PierreBachas† ,MatthewFisher-Post‡ ,AndersJensen§ ,GabrielZucman¶
May2024 Abstract
Thispaperbuildsandanalyzesanewglobalmacro-historicaldatabaseofeffective taxratesoncapitalandlaborin154countries.Weestablishanewstylizedfact:while effectivecapitaltaxratesfellindevelopedcountriesbetween1965and2018,theyrose indevelopingcountriessince1990.Multipleresearchdesignsatthecountry,sector andfirm-levelsuggestthattradeopennesscontributedtothisrise,byincreasingthe shareofoutputproducedincorporationsandlargerfirms,whereeffectivecapital taxationishigher.Incontrasttoacommonview,globalizationappearsinmany countriestohavesupportedgovernments’abilitytotaxcapital.
∗Thispaperwaspreviouslycirculatedunderthetitle"GlobalizationandFactorIncomeTaxation."The databasebuiltinthispaperisavailableonlineat http://globaltaxation.world.Additionalmaterialis availableintheonlinesupplementaryappendix: linkhere.Weacknowledgefinancialsupportfromthe WeatherheadCenterforInternationalAffairsatHarvardUniversityandtheWorldBankDevelopment Economics’ResearchSupportBudget.ZucmanacknowledgessupportfromtheStoneFoundation.We areindebtedtoElieGerschel,XabierMoriana,RafaelProença,RoxanneRahnamaandAntonReinicke forexcellentresearchassistance.WethanknumerousseminarparticipantsandinparticularPierreBoyer, DamienCapelle,DenisCogneau,MartinFiszbein,JasonFurman,SimonGalle,PinelopiGoldberg,Gordon Hanson,AmitKhandelwal,DavidLagakos,EtienneLehmann,JulianaLondoño-Vélez,BenjaminMarx, SergeyNigai,MathieuParenti,StevenPennings,NamPham,ThomasPiketty,TristanReed,AriellReshef, BobRijkers,DaniRodrik,NicholasRyan,EmmanuelSaez,NoraStrecker,RomainWacziarg,DanielYiXu andRomanZarateforinsightfulcommentsanddiscussions.Thefindings,interpretations,andconclusions expressedinthispaperarethoseoftheauthorsanddonotrepresenttheviewsoftheWorldBankand itsaffiliatedorganizations,orthoseoftheExecutiveDirectorsoftheWorldBankorthegovernmentsthey represent.
†ESSEC-BusinessSchoolandWorldBankResearch,pbachas@worldbank.org
‡ParisSchoolofEconomics,mfp@psemail.eu
§HarvardKennedySchoolandNBER,anders_jensen@hks.harvard.edu
¶ParisSchoolofEconomics,UCBerkeleyandNBER,zucman@berkeley.edu
CapitalTaxation,Development,andGlobalization:
∗
EvidencefromaMacro-HistoricalDatabase
1Introduction
Howhasglobalizationaffectedtherelativetaxationofcapitalandlabor?Hasituniformly erodedtheamountoftaxespaidbycapitalowners,shiftingtheburdentoworkers? Orhavesomecountriesmanagedtoincreaseeffectivecapitaltaxrates,andifsohow? Answeringthesequestionsiscriticaltobetterunderstandthemacroeconomiceffectsand socialsustainabilityofglobalizationinuncertaintimes (Goldberg&Reed, 2023).
Basedonanewlong-runglobaldatabaseofeffectivetaxratesoncapitalandlabor, wedocumentthatindevelopingcountries,effectivecapitaltaxrateshaveincreasedin thepost-1990eraofhyper-globalization.Consistentlyacrossseveralresearchdesigns,we findthatasignificantshareofthisrisecanbeexplainedbytradeopenness.Byexpanding theshareofeconomicactivityoccurringinthecorporatesector,andwithinthecorporate sectorinlargerfirms,ourresultsshowthattradeimprovestheeffectivecollectionoftaxes, particularlycorporateincometaxes.Globalizationhasalsohadwidelynotednegative effectsoncapitaltaxation,duetointernationaltaxcompetitionthatappliesdownward pressureoncorporatestatutorytaxrates.Wefindthatthepositivetaxcapacityeffectof tradeweuncoverprevailedindevelopingeconomies,causingopennesstoincreaseoverall governmenttaxrevenues(asa%ofGDP).Therevenueconsequencesofglobalization havenotbeensystematicallyinvestigatedindevelopingcountriesduetolimiteddata, andconcernsoverpotentialrevenuelosseshavepersistedasakeyobstacletofurther integrationacrossborders (WorldBank, 2020). Incontrasttoacommonview,ourfindings showthatglobalizationhasnotuniformlyerodedgovernments’abilitytoraiserevenue, andinsteadappearstohavesupportedcapitaltaxationinmanycountries.
Toestablishtheseresults,thispapermakestwocontributions.Thefirstistobuild andanalyzeamacro-historicaldatabaseofeffectivetaxratesoncapital(ETRK )andlabor (ETRL)covering154countries,withoverhalfstartingin1965,until2018.Each ETR dividesalltaxescollectedonthefactorbythenationalincomethataccruestoit;byrelying onactualtaxescollected, ETRscapturethenetpasteffectofalltaxrulesand,importantly fordevelopingcountries,taxevasionandavoidance.Complementarytoexisting ETR seriesthatfocusondevelopedcountries,ourdataprovidesaglobalcoveragebydigitizing andharmonizingthousandsofhistoricalandrecentpublicfinancerecordsindeveloping countries.Theglobaldatabaseallowsustosystematicallycharacterizetheevolutionof effectivetaxratesindevelopingcountriesandcomparetrendsacrossdevelopmentlevels.
Anovelfactemergesfromthisdatabase:theevolutionofcapitaltaxationhasbeen asymmetricacrossdevelopmentlevels.Inhigh-incomecountries,effectivecapitaltax ratesdeclined,fromahighof38-39%inthelate1960sto32-33%inthelate2010s.By
1
contrast,indevelopingcountries,effectivecapitaltaxrateshavebeenonarisingtrend sincethebeginningofthe1990s,albeitstartingfromalowlevel.Effectivecapitaltax ratesrosefrom10%in1989to18%in2018,withmorepronouncedincreasesinlarger economies.Forexample, ETRK rosefrom6%to24%inChina,5%to12%inIndia,and 7%to27%inBrazil.Thepositivetrendincapitaltaxationisdrivenbythecorporatesector: theaverageeffectivecorporatetaxraterosefrom12%in1989to20%in2018.
