia. I find it extremely difficult to recall exactly what I thought Russia was before I had been there; and I find Russia difficult to describe to those who have never been there. There is so much when one has been there that becomes so soon a matter of course that it no longer strikes one, but which to the newcomer is probably striking.

The first time I came to Russia I travelled straight to the small village where I am now staying. What did I imagine Russia to be like? All I can think of now is that there was a big blank in my mind. I had read translations of Russian books, but they had left no definite picture or landscape in my mind; I had read some books about Russia and got from them very definite pictures of a fantastic country, which proved to be curiously unlike Russia in every respect. A country where feudal castles, Pevenseys and Hurstmonceuxs, loomed in a kind of Rhine-land covered with snow, inhabited by mute, inglorious Bismarcks, and Princesses who carried about dynamite in their cigarette-cases and wore bombs in their tiaras; Princesses who owed much of their being to Ouida, and some of it to Sardou.

Then everything in these books was so gloriously managed; everybody was so efficient, so powerful; the Bismarcks so Machiavellian and so mighty; the Princesses so splendide mendaces. The background was also gorgeous, barbaric, crowded with Tartars and Circassians, blazing with scimitars, pennons, armour, and sequins, like a scene in a Drury Lane pantomime; and every now and then a fugitive household would gallop in the snow through a primæval forest, throwing their children to the wolves, so as to escape being devoured themselves. This, I think, was the impression of Russia which I derived before I went there from reading French and English fiction about Russia, from Jules Verne’s “Michel Strogoff,” and from memories of many melodramas. Then came the impressions received from reading Russian books, which were again totally different from this melodramatic atmosphere.

From Russian novels I derived a clear idea of certain types of men who drank tea out of a samovar and drove forty versts in a vehicle called a Tarantass. I made the acquaintance of all kinds of people, who were as real to me as living acquaintances; of Natascha and Levine, and Pierre and Anna Karenine, and Basaroff, and Dolly, and many others. But I never saw their setting clearly, I never realised their background, and I used to see them move before a French or German background. Then I saw the real thing, and it was utterly and totally different from my imaginations and my expectations. But now when I try to give the slightest sketch of what the country is really like the old difficulty presents itself; the difficulty which arises

from talking of a thing of which one has a clear idea to people who have a vague and probably false idea of the reality. The first thing one can safely say is this: eliminate all notions of castles, Rhine country, feudal keeps, and stone houses in general. Think of an endless plain, a sheet of dazzling snow in winter, an ocean of golden corn in summer, a tract of brown earth in autumn, and now in the earliest days of spring an expanse of white melting snow, with great patches of brown earth and sometimes green grass appearing at intervals, and further patches of half-melted snow of a steely-grey colour, sometimes blue as they catch the reflection of the dazzling sky in the sunlight. In the distance on one side the plain stretches to infinity, on the other you may see the delicate shapes of a brown, leafless wood, the outlines soft in the haze. If I had to describe Russia in three words I should say a plain, a windmill, and a church. The church is made of wood, and is built in Byzantine style, with a small cupola and a minaret. It is painted red and white, or white and pale-green. Sometimes the cupola is gilt.

The plain is dotted with villages, and one village is very like another. They consist generally of two rows of houses, forming what does duty for a street, but the word street would be as misleading as possible in this case. It would be more exact to say an exceedingly broad expanse of earth: dusty in summer, and in spring and autumn a swamp of deep soaking black mud. The houses, at irregular intervals, sometimes huddled close together, sometimes with wide gaps between them, succeed each other (the gaps probably caused by the fact that the houses which were there have been burnt). They are made of logs, thatched with straw; sometimes (but rarely) they are made of bricks and roofed with iron. As a rule they look as if they had been built by Robinson Crusoe. The road is strewn with straw and rich in abundance of every kind of mess. Every now and then there is a well of the primitive kind which we see on the banks of the Nile, and which one imagines to be of the same pattern as those from which the people in the Old Testament drew their water. The roads are generally peopled with peasants driving at a leisurely walk in winter in big wooden sledges and in summer in big wooden carts. Often the cart is going on by itself with somebody in the extreme distance every now and then grunting at the horse. A plain, a village, a church, every now and then a wood of birch-trees, every now and then a stream, a weir, and a broken-down lock. A great deal of dirt, a

