Download Governing health: the politics of health policy 5th edition, (ebook pdf) ebook All Chapters

Page 1


Governing Health: The Politics of Health Policy 5th Edition, (Ebook PDF)

https://ebookmass.com/product/governing-healththe-politics-of-health-policy-5th-edition-ebookpdf/

Download more ebook from https://ebookmass.com

More products digital (pdf, epub, mobi) instant download maybe you interests ...

Governing for Health: Advancing Health and Equity through Policy and Advocacy Fran Baum

https://ebookmass.com/product/governing-for-health-advancinghealth-and-equity-through-policy-and-advocacy-fran-baum/

Policy & Politics in Nursing and Health Care – E-Book (Policy and Politics in Nursing and Health) 7th Edition – Ebook PDF Version

https://ebookmass.com/product/policy-politics-in-nursing-andhealth-care-e-book-policy-and-politics-in-nursing-and-health-7thedition-ebook-pdf-version/

Health Policy and Politics: A Nurse’s Guide 6th Edition, (Ebook PDF)

https://ebookmass.com/product/health-policy-and-politics-anurses-guide-6th-edition-ebook-pdf/

Health Policy and Politics: A Nurseu2019s Guide

https://ebookmass.com/product/health-policy-and-politics-anurses-guide/

Policy & Politics in Nursing and Health Care

https://ebookmass.com/product/policy-politics-in-nursing-andhealth-care-ebook/

Essentials of Health Policy and Law (Essential Public Health) 4th Edition, (Ebook PDF)

https://ebookmass.com/product/essentials-of-health-policy-andlaw-essential-public-health-4th-edition-ebook-pdf/

Policy and Politics for Nurses and Other Health Professionals 3rd Edition, (Ebook PDF)

https://ebookmass.com/product/policy-and-politics-for-nurses-andother-health-professionals-3rd-edition-ebook-pdf/

Policy and Politics for Nurses and Other Health Professionals 3rd Edition – Ebook PDF Version

https://ebookmass.com/product/policy-and-politics-for-nurses-andother-health-professionals-3rd-edition-ebook-pdf-version/

Health Policy Analysis 3rd Edition – Ebook PDF Version

https://ebookmass.com/product/health-policy-analysis-3rd-editionebook-pdf-version/

Introduction

It had been a long time coming when in 2010 the Obama administration and a Democratic Congress passed by a single vote in the Senate and by legislative sleight-of-hand in the House a historic reform of US health care, the Affordable Care Act (ACA). The changes leveled the playing field in health insurance by requiring all Americans to buy and all sellers to sell to all comers, mandated that large and mid-sized employers provide insurance or pay fees for government coverage, and ended preexisting condition exclusions in health insurance policies as well as a plethora of other industry abuses that companies indulged in to protect themselves from adverse selection, moral hazard, and an inevitable death spiral if they enrolled too many sick patients. Access to care was expanded by the ACA through these market reforms, through broadened Medicaid coverage in states that chose to accept a generous offer of federal support for expansion, and through state or federal exchanges that sold comprehensive policies at reasonable premiums made affordable by subsidies based upon a sliding scale of income.

But the Republicans hated the ACA (which they dubbed Obamacare) in part because of the way the law was passed namely, by avoiding the necessity of a confirming Senate vote that would have fallen one vote short of ending a fatal filibuster. (A liberal Democratic senator had died and been replaced by a Republican after the bill left the Senate, so there was no chance of passing it there again if the House made too many changes.) But conservatives also hated the law because, in their view, it inappropriately expanded the role of the federal government into areas they believe are better

left to the private market or state governments. Thus, when the Republicans took over the House after the 2012 election, they began a series of nearly 60 votes to repeal Obamacare. The votes won a majority in each Republican House time after time, even though President Barack Obama was sure to veto the bill. But while Republicans knew they were shooting legislative blanks, they also thought that the vote might garner favor with supporters without causing much pain to some constituents. Nonetheless, when President Donald J. Trump took office in 2017, supported by Republican control of both houses, the repeal failed because three Republican senators balked. Two could not support the damage it would do to their constituents who were happy with their ACA coverage, and one was offended by the closed-door drafting of the bill that led to the repeal vote. Given the tiny majority the Republicans had in the Senate, the repeal went down in defeat, just one vote short.

Still, President Trump vowed to keep his campaign promise to repeal Obamacare, and he set about doing as much as he could with his executive authority. Thus, Congress terminated the ACA mandate that all Americans buy insurance, the president ended some subsidies that made many poor Americans able to afford insurance, and granted states authority to offer less comprehensive and shorter-term policies than called for by the ACA all of which also served his purpose of undermining public approval and confidence in the ACA. In addition, by delaying announcement of whether insurance carriers will be paid back for subsidies they are required by the law to grant to low-income people, he created uncertainty expected to drive some insurers out of the market. Other orders restricted funds and time for open enrollment and outreach enrollment assistance to eligible people, barred regional office staff from participating in open enrollment events, invited governors to request waivers of ACA requirements, allowed employers to opt out of contraception coverage if they have religious or moral objections, and directed federal agencies to find additional ways to permit sale of insurance that does not meet ACA standards.

To appreciate the full potential harm to the ACA of these efforts, it is important to understand one simple reality of insurance: For a company to avoid bankruptcy because too many sick people enroll, it must be careful that

people who are not sick also enroll. Those who enroll with a company become its “risk pool.” If the risk pool gets too sick, the company must raise its prices, with the effect that the least sick people now refuse to buy insurance, even as the sickest can’t afford to go without it. Consequently, the pool gets sicker as only those who are sick or very much fear getting sick enroll at high prices. This is called the death spiral of insurance: As rising premiums drive out first the well and then the less sick, the pool becomes sicker and sicker and premiums go higher and higher.