Thisriseofcapitaltaxationinlow-andmiddle-incomecountrieshadnotbeennoted intheliteraturebefore,duetoalackofdataontheevolutionoftaxationglobally.The findingappearsrobust.Itholds:whenweexcludeChinaandoil-richcountries;with otherapproachestocomputingcapitalandlaborincomeinunincorporatedbusinesses (wherefactorsharesarenotdirectlyobservable);andwithalternativewaysofsplitting personalincometaxrevenuebetweencapitalversuslabor.
Oursecondcontributionistoformulateandtestahypothesisthatshedslightonthe riseofcapitaltaxationindevelopingcountries.Wehypothesizethatopennessexertsa positiveeffectondevelopingcountries’capacitytotax,consistentwithtradeleadingtothe expansionoflargerfirmsrelativetosmallerones (Mrázová&Neary, 2018) andfirm-level effectivetaxationrisingwithsize,duetobetterenforcementandhigherstatutorytaxburdens (Almunia&Lopez-Rodriguez, 2018;Best,Shah,&Waseem, 2021).1 Ourhypothesis ismotivatedbytheobservationthattherisein ETRK coincideswithtradeliberalization. Sincethebeginningofthe1990s,manydevelopingcountriesopenedtheirmarketsand reducedtariffs,leadingtoaboomininternationaltradethatreshapedtheeconomiesof Mexico,India,andChinaamongothers (Goldberg, 2023). Bydisproportionatelybenefitinglargerfirms,tradecanincreasetheshareofeconomicactivityincorporationsand moreformalbusinesses,whereeffectivetaxationofcapital(andlabor)ishigher.
Tomotivatethetaxcapacityhypothesis,Figure 1 showsthattheshareofdomestic outputfromthecorporatesector(profitsandemployeecompensation)hasgrownover timeindevelopingcountries,attheexpenseofmixed-income(incomeofself-employed andunincorporatedbusinesses).Whilethecorporatesectoraccountedfor53%ofdomestic outputin1989,priortothehyper-globalizationera,itgrewto62%by2018;mixedincome fellfrom32%to20%overthesameperiod.Thus,developingcountrieshaveexperienced arelocationofactivityfromahard-to-taxsectortoasectorwithstrongereffectivetaxation.
1Highereffectivetaxationinthecorporatesectorstemsbothfromstrongerenforcementandhigherstatutory taxesthaninthenon-corporatesector.Ournotionoftaxcapacityisthattheseco-determinedforcesjointly leadtohigher ETRK withfirmsize(wheresizeismeasuredasfirmoutput,inourcaserevenue).
2
Weestablishthesecondcontributionintwosteps.First,westudytheimpactoftrade ontaxationindevelopingcountries,withafocuson ETRK andcorporatetaxes.Second, westudymechanismsthatlinktradetotaxation,withafocusonthetaxcapacitychannel.
Weimplementthreeresearchdesignstostudyhowtradeimpactstaxation.First,we estimatethenon-parametricassociationwithinacountryovertimebetween ETR and tradeopenness.Second,weanalyzemajortradeliberalizationeventsthatoccurredin sevenlargedevelopingcountries,includingChina’sWTOaccessionin2001,andcaused sharpreductionsintradebarriers (Brandt,Biesebroeck,Wang,&Zhang, 2017;Goldberg& Pavcnik, 2016). Weusesyntheticcontrolmethodsandpresentevent-studyresults.Third, weextendthetradeinstrumentsfrom Egger,Nigai,andStrecker(2019) tooursample.
Allthreedesignsshowthat,indevelopingcountries,tradeleadstoalargeincreasein ETRK ,andasmallerincreasein ETRL.Theeffectissizable:tradeopennesscanaccount for33%ofthedocumentedrisein ETRK since1989.Althoughstudyingmacroeconomic outcomespresentsidentificationchallenges,theresultsareconsistentacrossresearchdesigns,whichdifferintheiridentifyingassumptions,andarerobusttonumeroussensitivity checks.Acrosstheresearchdesigns,wealsofindthattradeleadstoanincreaseintotal taxrevenues(asa%ofGDP).Reflectingtrade’spositiveimpacton ETRK ,overhalfof thisincreasecomesfromhighercorporateincometaxes(CIT),andasmallersharefrom personalincometaxesandpayroll.Indirecttaxes(combiningtariffrevenuesanddomestic consumptiontaxes)slightlyrise,butthecoefficientisnotsignificant.
Wethenturntoinvestigatemechanisms.IntheIVandliberalizationevent-studies, wefindthattradeincreasestheshareofdomesticoutputproducedinthecorporate sector,relativetotheunincorporatedbusinesssector(mixed-income).2 Thus,outputis expandedinthecorporatesectorwhereenforcementisstrongerandeffectivetaxationis higher (Slemrod&Velayudhan, 2018). Moreover,withinthecorporatesectorwefindthat tradeincreasestheaverageeffectivetaxrateoncapital,suggestingtheexpandedcorporate outputaccruestofirmswhose ETRK increaseswiththeiroutput(ourproxyforfirmsize). Thesetwoeffectsoftradeareconsistentwiththetaxcapacitychannel.Simultaneously,we findthattradereducesthestatutorycorporatetaxrate,consistentwithataxcompetition channelwhereglobalizationpushesgovernmentstoreducethestatutorytaxburdenon capital.Onnet,thepositivetaxcapacityimpactoutweighsthetaxratereductionin developingcountries,causingtradetoincrease ETRK atthecountry-level.
Incontrast,wefindnotaxcapacityeffectoftradeindevelopedcountries,butastronger decreaseinstatutorycorporatetaxrates.Theseresultshelpreconciletheasymmetric evolutionofcapitaltaxationindevelopinganddevelopedcountries.
2Tradeleadstoasharpriseincorporateprofitsandaninsignificantchangeinemployeecompensation.