great deal of moisture. An overwhelming feeling of space and leisureliness, a sense that nothing you could say or do could possibly hurry anybody or anything, or make the lazy, creaking wheels of life go faster—that is, I think, the picture which arises first in my mind when I think of the Russian country.

Then as to the people. With regard to these, there is one fact of capital importance which must be borne in mind. The people if you know the language and if you don’t are two separate things. The first time I went to Russia I did not know a word of the language, and, though certain facts were obvious with regard to the people, I found it a vastly different thing when I could talk to them myself. So different that I am persuaded that those who wish to study this country and do not know the language are wasting their time, and might with greater profit study the suburbs of London or the Isle of Man. And here again a fresh difficulty arises. All the amusing things one hears said in this country, all that is characteristic and smells of the Russian land, all that is peculiarly Russian, is like everything which is peculiarly anything, peculiarly English, Irish, Italian, or Turkish, untranslatable, and loses all its savour and point in translation. This is especially true with regard to the Russian language, which is rich in peculiar phrases and locutions, diminutives, and terms which range over a whole scale of delicate shades of endearment and familiarity, such as “little pigeon,” “little father,” &c., and these phrases translated into any other language lose all their meaning. However, the main impression I received when I first came to Russia, and the impression which I received from the Russian soldiers with whom I mingled in Manchuria in the war, the impression which is now the strongest with regard to them is that of humaneness. Those who read in the newspapers of acts of brutality and ferocity, of houses set on fire and pillaged, of huge massacres of Jews, of ruthless executions and arbitrary imprisonments, will rub their eyes perhaps and think that I must be insane. It is true, nevertheless. A country which is in a state of revolution is no more in its normal condition than a man when he is intoxicated. If a man is soaked in alcohol and then murders his wife and children and sets his house on fire, it does not necessarily prove that he is not a humane member of society. He may be as gentle as a dormouse and as timid as a hare by nature. His excitement and demented behaviour are merely artificial. It seems to me now that

the whole of Russia at this moment is like an intoxicated man; a man inebriated after starvation, and passing from fits of frenzy to sullen stupor. The truth of this has been illustrated by things which have lately occurred in the country. Peasants who have looted the spirit stores and destroyed every house within reach have repented with tears on the next day.

The peasants have an infinite capacity for pity and remorse, and therefore the more violent their outbreaks of fury the more bitter is their remorse. A peasant has been known to worry himself almost to death, as if he had committed a terrible crime, because he had smoked a cigarette before receiving the Blessed Sacrament. If they can feel acute remorse for such things, much more acute will it be if they set houses on fire or commit similar outrages. If you talk to a peasant for two minutes you will notice that he has a fervent belief in a great, good, and inscrutable Providence. He never accuses man of the calamities to which flesh is heir. When the railway strike was at its height, and we were held up at a small side station, the train attendant repeated all day long that God had sent us a severe trial, which He had. Yesterday I had a talk with a man who had returned from the war; he had been a soldier and a surgeon’s assistant, and had received the Cross of St. George for rescuing a wounded officer under fire. I asked him if he had been wounded. He said, “No, my clothes were not even touched; men all around me were wounded. This was the ordinance of God. God had pity on the orphan’s tears. It was all prearranged thus that I was to come home. So it was to be.” I also had tea with a stonemason yesterday who said to me, “I and my whole family have prayed for you in your absence because these are times of trouble, and we did not know what bitter cup you might not have to drink.” Then he gave me three new-laid eggs with which to eat his very good health.

March 29th.