The ACA protected insurers against a death spiral by requiring everyone to buy comprehensive policies and by preventing insurers from setting prices based upon medical need. The changes made by President Trump and federal agencies at his direction has had the effect of eroding the strategies designed by law to guarantee that the insurance risk pools include healthy and younger people and are not dominated by sick and older people. The result has been an inevitable shrinking of the risk pool in many counties, a sicker, more expensive group of buyers willing to buy insurance, flight from those markets by insurance companies that fear that costs will exceed premiums, and requests by remaining insurers for much higher premiums. With access to insurance coverage beginning to narrow and the number of uninsured rising again from the historic lows reached following implementation of the ACA, the pool has been becoming sicker as only the sickest patients have been willing to pay the higher premiums.

If you are a supporter of health insurance for everyone, this is very bad. If you believe that the federal government had no business usurping the states’ role in health insurance regulation, then these steps that undermine the ACA and may cause it to fail in many counties means less federal overreach. These divergent views generally reflect political alignment: Most Democrats want the ACA preserved and improved; many Republicans want it to shrink, one way or the other. President Trump wants it gone. That is what he promised in his campaign.

If Democrats were to regain control of Congress, they might be able to put some fixes back in place, provided President Trump did not veto them something he would likely do unless Congress offered deals on other administration priorities.

Yet come what may with the ACA, there are still significant problems with American health care. Our costs continue to far outstrip those of comparable nations, our drug prices are far higher than those of other countries, and our care intensity varies widely from hospital to hospital, city to city, and state to state, with much of the care rendered proving ineffective and probably wasteful.

But there are hopeful signs. Some incentives for improvement were adopted in another new, less salient, law: the Medicare Access and CHIP Reauthorization Act of 2015 (MACRA). In a rare instance of both bipartisan cooperation and acceptance by the physician community, Congress passed a major reform of the way Medicare pays physicians and other providers, hoping to move their payment incentives away from volume and toward effective performance. The goal of the law is to ensure that more providers follow best practice guidelines, rendering only care of proven effectiveness for the patient’s condition, reporting diagnoses and treatments to electronic health records systems, innovating while avoiding unnecessary expense, and achieving markers of quality and cost-conscious performance. Meeting standards means earning bonuses. Departure from standards, excessive volume, high cost care, and other unreformed behaviors lead to fines. How tough the performance standards will be and how hard the fines will bite will be greatly influenced by regulations to be written by an executive agency, the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid (CMS). Critics feared that force of the law would be blunted by the Trump administration.

Such is the way of American policymaking in health care. What we pay for health care, how much we rely upon market competition versus regulation, how much we accept differences in the quality of health care, how much excessive, unneeded, and potentially harmful care we tolerate and pay for, and how some of us run into financial and other access barriers when we try to get care are all aspects of health policy and are shaped by many forces. These include the president, Congress, federal agencies, physicians, drug companies, unions, hospitals, medical equipment makers, insurance companies, managed care organizations, patient advocates and other interest groups, state legislatures and state bureaucracies, and all of us consumers of health care who demand that we have access to all the care that is available,

whether we need it or not. Republicans tend to favor market solutions and fear bureaucratic interference in medical decision making. They worry that an overbearing federal government will create a dependent class. Democrats criticize the market approach as unrealistic, given the many restraints on competition, and worry that it will produce barriers to insurance and care, which will create a divided society consisting of the nonpoor who are in good health and the poor who are in ill health. Policies change between administrations of different partisan persuasion, though frequently ideas from one administration are adopted by another. Republican President George W. Bush won passage of Medicare prescription drug coverage, an idea that had been pushed by his predecessor, Democrat Bill Clinton. President Obama’s ACA adopted market exchanges to sell ACA policies, an idea long favored by Republicans. Or did Republican Senator Marco Rubio (FL), who pushed the state legislature to fund a small health exchange in his home state when he was leader in the of Florida’s House of Representatives, get his idea from the Republican-derided “health alliances” offered in President Bill Clinton’s failed 1994 health insurance plan?

US health care policy reflects the complex cultural, political, economic, social, historical, and institutional forces that shape it. This book explores how government makes health policy, including the partisan political forces that influence decisions. Most health care in the United States is delivered by the private sector, but because public policy pays for and regulates so much of this care, health policy is vitally important. Moreover, private payers for health care tend to mimic the payment approaches of public policy, so public policy’s reach extends even farther into the private portion of health care policy another reason that foes of large government oppose the potential distortions that they fear will result from government insurance. Because so much of health care is outsourced and becomes the income stream of privatesector providers, claims processors, makers of health care products, and others, private interest groups have a huge stake in public policy and find it a good bargain to spend rather lavishly on lobbying and other strategies aimed at influencing public health care policy.

Most industrialized countries pay for most of their citizens’ health care publicly. We place more faith in private payment and attendant market

competition to reduce prices and improve access and quality. In general, it has not worked, in part because our delivery system restricts competition in a number of ways: Some providers or insurers dominate their markets, many drugs enjoy patent protection, which they are then able to extend through a variety of means, consumers are not well equipped to act as informed buyers, and interest-group lobbies resist cost and price disclosure, disclosure of performance data, and regulatory efforts.