3
Wesharpenourmechanismanalysisbyconductingafirm-levelinvestigationofthetax capacitychannel.WemergemultipleadministrativedatasetsinRwanda,whichallows ustoobserveeachfirm’sintegrationintointernationaltradeandcorporatetaxpayments. Theintegrationmeasureaccountsforthefirm’sindirectexposuretotradethroughits productionnetwork (Almunia,Hjort,Knebelmann,&Tian, 2023). Rwandaprovidesan interestingsetting:startingfromarelativelylowshareofdomesticoutput,thecorporate sectorhasgrownsignificantlysincethe1990s,intandemwithariseintradeopennessand taxcollection.Usingtheshift-sharedesignof Hummels,Jørgensen,Munch,andXiang (2014)foridentifyingvariation,wefindthattradeintegrationincreasesbothafirm’s ETRK anditssize.Thoughlimitedtoasinglecountry,thesefirm-levelresultsprovidemicroevidencefortrade’spositiveimpacton ETRK ,andsupportthetaxcapacitymechanism wherebytrade’simpactismediatedbyapositivefirmsize-ETRK gradient.
Finally,westudysourcesofheterogeneityinthepro-taximpactoftrade.Duringour sampleperiod,developingcountrieshaveinvestedindomestictaxenforcement,suchas largetaxpayerunits (C.Basri,Felix,Hanna,&Olken, 2019). Wefindthattrade’simpacts onthetaxcapacitymechanismandon ETRK holdintheabsenceoftheseenforcement policiesand,moregenerally,outsideofperiodsofsignificantfiscalpressure (Cagé& Gadenne, 2018). Thus,trade’spro-taximpactappearstobeabroadfeatureoftheglobalizationprocesswhichdoesnothingeongovernments’initialenforcementandrevenue needs.Atthesametime,wefindthatopenness’pro-taximpactdependsonthenature ofthetradeshock,inwaysthatareconsistentwithrecenttheoreticalworkontradeand formalization (Dix-Carneiro,Goldberg,Meghir,&Ulyssea, 2021).
Combiningmultipleempiricalstrategies,ourresultsatthecountry,corporatesector, andfirm-levelconsistentlysuggestthattradeopennessincreases ETRK andcontributedto thenewlydocumentedriseof ETRK indevelopingcountriessincetheearly1990s.Based onanewglobaldatabase,ourfindingsshowthatglobalizationhassupportedeffective capitaltaxationandoverallrevenuecollectioninmanycountriesaroundtheworld.
Section 2 discussesrelatedliterature.Section 3 describesthemethodologyanddata. Section 4 presentsfindingsonthelong-runevolutionof ETR.Section 5 analyzestrade’s impacton ETR andSection 6 investigatesthemechanisms.Section 7 concludes.
2RelatedLiterature
Globalizationandtaxstructure
Ourpapercontributestothemacroliteratureonglobalizationandtaxstructure (Alesina&Wacziarg, 1998), reviewedin Adam,Kammas,and Rodriguez(2013). The“racetothebottom”hypothesispositsthatgovernmentsreduce
4
taxesonfactorsthatbecomemoremobile(e.g.,capital)followingtradeliberalization (Slemrod, 2004). Toachieverevenueneutrality,governmentsraisetaxesonlessmobile factors(e.g.,labor).3 The“socialinsurance”hypothesispostulatesthatgovernmentsraise revenuetoinsureworkersdisplacedbyinternationalcompetition,oftenviasocialsecurity andpayrolltaxes (Rodrik, 1998). Thesestudiesmainlyfocusedonhigh-incomecountries. Byexpandingthescopetodevelopingcountries,weformulateandtestanewmechanism, wheretradeincreases ETR byexpandingactivityinfirmswithhighereffectivetaxcollection.Ourresultssuggestthatglobalizationhassupportedtheabilityofgovernments totaxcapitalinmanycountries.
Ourresultsarebasedonanewglobaldatabaseofeffectivetaxrates,whichcomplementsexistingdatasets (includingCarey&Rabesona, 2004;Kostarakos&Varthalitis, 2020;McDaniel, 2007) byexpandingcoveragetodevelopingcountries(detailsinSection 3).4 Ourbackward-looking ETR measureiscomplementarytotheliteratureonforwardlookingcapitaltaxrates (includingDevereux&Griffith, 1999), whichmodelsindetailthe statutorytaxburdenafirmwouldfaceunderdifferentconditions.Thisliteraturefinds thatthestatutorytaxburdenoncapitalhasfallenindevelopedanddevelopingcountries, consistentwiththe’racetobottom’mechanism (includingDevereux,Griffith,&Klemm, 2002;R.Kumar&James, 2022;Steinmüller,Thunecke,&Wamser, 2019).
Effectivetaxationandtradeindevelopingcountries Ourpapercontributestothemicroorientedliteratureontradeandpublicfinanceindevelopingcountries.Manystudiesfocus on bordertaxes andevasion (e.g.,Fisman&Wei, 2004;Javorcik&Narciso, 2017;Sequeira, 2016)orcross-borderincome-shifting(e.g.,Bilicka, 2019;Londoño-Vélez&Tortarolo, 2022; Wier, 2020). Wefocusinsteadontrade’simpactsonthe domestictaxbases ofcapitaland laboranddomesticeconomicstructure.5 Ourresultsareintuitivewhenconsideringthat thetradeliteraturefindspositiveeffectsofopennessondomesticoutcomesincluding marketshares (McCaig&Pavcnik, 2018), firmsize (Alfaro-Ureña,Manelici,&Vasquez, 2022), andlocaldevelopment (Méndez&VanPatten, 2022), whichthepublicfinance literaturehasseparatelyidentifiedasdeterminantsofeffectivetaxation (Besley&Persson,
3WithinlaborinOECDcountries, Eggeretal.(2019) findthatglobalizationinthepost-1994eraledtoa reductioninincometaxesforthetop1%ofworkersandincreasedincometaxesformiddle-classworkers.
4Wecomplementotherworkineconomichistoryontaxation (includingCogneau,Dupraz,Knebelmann,& Mesplé-Somps, 2021), byprovidinglong-runmeasuresoffactoreffectivetaxrates.
5Thetheoreticalliteraturehasfocusedontrade’simpactontheoptimalindirecttaxmixbetweenborder andconsumptiontaxesindevelopingcountries(e.g.EmranandStiglitz,2005)andmainlyabstractedfrom directtaxes. BenzartiandTazhitdinova(2021) studytheimpactofindirecttaxesontradeflows.