To-day I went out riding through the leafless woods and I saw one of the most beautiful sights I have ever seen, a sight peculiarly characteristic of Russian landscape. We passed a small river that up to now has been frozen, but the thaw has come and with it the floods of spring. The whole valley as seen from the higher slopes of the woods was a sheet of shining water. Beyond it in the distance was a

line of dark-brown woods. The water was grey, with gleaming layers in it reflecting the white clouds and the blue sky; and on it the bare trees seemed to float and rise like delicate ghosts, casting clearly defined brown reflections. The whole place had a look of magic and enchantment about it, as if out of the elements of the winter, out of the snow and the ice and the leafless boughs, the spring had devised and evoked a silvery pageant to celebrate its resurrection.

M, April 6th.

I have spent twelve instructive days in the country; instructive, because I was able to obtain some first-hand glimpses into the state of the country, into the actual frame of mind of the peasants; and the peasants are the obscure and hidden factor which will ultimately decide the fate of Russian political life. It is difficult to get at the peasants; it is exceedingly difficult to get them to speak their mind. You can do so by travelling with them in a third-class carriage, because then they seem to regard one as a fleeting shadow of no significance which will soon vanish into space. However, I saw peasants; I heard them discuss the land question and the manner in which they proposed to buy their landlords’ property. I also had some interesting talks with a man who had lived among the peasants for years. From him and from others I gathered that their attitude at present was chiefly one of expectation. They are waiting to see how things turn out. They were continually asking my chief informant whether anything would come of the “levelling” (Ravnienie); this is, it appears, what they call the revolutionary movement. It is extremely significant that they look upon this as a process of equalisation. The land question in Russia is hopelessly complicated; it is about ten times as complicated as the land question in Ireland, and of the same nature. I had glimpses of this complexity. The village where I was staying was divided into four “societies”; each of these societies was willing to purchase so much land, but when the matter was definitely settled with regard to one society two representatives of two-thirds of that society appeared and stated that they were “Old Souls” (i.e., they had since the abolition of serfage a separate arrangement), and wished to purchase the lands separately in order to avoid its partition; upon which the representatives of the whole society said that this was impossible, and that they were the

majority. The “Old Souls” retorted finally that a general meeting should be held, and then it would be seen that the majority was in favour of them. They were in a minority; and in spite of the speciousness of their arguments it was difficult to see how the majority, whose interests were contrary to those of the “Old Souls,” could be persuaded to support them. This is only one instance out of many.

Another element of complication is that the peasants who can earn their living by working on the landlords’ land are naturally greatly averse from anything like a complete sale of it, and are alarmed by the possibility of such an idea. Also there is a class of peasants who work in factories, and therefore are only interested in the land inasmuch as profit can be derived from it while it belongs to the landlord. Again, there are others who are without land, who need land, and who are too poor to buy it. If all the land were given to them as a present to-morrow the result in the long run would be deplorable, because the quality of the land—once you eliminate the landlord and his more advanced methods—would gradually deteriorate and poverty would merely be spread over a larger area. One fact is obvious: that many of the peasants have not got enough land, and to them land is now being sold by a great number of landlords. To settle the matter further, a radical scheme of agrarian reform is necessary; many such schemes are being elaborated at this moment, but those which have seen the light up to the present have so far proved a source of universal disagreement. The fact which lies at the root of the matter is of course that if the land question is to be solved the peasant must be educated to adopt fresher methods of agriculture than those which were employed in the Garden of Eden; methods which were doubtless excellent until the fall of man rendered the cultivation of the soil a matter of painful duty, instead of pleasant recreation.

I asked my friend who had lived among the peasants and studied them for years what they thought of things in general. He said that in this village they had never been inclined to loot (looting can always arise from the gathering together of six drunken men), that they are perfectly conscious of what is happening (my friend is one of the most impartial and fair-minded men alive); they are distrustful and they say little; but they know. As we were talking of these things I

mentioned the fact that a statement I had made in print about the peasants in this village and in Russia generally reading Milton’s “Paradise Lost” had been received with interest in England and in some quarters with incredulity. It was in this very village and from the same friend, who had been a teacher there for more than twenty years, that I first heard of this. It was afterwards confirmed by my own experience.