Our federal system continues to require a partnership between the federal and state governments in health care provision and reform. Often this leads to new ideas bubbling up from the states to the federal realm. Yet, partisanship can sometimes be a barrier to cooperation. When it came time to implement major reform programs such as the ACA-mandated expansion of Medicaid in every state, 27 of them sued the federal government and received a favorable ruling from the US Supreme Court saying the states could not be forced to expand their programs. So many Republican states did not expand. And many accepted President Trump’s invitation to impose more restrictive qualifications upon those seeking Medicaid, including requirements that they be employed or looking for work, earn incomes lower than the maximums set for eligibility by the ACA, be tested for drug use, pay higher deductibles for emergency care, and limit time participating in the program. Creative state officials are likely to come up with additional ideas for CMS to consider, and President Trump has made it clear that he wants CMS to do what it can to approve state requests, including those that may threaten the viability of the ACA.

This book examines the US experience with governing health. It is a political science book about health care policy written by political scientists, who, as former journalists, respect the role of the news as a first draft of history. Accordingly, we combine political science theory with a heavy reliance upon timely news reports of the continuing saga of health care policy. A theme of the book concerns health policy as the product of the US government’s unique ways of combining several forces:

the increasing, and increasingly pervasive, power of ideological polarization and party politics;

the need for members of Congress to constantly seek reelection, claim credit, trade votes, and overcome uncertainty in their policy choices; the waxing and waning persuasive power of the presidency, promising much, sometimes delivering, but often disappointing; the discretion exercised by the bureaucracy in its role as agent of the president, Congress, the courts, its clients, and the public; the pervasive and well-financed influence of the burgeoning army of special health interests, the coalitions they form, the millions they spend, and the strategies they employ to frame issues and shape health policy to their liking; the growing tests of strength between traditional health policy interests and ideologically motivated campaign donors; the continuing struggle of the states, torn between being supplicants, seeking more financial support from the federal government, and being sovereigns, desperate to control their own health policy destinies while trying to hew to partisan persuasions; and the challenge of effective problem definition, the choice of solutions, and various models of the policy process, all incomplete but each capturing an aspect of the insights we need if we are ever to predict policy outcomes.

The first edition of Governing Health grew out of a frustration with the absence of a text written by political scientists for use in health politics classes. Sociologists and economists have authored or contributed to a small number of worthy volumes bringing their own disciplines’ perspectives to the topic of health politics and policy, and although they have much to offer, a gap remains. Politics is more than the sociology of institutions or the workings of economic self-interest. Politics is about power, and the making of health policy is nothing if not the wielding of power. Institutional rules endow some actors with more power than others, differential endowments of other types give some interests more power than others, and the fleeting saliency of the issues themselves sometimes gives one side more bargaining power than another. This book illuminates how institutions and the policymaking process wield power over health policy.

The intended audience is students of health policy who need to understand that problems as well as solutions are political and must be treated as part of the policy process; health policy analysts who want to become more adept at gauging the political feasibility of their proposals; health professionals who seek a better understanding of how policy is made and how they might change it; health system managers who are savvy enough to see that in a system in which nearly half the money and most of the paperwork burden come from government, they need to understand how government makes its policies; and political scientists who seek illustrations of how the principles of government work in a policy arena with all the ingredients of political conflict: saliency, huge financial stakes, powerful interests, and venues in all the institutions of government. We present a comprehensive synthesis of political science research on the institutions of government and the policy process, as well as an extensive review of the policies that have governed health care for more than a generation. We try hard to keep the book as interesting as the health care policy debate really is by illustrating political science concepts with contemporary examples of changing policies, partisan fights, implacable ideologies, congressional posturing and one-upsmanship, indefatigable policy entrepreneurs and pleading patient advocates, correcting and corrupting interest-group influence, compliant and defiant bureaucrats and state actors, upbraiding court decisions, and presidents whose popularity enhances or hobbles their ability to lead this army of passion and plunder.

We begin each chapter with a comparison that shows how different the institution under study looked during various periods when new presidential administrations began their policymaking quests, each one ushering in a new era of public health policy.

President Lyndon Johnson in 1965 rode the crest of a Democratic wave of power and ideas and a growing consensus that elderly and poor Americans, at least, deserved a health care subsidy. But he stretched the compromise by eliminating means testing from his Medicare proposal and set the stage for waste and excess use of care with his payment methods.

President Ronald Reagan in 1981, elected with a mandate to shrink and

constrain government-supported health care, welfare, and social services, oversaw the passage of a major Medicare expansion program to cover catastrophic events and costs.

President Barack Obama in 2009 took health care policy by the horns, shepherded a legislative victory that made major expansions of coverage, major reforms of the insurance industry, and some modest inroads toward cost control and quality improvement, but even with a Democratic Congress was unable to produce the comprehensive, costsaving health care reform he promised in his campaign.

President Donald Trump promised repeal of the Obama plan and was strongly supported by a Republican Congress committed to doing so, but then failed in a narrow showdown with senators of his own party. He went on to demonstrate that the presidency has considerable power to do many things that may lead to the failure of Obamacare in many of the nation’s health care markets, acting through tweets, executive orders, regulatory relaxation, and directives to executive agency leadership and staff, as well as taking advantage of the president’s unique ability to frame issues and sway public opinion.

Chapter 1, “The Policy Process,” introduces health care policymaking and illustrates how it touches our lives. We start by comparing the plights of two sisters who live in Florida and experience health policy in different ways in order to show that policy really does affect patient access, care, and financial burden. We provide an overview of the ACA and President Trump’s changes to some of its key provisions, as well as a summary of some of the major health policy initiatives that have brought us to our present system. We note the influence of other policies, including the Emergency Medical Treatment and Active Labor Act (EMTALA), on access to care and on workman’s compensation and thereby illustrate that health policy comes from many quarters and takes many shapes. We contrast public and private policy. We describe the essential role of problem definition in policy formation and identify some of the sources of demand for policy change. We review models of public policymaking, including the Garbage Can model, advocacy coalitions, and institutional analysis development, among others. We review

categories of public policy including procedural, regulatory, morality, economic, comprehensive, incremental, and others in a discussion replete with examples. We consider the importance of issue framing and causal attribution in policy analysis, again with examples. We discuss solution options and the necessity of considering market versus public options and criteria and looking at the elements of market failure most relevant to the health care market. We note the importance of ideology in evaluating market failure and the historical, institutional, and partisan preference for marketbased solutions wherever possible. We discuss equity, technical feasibility, administrative burden, and political feasibility as evaluation criteria for solution options and review the criticisms of the ACA, which contrast fairness with functionality and argue that subsidizing the premiums of sicker populations with higher premiums on those who are young and healthy will drive the latter out of the market, undercutting viability.