5
2014;Bestetal., 2021).6 Wecontributebylinkingthesetwobodiesofworkanddirectly studyingtrade’simpactsondomestictaxbasesatthecountry,sectorandfirmlevel.
Byincorporatingdomestictaxbases,wecancomprehensivelystudythetotaltaxrevenueimpactsofglobalization.Previousstudiesontrade’srevenueimpactindeveloping countrieshaveproducedmixedfindings,possiblyduetodifferencesinsample,methods andtaxbasefocus (includingBaunsgaard&Keen, 2009;Buettner&Madzharova, 2018; Cagé&Gadenne, 2018). Wecontributebyimplementingmultipleidentificationstrategiesinthelargestsampletodateandfindthattrade’simpactsondomestictaxbasesare sufficientlylargethatopennessincreasestotaltaxrevenue(asa%ofGDP).
Theseimpactsoftradearemediatedbythetaxcapacitymechanism,whichisrooted intwodistinctinsightsfromthetradeandthepublicfinanceliteratures.First,alarge classofmodelspredictsthattradeleadstotheexpansionoflargefirmsrelativetosmall firms (Mrázová&Neary, 2018); forempiricalevidence,see Bernard,Jensen,Redding, andSchott(2007). Second,indevelopingcountriessmallfirmsaremainlyinformal, andeffectivetaxationincreaseswithfirmsize(measuredasfirmrevenue)7;thispositive gradientarisesbecauseeffectivetaxcollectionishigherinlargerfirmsandcorporations duetotheirvisibility,complexproductionstructures,andemploymentofmanyworkers (Almunia,Hjort,etal., 2023;Waseem, 2020). Theresultinginformationtrailsimprove enforcement (Naritomi, 2019;Pomeranz, 2015), thoughwithlimits (Carillo,Pomeranz,& Singhal, 2017).8 Thepositivesize-gradientalsoarisesbecausethetaxcodeindeveloping countriesoftenleadstohigherstatutorytaxburdensforlargerfirmsandcorporations (R. Kumar&James, 2022): Bachas,Brockmeyer,Dom,andSemelet(2023) findapositivesizestatutorytaxgradientamongcorporationsin15countries.Ourmechanismismotivated by AbbasandKlemm(2013), whohypothesizethatthecorporatesectorexpansioncould explainwhythereductioninstatutorycorporatetaxburdensindevelopingcountrieshas notledtoareductioninCITrevenue(%ofGDP).9 Themechanismalsorelatestostudiesin high-incomecountriesthatlinkCITcollectiontothecorporatesector’sstatutoryburden, output-shareandprofitability (Clausing, 2007;Griffith&Miller, 2014;Sørensen, 2007).
Wefocusonamechanismbasedonfirmsize,butmanylinksbetweentrade,firm structure,andtaxationremaintobeexplored (Atkin&Khandelwal, 2020;Parenti, 2018).
6Ourresults,whichfocusonthecorporateoutput-share,arecompatiblewithfindingsfromtradeformalizationstudies,whichinsteadfocusontheshareofformalworkersorfirms(Section 6).
7Seealso KopczukandSlemrod(2006), Kleven,Knudsen,Kreiner,Pedersen,andSaez(2011), LaPortaand Shleifer(2014), Bachas,Fattal,andJensen(2019) and Bestetal.(2021).
8IndevelopedcountriesincludingtheUS,thelargecorporatesectorisconsideredanimportantdeterminant ofeffectivetaxcollection (Kleven,Kreiner,&Saez, 2016;Slemrod&Velayudhan, 2018).
9Seealso Quinn(1997), M.M.S.KumarandQuinn(2012) and Abramovsky,Klemm,andPhillips(2014).
6
3ConstructionofEffectiveTaxRates
Thissectionpresentsanewdatabaseofeffectivetaxrates(ETR)onlaborandcapital, whichcovers154countries,startingin1965whenpossible,until2018.Wefirstoutlinethe conceptualframeworktobuild ETR,thenpresentthedatasources,andfinallydiscuss thesamplecoverage.FurtherdetailsareinAppendix B
3.1Methodology
Effectivetaxrates Wecomputemacroeconomiceffectivetaxratesfollowingthemethodologyof Mendoza,Razin,andTesar(1994). Theeffectivetaxrateonlabor,denoted ETRL, isthetotalamountoftaxeseffectivelycollectedonlabordividedbytotallaborincomein theeconomy;similarlyforcapital,denoted ETRK :
Toconstructthenumerators,eachtypeoftaxrevenueisassignedtolabororcapital:
where λj istheallocationtolaborofeachtype j oftax τj .Typesoftaxes j followtheOECD Revenueclassification.Weallocatetaxesasfollows:(1)corporateincometaxes,wealth taxes,andpropertytaxesareallocatedtocapital;(2)payrolltaxesandsocialsecurity paymentsareallocatedtolabor;(3)personalincometaxes(PIT)areallocatedpartlyto laborandpartlytocapital,inacountry-timespecificmanner(detailsbelow).Indirect taxesareneitherassignedtolabornortocapital(butanalyzeddirectlyinSection 5.3). Table B2 providesadetailedallocationsummary.
Toconstructthedenominators,wedecomposenetdomesticproductasfollows:
Laborincome YL equalscompensationofemployees(CE)plusashare ϕ ofmixedincome (operatingsurplusofprivateunincorporatedenterprises, OSPUE ).Capitalincome YK equalstheremainingshare (1 ϕ) ofmixedincome,pluscorporatefirms’profitsnetof
ETRL = TL YL and ETRK = TK YK (1)
TL = j λj τj and TK = j (1 λj ) τj (2)
Y = YL + YK = CE + ϕ · OSPUE YL +(1 ϕ) · OSPUE + OSCORP + OSHH YK (3)
7
depreciation(operatingsurplusofcorporations, OSCORP ),plusactualandimputedrental income(operatingsurplusofhouseholds, OSHH ).10
Wealsomeasuretheeffectivetaxrateoncorporateprofits, ETRK C ,astheratioof corporateincometaxestocorporateprofits.Thisisanaverageeffectivetaxrateatthe corporatesectorlevel;inSection 6,weanalyzethefirm-levelcorporateeffectivetaxrate.