“Who denies it?” he asked. “Russians or Englishmen?” “Englishmen,” I answered. “But why?” he said. “I have only read it myself once long ago, but I should have thought that it was obvious that such a work would be likely to make a strong impression.”

I explained that at first sight it appeared to Englishmen incredible that Russian peasants, who were known to be so backward in many things, should have taken a fancy to a work which was considered as a touchstone of rare literary taste in England. I alluded to the difficulties of the classicism of the style—the scholarly quality of the verse.

“But is it written in verse?” he asked. And when I explained to him that “Paradise Lost” was as literary a work as the Æneid he perfectly understood the incredulity of the English public. As a matter of fact, it is not at all difficult to understand and even to explain why the Russian peasant likes “Paradise Lost.” It is popular in exactly the same way as Bunyan’s “Pilgrim’s Progress” has always been popular in England. Was it not Dr. Johnson who said that Bunyan’s work was great because, while it appealed to the most refined critical palate, it was understood and enjoyed by the simplest of men, by babes and sucklings? This remark applies to the case of “Paradise Lost” and the Russian peasant. The fact therefore is not surprising, as would be, for instance, the admiration of Tommy Atkins for a translation of Lucretius. It is no more and no less surprising than the popularity of Bunyan or of any epic story or fairy tale. When people laugh and say that these tastes are the inventions of essayists they forget that the epics of the world were the supply resulting from the demand caused by the deeply-rooted desire of human nature for stories—long stories of heroic deeds in verse; the further you go back the more plainly this demand and supply is manifest. Therefore in Russia among the peasants, a great many of whom cannot read, the desire for epics is

strong at this moment. And those who can read prefer an epic tale to a modern novel.

Besides this, “Paradise Lost” appeals to the peasants because it is not only epic, full of fantasy and episode, but also because it is religious, and, like children, they prefer a story to be true. In countries where few people read or write, memory flourishes, and in Russian villages there are regular tellers of fairy tales (skashi) who hand down from generation to generation fairy tales of incredible length in prose and in verse.

But to return to my friend the schoolmaster. I asked him if “Paradise Lost” was still popular in the village. “Yes,” he answered, “they come and ask me for it every year. Unfortunately,” he added, “I may not have it in the school library as it is not on the list of books which are allowed by the censor. It is not forbidden; but it is not on the official list of books for school use.” Then he said that after all his experience the taste of the peasants in literature baffled him. “They will not read modern stories,” he said. “When I ask them why they like ‘Paradise Lost’ they point to their heart and say, ‘It is near to the heart; it speaks; you read and a sweetness comes to you.’ Gogol they do not like. On the other hand they ask for a strange book of adventures, about a Count or a Baron.” “Baron Munchausen?” I suggested. “No,” he said, “a Count.” “Not Monte Cristo?” I asked. “Yes,” he said, “that is it. And what baffles me more than all is that they like Dostoievski’s ‘Letters from a Dead House.’” (Dostoievski’s record of his life in prison in Siberia.) Their taste does not to me personally seem to be so baffling. As for Dostoievski’s book, I am certain they recognise its great truth, and they feel the sweetness and simplicity of the writer’s character, and this “speaks” to them also. As for “Monte Cristo,” is not the beginning of it epical? It was a mistake, he said, to suppose the peasants were unimaginative. Sometimes this was manifested in a curious manner. There was a peasant who was well known as a great drunkard. In one of his fits of drink he imagined that he had sold his wife to the “Tzar of Turkey,” and that at midnight her head must be cut off. As the hour drew near he wept bitterly, said goodbye to his wife, and fetching an axe said with much lamentation that this terrible deed had to be done because he had promised her life to the “Tzar of Turkey.” The neighbours eventually interfered and stopped the execution.

Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.