We note that legislators vote only on policies not on outcomes, why this is so, and how this practice explains the ambiguity of some public policy. We explore how policies occasionally have unintended consequences and may at times even worsen the lives of those whom they were intended to make better.

We review patient coverage options in such programs as Medicare and their implications for treatment sources and co-payment requirements, along with the gaps in Medicare coverage and the options for filling them. We identify proposals for major revisions of such programs as Medicare and Medicaid.

We discuss the role of research in policymaking and where data come from. We describe procedures of the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) for compiling basic health information such as birth and death certificates, tracking infectious disease outbreaks and seeking to prevent or control them, providing health education, and responding to vaccine shortages and antibiotic-resistant bacteria. We note how many of these basic public health functions differ in their implementation from state to state.

We catalogue the points of contention that have perennially plagued each major health reform proposal, including who will bear the cost burden and

what the appropriate role of government should be. We examine factors that help to explain the success of some policies and the failure of others, including saliency, timing, problem definition, institutional endowments, balkanized supporters, and others.

Finally, we describe the implementation process, the players involved, and factors that can make or break it. Each aspect is illustrated with examples from health policy options that have been considered and accepted or rejected.

Chapter 2, “Congress,” describes the structures and functioning of Congress and the motivations of its members. Its theme is that Congress was intended to be, and sometimes still is, the dominant branch of government. The chapter begins with a review of the ideas of the framers, who conferred on the legislative branch enormous powers and many binding constraints.

We describe shifts in power of party and institutional leadership and the roles and responsibilities of committees and subcommittees, which have long had special importance in health care policymaking. We also note that as partisan polarization has increased in recent years, conference committees have given way to more informal, leadership-crafted deals between the two Houses.

We devote considerable attention to the effects of party polarization on the ability of the houses to legislate, comparing partisanship in Congress and partisanship in the country and how it is manifested in the electoral process. We describe fundamental differences between the House and Senate, as well as the key role of leadership and its increasingly difficult job of holding together a majority in a party often split into factions.

We describe in detail the powerful role of committees and subcommittees in shaping health policy, focusing in particular on the House Ways and Means Committee, the Senate Finance Committee, the House Energy and Commerce Committee, and the Senate Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions Committee.

We chronicle the bill-drafting process, including debating, amending, and voting, a bill’s path from subcommittee to committee and its movement from house to house (as well as statistics showing the low likelihood of any given bill becoming a law, thanks to the many gatekeeping points in the law-

making process). We review the contentious and complementary relationships between presidents and Congress in periods of one-party dominance and the more frequent circumstance of divided government.

We detail the factors important to members considering whether or not to participate on an issue, how active to be, how to vote, and how to take cues on issues in which they are not heavily vested. We describe the congressional enterprise as well as the day to day work of a member of Congress. We explore the competition for members’ favor among interest groups, party and White House demands on them, their responsibilities and responses to constituents, and the pressures members feel to constantly raise money for reelection and produce a voting record that will help them in their quest to get reelected.

We review the models of congressional organization, why they are necessary to the body’s function, and how they manifest in rules and norms of behavior. We contrast Senate and House rule differences and their consequences, as well as the changes introduced to the filibuster.

Budgeting, the increasingly dominant task of a deficit-swelling Congress, is closely examined; we step carefully between the concepts that are likely to continue to characterize the process and the changing rules and terms that complicate it. We explain and illustrate deficits, debt, and the dire predictions that accompany their ever-steeper upward slopes. We explore the contentious reconciliation process, which can bypass the committee process and has long been a principal vehicle for modifying health policy.

We explain regular order, its frequent absence, how that happened, and why its continuing absence matters. We explain earmarks, their rise, stratospheric further rise, and eventual fall, the emergence of letter marks, phone marks, and the other incarnations of pork.

We discuss how Congress interacts with other institutions including federal agencies, states, and the judicial system.

Chapter 3, “The Presidency,” starts with the sources and scope of presidential power and the high-stakes rivalry that characterizes the relationship between the presidency and Congress even in the best of times. Focused as the book is on health care policymaking, the subject of this chapter is how the president makes choices in domestic problem solving. His

role in setting the agenda, proposing initiatives, and monitoring congressional progress is examined. A theme of the chapter is that there is much truth to the axiom that “a president proposes but Congress disposes.” The president is much more influential than any of the 535 members who work for or against him, but he is not, in the final analysis, a legislator, even though he can and does use executive orders, memos, suggestions, and uniquely with President Trump—tweets to move policy in directions he has been unable to persuade Congress to pursue. We examine the measures of presidential legislative success, both when he cannot count on a party majority in Congress and when his party controls both Houses. Even then, he must work hard to get enough members to support him in passing a law, and quickly learns to blame Congress or individual members when his proposals fail.