Thesemacroeconomic ETRsrelyonseveralconventionsandassumptions (seeCarey &Rabesona, 2004). First,asisdoneintheliterature,theydonotfactorineconomic incidenceinthattheeconomiccostoftaxesisnot“shifted”fromonefactorofproduction toanother:alllabortaxesareallocatedtolaborandallcapitaltaxesareallocatedtocapital. Second,thetaxrevenuestreamsneedtobecomparabletotheirmacroeconomictaxbases measuredinnationalaccounts.Thisgeneratestwokeychallengesforour ETRs:(i)inthe numerator,whatshareofpersonalincometaxrevenuestoallocatetocapitalversuslabor; and(ii)inthedenominator,whatshareofmixedincometoallocatetocapitalversuslabor. Weoutlinebelowourbenchmarkassumptions(detaileddiscussionisinAppendix B.2). Allocationofpersonalincometaxes(PIT) Themainempiricaldifficultyinassigning taxestolaborandcapitalconcernstheallocationofPIT.Anaiveprocedureallocates70% ofthePITtolaborand30%tocapital,roughlymatchingthelaborandcapitalshares ofdomesticproduct.Inpractice,however,recentworkhighlightsthatnotalllaborand capitalincomeissubjecttoPIT,sincenotallindividualsarerequiredtofilePIT,and exemptionsapplytosomeincometypes (Jensen, 2022). Exemptionsforcapital(e.g., imputedhousingrents,undistributedprofits)aretypicallylargerthanforlabor(e.g., pensioncontributions).Further,laborandcapitalincomemightnotfacethesametax rate:dual-incometaxsystemstaxlaborincomewithprogressiveratesbutcapitalincome withflatrates.IntheUS, Piketty,Saez,andZucman(2018) usedetailedtaxandnational accountsdatatomeasurethat75%oflaborincomeissubjecttoPIT,versus33%ofcapital income.Thissuggestsallocating15%ofPITtocapitaland85%tolabor.11
Startingfromthisbaselinewhere15%ofPITrevenuesderivefromcapital,weperform twocountry-yearadjustments:(i)weraisecapitalrevenuesforcountry-yearswithahigh PITexemptionthresholdintheincomedistribution (Jensen, 2022); (ii)weloweritin country-yearswheredividendsfacelowertaxesthanwages.Theresultingcapitalshare ofPITrevenuevariesbetween7%and32%acrosscountry-years.Overtime,thissharefalls
10Wedecomposenetdomesticproduct(NDP),whichsubtractsconsumptionoffixedcapitalfromgross domesticproduct(GDP).NDPislowerthanGDP,by10%onaverage.Weexcludecapitaldepreciation sinceitdoesnotaccruetoanyfactorofproductionandisusuallytax-exempt.Factorincomesalsoexclude indirecttaxes(whicharealsoexcludedinthenumeratorof ETR).
11If75%oflaborincomeistaxableandlaborincomeis70%ofnationalincome(resp.33%and30%for capitalincome),then 75% × 70%/(75% × 70%+33% × 30%)=84% ofthePITislaborincome.
8
fromaglobalaverageof19%in1965to14%in2018,duetoareductioninPITexemption thresholdsandincreasedprevalenceofdualtaxsystems.
Intheabsenceofdetailedtaxrecordsineverycountryandyear,theseadjustments provideanimperfectapproximationofthetruecapitalshareofPIT.Wethereforeimplementtwosimplerobustnesscheckswheretheshareallocatedtocapitalisfixedovertime ateither0%or30%,representinglowandhigh-endscenarios.
Thelaborshareofmixedincome Thelaborshareofmixedincome(unincorporated enterprises)ishardtomeasure.12 Forourbenchmarkseriesweassume ϕ =75%,i.e., 25% ofmixedincomeisconsideredcapitalincome.13 Intheabsenceofaconsensusover alternativesthisassumptionhastheadvantageofbeingtransparent,thoughfactorshares areunlikelyinpracticetoeverywherebetimeandcountry-invariant.Wethereforeimplementtworobustnesschecks,whichcreatetimeandyearvariationin ϕ.Thefirstmethod, basedon ILO(2019), usesmicro-datatoestimatethecountry-specificlaborincomeofselfemployedbasedontheobservablecharacteristicsoftheseworkersandtheircomparison withemployees.14 Second,weassignto ϕ theobservedcountry-yearlaborshareofthe corporatesector (asinGollin, 2002).
Theexact ETR formulaswhichincludetheaboveadjustmentsareinAppendix B.2. UsefulnessandlimitationsofETR Sincenationalaccountstatisticsarecompiledfollowingharmonizedguidelines, ETRsareconceptuallycomparableovertimeandacross countries,thoughthedatalimitationsdescribedaboveshouldbekeptinmind.Byrelying ontaxesactuallycollected,the ETRsincorporatetaxavoidanceandevasionbehavioras wellasthenetpasteffectsofalltaxpolicies,includingrates,exemptionsandcredits. Thisisparticularlyrelevantinadevelopmentcontext,whereduetowidespreadevasion, knowledgeofstatutorytaxrulesonlyprovidesapartialpictureofeffectivetaxburdens.
The ETRsarebackward-lookingmeasuresthatcomprehensivelycapturehowmuch capitalandlaborhaveeffectivelypaidintaxes.Theyarehelpfulforthreereasons.First, knowinghowmuchrevenuesareeffectivelycollectedfromeachfactorisimportantwhen governmentsfacefiscalpressure (Besley&Persson, 2014): thisischaracteristicofmost
12TheUN’snationalaccountsframeworkoutlinesthecombinationofmultiplemethodstoovercomechallengesofmeasuringthe level ofmixedincomeineconomieswithwidespreadinformality.Whileinformationonthemethodsusedisnotavailableonacountry-yearbasis,aninspectionofthepublished frameworkssuggestsnochangeinmethodologiesformixedincomeovertime.
13Thisisbelowthe30%usedinDistributionalNationalAccounts(DINA)guidelines (Blanchet,Chancel, Flores,&Morgan,2021),butsincetheglobalaverageofthecorporatesector’scapitalshareis27%,assuming alowercapitalshareforunincorporatedenterprisesseemsreasonable (seeGuerriero, 2019).
14DetailsinAppendix B.2.Achallengewiththismethodisthatitcancreateimplausiblylargeestimatesof thelevelofmixedincomecomparedtotheirvaluesinnationalaccounts.Weimplementanadjustmentto helpwiththislimitation,butforthisreasonwechoosetouse ILO(2019) onlyforrobustness.
9
developingcountries,wherepotentialrevenuelossesorgainsisakeypolicydeterminant. Second,thelevelofthe ETR anditsdeviationfromastatutoryrateisfrequentlyaninput intopolicy-makingtounderstandthesizeoftaxgaps(e.g.therecentfocusonthefirmlevel ETR intheglobalminimumtaxagreements).Finally,thetaxburdenleviedoneach factorisanimportantstartingpointtodeterminetheeconomicincidenceofataxsystem.
Alimitationofmacroeconomic ETRsisthattheyareimpactedbyboththetaxcode andeconomicchanges.Thus,studying ETRsismosthelpfullydoneincombinationwith analyzingitsmechanisms,whichwefocusoninSection 6.Related,weemphasizethat the ETR shouldnotbeinterpretedasaproxyforthestatutorytaxburden.Animportant complementarybodyofworkcarefullymeasureslegaltaxburdens (Devereux&Griffith, 1999), byconstructingforward-lookingaveragetaxratesoncapitalbasedonthesimulated presentvalueofreturnsandcostsofanewinvestment.Drivenbydifferingobjectives,the backward-lookingandforward-lookingmeasuresarerelated,yetdistinct.15
3.2Datasources
3.2.1Nationalaccounts
Tomeasurefactorincomesfor154countriessince1965whenpossible,wecreateapanel ofnationalaccountsusingdatafromtheSystemofNationalAccounts(SNA)producedby theUnitedNations.Wefirstusethe2008SNAonlinerepositorythathasglobalcoverage forrecentdecades.Inturn,theUNStatisticsDivisionprovideduswithaccesstothe1968 SNAofflinedatawhichcovershistoricaldatafromthe1960sand1970s.Tothebestof ourknowledge,ourpaperisthefirsttoharmonizeandintegratethe2008-SNAand1968SNAdatasets.16 Estimatingfactorincomesrequiresinformationonallthecomponentsof nationalincome(equation 3).Wheneverwehavenationalincomeforacountry-yearbut informationonacomponentismissing,weattempttorecoveritwithinformationfrom thesecondSNAdataset,aswellasusingnationalaccountingidentitieswithnon-missing valuesfortheotherincomecomponents.Intheremainingcases,weimputecomponent valuesfollowingDINAguidelines (Blanchetetal., 2021) (detailsinAppendix B.1).
3.2.2Taxrevenue
Weconstructanewtaxrevenuedatasetthatdisaggregatestaxesbytypefollowingthe OECDRevenueStatisticsclassificationoftaxes.Ourdatabaseincludesalltaxes—onper-
15Thisisparticularlythecasefor ETR K C :see supplementaryappendix foradetaileddiscussion.Our measureof ETR K C alsorelatestotheCIT-efficiencymeasureby IMF(2014). Inthe supp.apppendix we findthatCIT-efficiencymeasuredwithourdataintherelevantsamplematcheswellthe IMF(2014) series. 16Relativetorecentwork (includingGuerriero, 2019;Karabarbounis&Neiman, 2014), ourdataexpands coverageinspaceandtime,mainlytodevelopingcountries,andsystematicallyattemptstomeasurefactor incomesfortotaldomesticoutput(vs.onlyforthecorporatesector).
10
sonalandcorporateincome,socialsecurityandpayroll,property,wealthandinheritance, consumptionandinternationaltrade—atalllevelsofgovernment.Weensureasystematic separationofincometaxesintopersonalandcorporateincome.Wecollectnewarchival dataandintegrateitwithexistingdatasources.
Whenavailable,OECDRevenueStatisticsdata(link)isthepreferredsource,asitcovers alltypesoftaxrevenuesandgoesbackto1965forOECDcountries.Itaccountsfor2,875 country-yearobservations(42.3%ofthesample).Itsdrawbackisitslimitedcoverage ofnon-OECDcountries,asitcovers93countriesintotalandonlycoversdeveloping countriesmorerecently.WeadddatafromICTD (link).ICTDincludesmostdeveloping countries,withcoveragethatstartsinthe1980s.ICTDsometimescombinespersonaland corporateincometaxes,andsometimeslackssocialsecurity.ICTDadds1,246countryyearobservations(18.3%ofthesample).
Tocomplementtheseexistingsources,weconductedarchivaldatacollectiontodigitize recordsfromgovernmentbudgetsandnationalstatisticalyearbooks.Thisadds2,011new country-yearobservations.17 Wesupplementedthesearchivalrecordswithcountries’ onlinepublications,andofflinedatafromtheIMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics(19721989).Intotal,thisdatacollectionadds2,678observations(39.4%ofthesample).
Buildingadatasetbasedonnewlydigitizedhistoricalsourcesnecessarilyrequires makinganumberofdecisions.Toincreasethecredibilityofourdata,wefollowfour guidingprinciples.First,weseektobuildlonghistoricaltime-seriesthatoverlapinyears withexistingsources.Weaimtoonlyusetwodatasourcespercountry,butusethe overlappingyearsbetweenmultiplesourcestocorroboratethattheyarecomparablein levelsoftaxrevenueandtypesoftaxesinplace.18 Forthisreason,aswitchindatasource rarelyleadstoasignificantchangeintrend.Second,forthehistoricalperiodswithout overlapwithexistingdata,wecorroboratethelevelsoftaxtoGDPwithacademicand policystudies.Third,wedrawonhistoricalstudiestoverifythatlargechangesinrevenues collectedreflectpolicy,economicorpoliticalchangesratherthandataartifacts.Fourth, weaimtobeconservativeandexcludecountriesintimeperiodswhereconcernsexist aboutdataquality,duetotheeconomicandpoliticalcontext.
Tohelpassessourapproach,the supplementaryappendix providesadditionalmaterial.Weprovideatablewhichoutlines,ineachofthe154countries,themainconsiderationsandourchoicesrelatingtothefourguidingprinciples.Thetableemphasizesthe uncertaintysurroundingspecificcountriesandtimeperiods,andflagsinstanceswhere
17ThearchiveswereaccessedintheGovernmentSectionoftheLamontLibrary(websitelink).