When the president is not of the same party as Congress, oversight hearings occur with great frequency and at times make headlines that castigate bureaucratic agency heads for inaction or actions that members of the majority party in Congress do not like. But when the president and both Houses are controlled by the same party, oversight hearings are rare, and bureaucrats find that they have fewer opportunities to resist their political leaders. Norms are violated, evidence may be ignored, and there is little recourse short of the courts’ ability to rein in policy changes that offend committed supporters of the last administration’s ideas. We review models of presidential organization, the structure of the White House, presidential capital, public support and popularity trends, agenda setting and successes, and limits upon presidential power.

In chapter 4, “Interest Groups,” we describe the zealous huckstering of that diverse congeries of hired guns, savvy professionals, and former members of Congress and their staffs, who have spun through a revolving door from government to lobbying firms and sometimes back again, niche groups, coalitions, political action committees (PACs), super PACs, and groundswell participants who engage in lobbying, campaign financing, and grassroots organizing to try to keep things off the public agenda or shape them to their liking when they cannot. We define and examine PACs and super PACs, 527 groups, bundling, and other strategies for funneling money to members of Congress. We chase the will-o-the-wisp connection between

money and votes and offer some perspectives for examining how and when interest groups get their money’s worth. We review traditional strategies of gaining access and wielding influence, ranging from grassroots movements, to direct lobbying, to in-kind service, to campaigns and more. We chronicle the growth of social media as a lobbying tool, but question whether it has thus far much changed the way things work.

A theme of the chapter is that interest groups are extremely influential— and in many instances the controlling influence in health care policymaking. Lobbyists have many resources, including detailed knowledge of policies affecting them or their clients, money, organizing skills, and singularity of purpose, and they are only too happy to show a legislator the correct path toward constituent service and comfortable reelection margins. Another theme is that while interest groups have always been one of the key institutions of government, they do not always or even usually act in the public interest.

We examine how interest groups form and stay together, the dominant role of occupational alliances, and the deliberate or inadvertent role of government itself in sometimes spawning such groups. The interest-group world of today is complex and characterized by both permanent and temporary coalitions that share and complement one another’s strengths and resources. Much of the lobbyist’s work has to do with the unglamorous job of monitoring legislation and providing information. We describe the ways in which these groups move through the many venues of government, as well as the strategies they employ in campaign giving and grassroots campaigning to ensure that they will have access after the election.

Chapter 5, “The Bureaucracy,” takes a sympathetic view of public bureaucracy. Both of us have worked for the federal government as well as groups and firms that support federal and state governments and so know well how agencies work and the enormous capabilities and resources that they enjoy. Bureaucracy here is viewed as a repository of expertise, with detail-oriented people who bring the long view to the policy process and stand ready to serve their multiple masters Congress, the president, the courts, their constituents, and the industries they regulate. We also look at the strategies bureaucrats use to increase their own discretion to pursue their

Another random document with no related content on Scribd:

Creswick, Thomas

Critius and Nesiotes

Crivelli, Carlo

Crome, John

Cropsey, J. F.

Crowe, Sir J. A.

Cruikshank, George

Cuyp

Dahl, Hans

Dahl, J. C.

Dahl, Michael

Dallin, Cyrus E.

Dalou, Jules

Damophon

Danby, Francis

Daniell, Thomas

Dannat, William T.

Dannecker, J. H. von

Daubigny, C. F.

Daumier, Honoré

David, Gerard

David, J. L.

David, Pierre Jean

Davis, C. H.

Davis, H. W. B.

De Camp, Joseph

Decamps, A. G.

Degas, H. G. E.

De Haas, M. F. H.

De Keyser, Thomas

Delacroix, F. V. E.

Delaroche, H. (Paul)

Delaunay, Elie

Della Bella, Stefano

Della Colle, Raffaellino

Della Quercia, Jacopo

Della Robbia

De Loutherbourg, P. J.

Demetrius

Desiderio da Settignano

Detaille, J. B. E.

Dewing, T. W.

De Wint, Peter

Diamante, Fra

Diaz, N. V.

Dielmann, Frederick

Diepenbeck, A. van

Dies, C. A.

Dietrich, C. W. E.

Dillens, Julien

Dipoenus and Scyllis

Dobson, William

Dolci, Carlo

Domenichino, Zampieri

Donatello

Doré, L. A. Gustave

Douw, Gerhard

Downman, John

Doyen, G. F.

Doyle, Richard

Drawing

Drouais, J. G.

Dubois, Paul

Du Maurier, G. L. P. B.

Dumont (family)

Dumont, François

Duncan, Thomas

Dupré, Jules

Durand, Asher Brown

Dürer, Albrecht

Duveneck, Frank

Dyce, William

Eakins, Thomas

Earle, Ralph

Earlom, Richard

East, Alfred

Eastlake, Sir C. L.

Eaton, Wyatt

Eckersberg, Kristoffer

Edelinck, Gerard

Eeckhout, G. van den

Effigies, Monumental

Egg, A. L.

Encaustic Painting

Endoeus

Engleheart, George

Engraving

Enneking, J. J.

Etching

Etex, Antoine

Etty, William

Euphranor

Euphronius

Eupompus

Eutychides

Everdingen, Allart van

Eyck, Van

Faed, Thomas

Faithorne, William

Falcone, Aniello

Falconet, E. M.

Falguière, J. A. J.

Fantin-Latour, I. H. T.

Farinato, Paolo

Feltre, Morto da

Fernow, K. L.

Ferrari, Gaudenzio

Ferri, Ciro

Feuerbach, Anselm

Fielding, A. V. Copley

Fildes, Sir Luke

Finden, William

Fiorenzo di Lorenzo

Fiorillo, J. D.

Fisher, Alvan

Flandrin, J. Hippolyte

Flaxman, John

Flinck, Govert

Floris, Frans

Fontana, Lavinia

Fontana, Prospero

Fogelberg, B. E.

Foley, J. H.

Foppa, Vincenzo

Forain, J. L.

Ford, E. Onslow

Forster, François

Fortuny, M. J. M. B.

Foster, M. Birket

Foucquet, Jean

Fragonard, J. H.

Français, F. L.

Franceschi, Piero de’

Franceschini, Baldassare

Francia

Franciabigio

Franck

Francken (family)

Frèmiet, Emmanuel

French, Daniel C.

Frère, P. E.

Fresco

Fresnoy, C. A. du

Frith, W. P.

Fromentin, Eugène

Frost, W. E.

Fruytiers, Philip

Führich, Joseph von

Fuller, George

Furniss, Harry

Furse, C. W.

Fuseli, Henry

Fyt, Johannes

Gaddi (family)

Gainsborough, Thomas

Gallait, Louis

Gauermann, Friedrich

Gaul, G. W.

Gavarni

Gay, Walter

Geddes, Andrew

Geikie, Walter

Genelli, G. B.

Genga, Girolamo

Gentile da Fabriano

Gentileschi, Artemisia and Orazio de’

Gérard, Baron F.

Gérard, J. I. I.

Géricault, J. L. A. T.

Gérôme, Jean Léon

Gervex, Henri

Ghiberti, Lorenzo

Ghirlandajo, Domenico

Ghirlandajo, Ridolfo

Gibson, C. Dana

Gibson, John

Gibson, W. H.

Gifford, R. S.

Gifford, S. R.

Gilbert, Alfred

Gilbert, Sir John

Gillot, Claude

Gillray, James

Giordano, Luca

Giorgione

Giottino

Giotto

Girardon, François

Girodet de Roussy, A. L.

Girtin, Thomas

Giulio Romano

Giunta Pisano

Giusto da Guanto

Gleyre, M. C. G.

Goes, Hugo van der

Goldschmidt, Hermann

Goltzius, Hendrik

Gordon, Sir J. W.

Gouache

Goujon, Jean

Gould, Sir F. C.

Goya y Lucientes, F.

Goyen, J. J. Van

Gozzoli, Benozzo

Grafly, Charles

Granet, F. M.

Grant, Sir Francis

Gray, Henry Peters

Greco, El

Green, Valentine

Greenaway, Kate

Greenough, Horatio

Gregory, Edward John

Greuze, J. B.

Grimaldi, G. F.

Grisaille

Gros, Antoine Jean

Grün, Hans Baldung

Grünewald, Mathias

Guardi, Francesco

Guariento (Guerriero)

Guérin, J. B. P.

Guérin, P. N.

Guido of Siena

Guido Reni

Guillaume, J. B. C. E.

Guthrie, Sir James

Haag, Carl

Haden, Sir F. Seymour

Hals, Frans

Hamerton, P. G.

Hamon, Jean Louis

Harding, Chester

Harding, J. D.

Harpignies, Henri

Harrison, T. A.

Hart, William

Hartley, Jonathan S.

Harvey, Sir George

Hassam, Childe

Haydon, B. R.

Hayter, Sir George

Head, Sir E. W.

Healy, G. P. A.

Heda, Willem Claasz

Heem, Jan Davidsz van

Heemskerk, M. J.

Heim, F. J.

Helst, B. van der

Hemy, C. Napier

Hennequin, P. A.

Henner, J. J.

Henry, E. L.

Herkomer, Sir H. von Herlen, Fritz

Herrera, Francisco

Hersent, Louis

Hess (family)

Heusch, Willem

Heyden, Jan van der Hildebrandt, Eduard

Hildebrandt, Theodor

Hilliard, Lawrence

Hilliard, Nicholas

Hilton, William

Hiroshige

Hitchcock, George

Hobbema, Meyndert

Hoefnagel, Joris

Hogarth, William

Hokusai

Holbein, Hans (elder)

Holbein, Hans (younger)

Holl, Frank

Hollar, Wenzel

Holroyd, Sir Charles

Homer, Winslow

Hondecoeter, M. d’

Hone, Nathaniel

Honthorst, Gerard van

Hooch, Pieter de

Hoogstraten, S. D. van

Hook, James Clarke

Hoppner, John

Horsley, J. C.

Hoskins, John

Hosmer, Harriet G.

Hotho, Heinrich G.

Houbraken, Jacobus

Houdon, J. A.

Hovenden, Thomas

Huchtenburg (family)

Humphry, Ozias

Hunt, Alfred William

Hunt, William Henry

Hunt, William Holman

Hunt, William Morris

Huntington, Daniel

Hurlstone, F. Y.

Huysmans (family)

Huysum, Jan van

Illuminated MSS.

Illustration

Impressionism

Ingham, C. C.

Ingres, J. A. D.

Inman, Henry

Inness, George

Isabey, Jean Baptiste

Israëls, Josef

Ivory

Jackson, Mason

Jameson, George

Janssen, Cornelius

Janssens, V. H.

Janssens van Nuyssen, Abraham

Jarvis, J. W.

Joanes, Vicente

Johnson, Eastman

Jordaens, Jacob

Jouvenet, Jean

Kalckreuth, Leopold von Kauffmann, Angelica

Kaulbach, Wilhelm von

Kay, John

Keene, C. S.

Keller, Albert

Kensett, J. F.

Khnopff, F. E. J. M.

Klinger, Max

Kneller, Sir Godfrey

Knight, D. R.

Knight, John Buxton

Koninck, Philip de Korin, Ogata

Krafft, Adam

Kyosai, Sho-fu

Laer, Pieter van

La Farge, John

Lafosse, Charles de Lagrenée, L. J. F.

Lahire, Laurent de Lambeaux, Jef

Lancret, Nicolas

Landon, C. P.

Landseer, Sir E. H.