18OECDisthepreferredstartingpointandarchivaldataisinitiallysecondinprioritysinceitoftendisaggregatestaxtypesandgoesbackfarintime,butwerevisethisbasedonthesourcethatbestmatches theOECDdata.The supplementaryappendix summarizesthedatasourcesusedforeachcountry.
11
thedataappearsworthyofinclusionbutshouldbeinterpretedwithcaution(allourmain resultsareunchangedifweexcludetheseinstances).Moreover,weprovidein-depthcountrycase-studieswithdirectlinkstotheinitialarchivalsources;thecase-studiescurrently coverallcountrieswithmorethan15millioninhabitantsbutwillultimatelyexpandto coverall154countries.Weinvitecommentsfromresearcherstohelpimprovetheaccuracy oftheseriesaswecontinuouslyupdatethedata.
3.3Datacoverageofeffectivetaxrates
Thefinal ETR samplecontains6,799country-yearobservationsin154countries(Figure A1).Thenumberofcountriesstartsat78in1965andgrowsto110by1975(dueto independenceorcountrycreation).Thekeyjumpincoverage—from117to148— correspondstotheentryofex-communistcountriesin1994,includingChinawhenit arguablybuiltamoderntaxsystem(Appendix B.1).Thedataiseffectivelycomposedof twoquasi-balancedpanels.Thefirstcovers1965-1993andexcludescommunistregimes, accountingfor85-90%ofworldGDP.Thesecondcovers1994-2018andincludesformer communistcountries,accountingfor97-98%ofworldGDP.Figure A1 showscoverageby developmentlevel.WeusetheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018,classifyinglow andmiddle-incomecountries(LMICs)asdevelopingcountriesandhigh-incomecountries (HICs)asdevelopedcountries.WereferinterchangeablytoLMICsasdevelopingcountries andHICsasdevelopedcountries.Oursamplecontains5,144observationsinLMICsand 1,655observationsinHICs.
Comparisonwithexistingdatasets Ourdatabasecomplementsprevious ETR series byexpandingcoveragetoLMICs.Table B3 summarizesthecoverageofexisting ETR series,whichfocusonHICs (Carey&Rabesona, 2004;Kostarakos&Varthalitis, 2020; McDaniel, 2007;Mendozaetal., 1994). Ourbenchmark ETRsrelyonspecificchoices: Table B3 summarizesthemethodologicaldifferenceswithexisting ETR series,which relatemainlytoallocatingcapitaltobothmixedincomeandPIT.19 Thealternativechoices arecoveredbytherobustnesschecksofSection 3.1,whichareimplementedinSection 4.2.
4StylizedFactsonGlobalTaxationTrends
4.1Evolutionofeffectivetaxratesoncapitalandlabor
Figure 2 documentstheevolutionofeffectivetaxratesoncapitalandlaborfrom1965to 2018.Aggregatesaredollar-weighted,i.e.,theglobaleffectivetaxrateoncapitalequals worldwidecapitaltaxrevenuesdividedbyworldwidecapitalincome.Theseseriescan
19Acomprehensivediscussionofthemethodologicaldifferencesisprovidedinthe supp.appendix.
12
thusbeinterpretedastheaveragetaxrateonadollarofcapitalincomederivedfrom owninganassetrepresentativeoftheworld’scapitalstock.Thetoppanelshowsglobal trendsandthebottompanelsseparateHICsandLMICs.
Globally,effectivetaxratesonlaborandcapitalconvergedbetween1965and2018,due toariseinlabortaxationandadropincapitaltaxation.Theglobal ETRL rosefrom16% inthemid-1960sto25%inthelate2010s,while ETRK fellfrom32%to26%.
Theglobaltrendsmaskheterogeneitybydevelopmentlevels.Whilelabortaxationrose everywhere,thedeclineincapitaltaxationonlyoccurredinHICs:theeffectivecapitaltax ratefellfrom38-39%to32-33%betweenthelate1960sandlate2010s,fueledbyalarge reductionineffectivecorporatetaxrates,whichfellfrom27%to19%.Incontrast,starting fromalowlevel, ETRK increasedinLMICs,withtherisehappeningentirelysincethe beginningofthe1990s. ETRK startedat10%inthemid-1960sandwasatthesamelevel in1989;inbetween,therewasariseanddeclineinthelate1970s,butthistemporary changewasfullydrivenbyresource-richcountries(Figure 4).From10%in1989, ETRK sawasustainedincreaseoverthenexttwodecadeswhichreached18%in2018.Therise incapitaltaxationispartlydrivenbyhighereffectivetaxationinthecorporatesector:the effectivecorporatetaxraterosefrom12%to20%between1989and2018inLMICs.20
4.2Theriseofcapitaltaxationindevelopingcountries
Theseculardeclinein ETRK inHICshasbeendocumentedbefore (Dyreng,Hanlon, Maydew,&Thornock, 2017;Garcia-Bernardo,Janský,&Tørsløv, 2022), buttherisein ETRK inLMICsstartingatthebeginningofthe1990sisnovel.Wethereforeneedto establishthatthisresultisrobusttotheassumptionsweusedtoconstructthe ETR series.
The ETR seriesdependsonfourmainmethodologicaldecisions:(1)howtoassign PITrevenuetocapitalvslabor;(2)howtoallocatemixedincometocapitalvslabor;(3) balancedvs.unbalancedpanel;(4)weightstoaggregatecountries.Ourbenchmarkseries: (1)assignsPITtocapitalvs.laborforeachcountry-yearusingdataonPITexemption thresholdsandthetaxtreatmentofdividendsrelativetowages;(2)allocatesafixed25% ofmixedincometocapital;(3)consistsoftwoquasi-balancedpanelsbeforeandafter1994 (whenChina,Russiaandotherformercommandeconomiesenterthesample);and(4) weighscountriesbytheirshareofworldwidefactorincomeineachyear.Weassesshow resultschangewhenvaryingone,several,orallofthesechoicesatthesametime.