Lantara, S. M.

Lanzi, Luigi

Largillière, Nicolas

Lathrop, Francis

La Tour, Quentin de

Lavery, John

Lawrence, Sir Thomas

Lawson, Cecil Gordon

Leader, B. W.

Léandre, C. L.

Lear, Edward

LeBrun, Charles

Leech, John

Legros, Alphonse

Leighton, Baron Frederick

Lejeune, Baron L. F.

Lely, Sir Peter

Lemoyne, J. B.

Le Nain

Lenbach, Franz von Leochares

Leonardo da Vinci

Leopardo, Alessandro

Leslie, C. R.

Le Sueur, Eustache

Leutze, Emanuel

Lewis, J. F.

Leys, Hendrik

Liebermann, Max

Limousin, Léonard

Line Engraving

Linnell, John

Linton, W. J.

Liotard, J. E.

Lippi

Lockwood, Wilton

Lombardo (family)

Longhi, Pietro

Lotto, Lorenzo

Low, Will Hicok

Lucas, J. Seymour

Leyden, Lucas van

Luini, Bernardino

Lysippus

Lysistratus

Mabuse, Jan

MacCulloch, Horatio

Macdonald, Lawrence

McEntee, Jervis

Maclise, Daniel

MacMonnies, F. W.

Macnee, Sir Daniel

MacNeil, Hermon A.

Madou, J. B.

Madrazo y Kunt, Don F. de

Maes, Nicolas

Makart, Hans

Mander, Carel van

Manet, Edouard

Manson, George

Mantegna, Andrea

Marcantonio

Maris, Jacob

Marochetti, Baron Carlo

Marr, Carl

Martin, Homer Dodge

Martin, John

Martini, Simone

Masaccio

Masolino da Panicale

Mason, G. H.

Matsys, Quintin

Mauve, Anton

May, Phil

Mead, Larkin G.

Meer, Jan van der

Meissonier, J. L. E.

Melanthius

Melchers, Gari

Melozzo da Forli

Melville, Arthur

Memling, Hans

Mena, Pedro de

Mengs, Anthony Raphael

Menzel, A. F. E. von Mercié, M. J. A.

Merian, Matthew

Méryon, Charles

Metcalf, W. L.

Metsu, Gabriel

Meulen, A. F. van der

Meunier, Constantin

Mezzotint

Michel, Claude

Michelangelo

Michelozzo di Bartolommeo

Micon

Mierevelt, M. J. van

Mieris (family)

Mignard, Pierre

Mignon, Abraham

Milanesi, Gaetano

Millais, Sir J. E.

Miller, William

Millet, Francis Davis

Millet (Milé), Jean François

Millet, Jean François

Miniature

Mino di Giovanni (da Fiesole)

Minor, Robert C.

Models, Artists’

Monet, Claude

Montañes, J. M.

Moore, Albert J.

Moore, Henry

Mora, José

Moran, Edward

Moran, Thomas

Moreau, Gustave

Morelli, Giovanni

Moretto, Il

Morghen, R. S.

Morland, George

Moro, Antonio

Moroni, Giambattista

Mosler, Henry

Mount, W. S.

Mowbray, H. S.

Müller, W. J.

Mulready, William

Munkacsy, Michael von

Murillo, B. E.

Murphy, John Francis

Murray, David

Muziano, Girolamo

Muzzioli, Giovanni

Myron

Nanteuil, Robert

Nasmyth, Alexander

Nast, Thomas

Nattier, J. M.

Navarrete, J. F.

Neal, D. D.

Neer, van der

Netscher, Gaspar

Neuville, Alphonse M. de Newlyn

Niehaus, C. H.

Nicholson, William

Nicias

Nicomachus

Nollekens, Joseph

Northcote, James

Oberlander, A. A.

Ochtman, Leonard

O’Donovan, W. R.

Oliver, Isaac

Oliver, Peter

Onatas

Opie, John

Orcagna

Orchardson, Sir W. Q.

Orley, Bernard von Ostade

Oudiné, E. A.

Overbeck, J. F.

Pacchia, Girolamo del, and Pacchiarotto, Jacopo

Pacheco, Francisco

Paeonius

Page, William

Painting

Pajou, Augustin

Palette

Palma, Jacopo

Palmer, E. D.

Palmer, Samuel

Palomino, de Castro y Velasco

Pamphilus

Panaenus

Panorama

Pareja, Juan de

Parmigiano

Parrhasius

Partridge, J. Bernard

Partridge, W. O.

Pasiteles

Pastel

Paton, Sir J. Noel

Paul Veronese

Pausias

Peale, C. W.

Peale, Rembrandt

Pearce, C. S.

Pennell, Joseph

Penni, Gianfrancesco

Perino del Vaga

Perkins, C. C.

Perugino, Pietro

Peruzzi, Baldassare

Petitot, Jean

Petitot, Jean Louis

Pettenkofen, A. von

Pettie, John

Pheidias

Phillip, John

Phillips, Thomas

Picknell, W. L.

Piero di Cosimo

Pigalle, J. B.

Piloty, Karl von

Pinturicchio

Pinwell, G. J.

Piranesi, G. B.

Pisano, Andrea

Pisano, Giovanni

Pisano, Niccola

Pisano, Vittore

Pissarro, Camille

Plimer, Andrew

Plimer, Nathaniel

Plumbago Drawings

Pollaiuolo (family)

Polyclitus

Polygnotus

Pontormo, Jacopo da

Poole, Paul Falconer

Pordenone, Il

Portaels, J. F.

Porter, B. C.

Portraiture

Poster

Potter, Paul

Poussin, Nicolas

Powers, Hiram

Poynter, Sir E. J.

Pradier, James

Pradilla, Francisco

Praxias and Androsthenes

Praxiteles

Predella

Preller, Friedrich

Prieur, Pierre

Prinsep, V. C.

Proctor, A. P.

Protogenes

Prout, Samuel

Prud’hon, Pierre

Puget, Pierre

Puvis de Chavannes

Pythagoras

Pyle, Howard

Raeburn, Sir Henry

Raffaellino del Garbo

Raffet, D. A. M.

Raimbach, Abraham

Ramsay, Allan

Ranger, H. W.

Raoux, Jean

Raphael Sanzio

Raven-Hill, Leonard

Rauch, C. D.

Redgrave, Richard

Regnault, Henri

Regnault, J. B.

Reid, Sir George

Reid, Robert

Reinhart, C. S.

Reinhart, J. C.

Relief

Rembrandt

Remington, Frederick

Renoir, F. A.

Repin, I. J.

Restout, Jean

Rethel, Alfred

Reynolds, Sir Joshua

Rhoecus

Ribera, Giuseppe

Ribot, Théodule

Ricard, L. G.

Ricciarelli, Daniele

Richards, W. T.

Richmond, Sir W. B.

Richter, A. L.

Rietschel, E. F. A.

Rigaud, Hyacinthe

Rimmer, William

Riviere, Briton

Robert, Hubert

Robert, L. L.

Robert-Fleury, J. N.

Roberts, David

Robinson, Theodore

Rodin, Auguste

Rogers, John

Roll, A. P.

Romney, George

Rops, Félicien

Rosa, Salvator

Rosenthal, T. E.

Rosselli, Cosimo

Rossellino, Antonio

Rossetti, D. G.

Roubiliac, L. F.

Rousseau, Jacques

Rousseau, P. E. T.

Rowlandson, Thomas

Rubens, Peter Paul

Rude, François

Runciman, Alexander

Russell, John

Ruysdael, Jacob van

Ryder, A. P.

Ryland, W. W.

Sacchi, Andrea

Saint-Gaudens, Augustus

Sambourne, E. Linley

Sandby, Paul

Sandrart, Joachim von

Sandys, Frederick

Sansovino, Andrea C. del Monte

Sansovino, Jacopo

Santerre, J. B.

Sargent, J. S.

Sarrazin, Jacques

Sartain, John

Satterlee, Walter

Sayer, James

Schadow

Schadow, J. G. and R.

Schalcken, Godfried

Scharf, Sir George

Scheemakers, Peter

Scheffer, Ary

Schetky, J. C.

Schiavonetti, Luigi

Schirmer, Friedrich W.

Schirmer, Johann W.

Schlüter, Andreas

Schnorr von Karolsfeld

Schongauer, Martin

Schreyer, Adolf

Schwanthaler, L. M.

Schwartze, Teresa

Schwind, Moritz von Scopas

Scott, David

Scott, William Bell

Sculpture

Sebastiano del Piombo

Seddon, Thomas

Segantini, Giovanni

Sequeira, D. A. de Sergel, Johan Tobias

Severn, Joseph

Shannon, C. H.

Shannon, J. J.

Sharp, William

Shee, Sir M. A.

Sherwin, J. K.

Short, F. J.

Sigalon, Xavier

Signorelli, Luca

Silanion

Simon, Abraham

Simon, Thomas

Simmons, E. E.

Simson, William

Sisley, Alfred

Slodtz, René Michel

Smart, John

Smedley, W. T.

Smillie, J. D.

Smirke, Robert

Smith, Colvin

Smith, John Raphael

Smybert, John

Snyders, Franz

Sodoma, Il

Solario, Antonio

Sorolla y Bastida, J.

Spagna, Lo

Spinello, Aretino

Stanfield, W. C.

Stannard, Joseph

Stark, James

Steen, Jan Havicksz

Steer, P. Wilson

Stevens, Alfred

Stevens, Alfred

Stewart, Julius L.

Stillman, W. J.

Stone, Frank

Stone, Marcus

Stone, Nicholas

Stoss, Veit

Stothard, C. A.

Stothard, Thomas

Strang, William

Strange, Sir Robert

Strongylion

Stuart, Gilbert

Stuck, Franz

Subleyras, Pierre

Sully, Thomas

Swan, J. M.

Taft, Lorado

Tait, A. F.

Tanner, H. O.

Tarbell, Edmund C.

Tempera

Teniers (family)

Tenniel, Sir John

Ter Borch, Gerard

Terra Cotta

Thayer, Abbott H.

Theon of Samos

Thoma, Hans

Thompson, Launt

Thomson, John

Thornhill, Sir James

Thornycroft, W. Hamo

Thorwaldsen, Bertel

Thrasymedes

Tiepolo, G. B.

Tiffany, L. C.

Timanthes

Timomachus

Timotheus

Tintoretto

Tisio, Benvenuto

Tissot, J. J. J.

Titian

Torrigiano, Pietre

Triptych

Troy, J. F. de

Troyon, Constant

Trumbull, John

Tryon, D. W.

Turner, Charles

Turner, J. M. W.

Uhde, F. K. H. Von Utamaro

Vanderlyn, John

Van der Stappen, C.

Van der Weyden, R.

Vandevelde, Adrian

Vandevelde, William

Van Dyck, Sir Anthony

Vanloo, C. A.

Vanloo, J. B.

Varley, Cornelius

Varley, John

Vasari, Giorgio

Vedder, Elihu

Veit, Philipp

Velazquez, D. R. de Silva y Verboeckhoven, E. J.

Vereshchagin, V. V.

Verlat, M. M. C.

Vernet (family)

Verrocchio, Andrea del

Vertue, George

Vien, J. M.

Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.