20Figure A2 showsthatbothcorporatetaxrevenuesandcorporateprofitsincreasedsince1989buttheformer outpacedthelatter,causing ETR K C torise.Corporateprofitsandtaxrevenuearethelargestcomponents thatdeterminechangesin ETRK .Smallercontributionsto ETRK ’srisecomefromthedeclineinmixedincome,andthesteadyincreaseinpropertyandwealthtaxes,whichoutpacedincomefromrents,albeit startingfromaverylowlevel(0.3%ofNDPin1989).
13
Figure 3 investigatestherobustnessofthe ETRK trendinLMICs.21 Panel(a)varies theallocationofpersonalincometax(PIT)revenue.Ourbenchmarkfollowsadata-driven country-yearassignment;insteadweconsidertwosimplerscenarioswheretheshare allocatedtocapitalisfixed,ateither0%or30%(lowandhigh-endscenarios).Dueto highPITexemptionthresholdsinLMICs,thebenchmarkcountry-specificassignmentis closerinlevelstothe30%thantothe0%scenario.Thoughthecapitalshareallocatedto PITslightlychangesovertime(Section 3.1),thetime-invariantrobustnessseriestrackthe trendsinthebenchmarkseriesclosely.ThisisbecausethePITremainslimitedinLMICs, suchthatitssplitintolaborversuscapitalisofminorconsequence.
Panel(b)variestheassignmentoffactorsharesinmixedincome.Weimplementtwo robustnesschecks,creatingmixedincomelaborsharesthatvaryatthecountry-levelbased onthe ILO(2019) method,andatthecountry-yearlevelbasedontheobservedcorporate laborshare.Bothalternativeseriesareverysimilartothebenchmark.
Panel(c)quantifiestheeffectofcountryentryintothepanel.Inourbenchmark, China,Russia,andotherformercommandeconomiesenterin1994.Inthisrobustness, webalancethepanelbyimputingmissingobservationsbetween1965and1993;weuse theobserved ETRK valueforthatcountryin1994andthetrendsin ETRK observedfor otherLMICsin1965-1993.Theimputationraises ETRK between1965and1993,because Russiahadbothahigh ETRK andahighweightwhenenteringthesamplein1994.
Panel(d)aggregatescountriesusingnetdomesticproduct(NDP),insteadofcapital incomeweights.TheNDPweightsareeithertime-varyingorfixedin2010.These alternativeweightingproceduressuggestaslightlyhigherincreasein ETRK overtime.
Finally,panel(e)plotsall54combinationsofthefourmethodologicalchoices.Therise in ETRK inLMICsbetween1989and2018isclearlyapparentineachofthe54series.How wideistherangeofincreasesandhowdoesourbenchmarkseriescompare?Computing the1989-2018changeinthe54series,weobtainafairlytightrangeof ETRK increases, between6.4pptand10.3ppt.Ourbenchmarkisat8.7ppt,whichisclosetothemean increaseof9.2ppt;therearelargerincreasesthanourbenchmarkin43seriesandsmaller increasesin10.22 Ourbenchmarkseriescorrespondstoan87%increaseintheeffectivetax rateoncapitalinLMICssince1989,reflectingboththestronggrowthandlowbaseline.
Comparisonwithpreviousstudies Pre-existing ETR seriesmainlycoverHICs,which limitsthecomparisontooursample.InHICs,ourbenchmark ETR trendsarecomparable
21Therobustnessfor ETRL inLMICs,and ETRL and ETRK inHICsareshowninthe supp.appendix
22Setting1989asthebaseyearispartlyarbitrary,butitallowsustofixastartinglevelfor ETRsimmediately beforetheperiodofstrongtradeliberalizationinLMICs.Ifweinsteadcomputethechangein ETRK between2018andthelowestpointinagivenseries,therangeofchangesis6.8-11.3pptacrossthe54series, withameanat9.6pptandourbenchmarkat9.4ppt.
14
topreviousstudies,butthelevelsdifferby16.5%onaverage(Figure B1).Thisdifference isprimarilyduetomethodologicalassumptionsabouttheallocationofcapitaltomixed incomeandPIT(Table B3).However,thealternativemethodologiesfromthepre-existing seriesarecontainedwithintherangeof ETR trendsproducedbyourrobustnesschecks. InHICs,thatrangeof ETRK trendsisindeedwide(duetothequantitativeimportance ofthePIT; ETR seriesin supp.appendix).However,therangeof ETRK trendsin LMICsiscomparativelytighter(Figure 3);thisisbecausetherisein ETRK inLMICsis primarilydrivenbythecorporatesector(Figure A2),whichisnotstronglyaffectedbythe methodologicaldifferencesbetweenourstudyandpre-existingstudies.
4.3Wherehascapitaltaxationrisen?
Figure 4 showsthe ETRK seriesforsubsamplesofcountries.Panel(a)plots ETRK series forthemostpopulousLMICs:Brazil,China,IndiaandIndonesia.Alldisplayamarked ETRK riseovertime.Startingin1989(1994forChina)until2018, ETRK rosefrom7%to 27%inBrazil,6%to24%inChina,5%to12%inIndia,and9%to15%inIndonesia.
China’sweightandfast-risingcapitaltaxationimplythatitplaysakeyroleinthe aggregate ETRK trendinLMICs.Panel(b)showsthat,whenexcludingChina,therisein ETRK ishalfaslarge(from10%to15%)andamoresignificantpartoftheriseoccurred earlierinthe1990s.Panel(c)showsthatoil-richcountries,measuredasderivingmore than7%ofGDPinoilin2018,havebeenonacompletelydistinctpath.Reflectingtheoil commodityshocks,their ETRK roseinthe1970sbutfellinthe1980s,andhavestayed flatsince.Excludingoil-richcountriesyieldsamorepronounced ETRK rise,from9%in 1989to21%in2018,andaflat ETRK seriesfrom1965to1989.IfweexcludebothChina andoil-richcountries,weobservearisein ETRK from9%in1989to17%in2018,which issimilarinmagnitudetothebenchmarkseries.
Panel(d)revealsthat,amongnon-oil-richcountries,the ETRK riseisstrongerinlarge LMICs,definedasthe19countrieswithapopulationabove40millionin2018.Even whenexcludingChina,the ETRK oftheother18mostpopulatedcountriesrosefrom9% to18%between1989and2018;insmallercountries, ETRK rosefrom10to14%overthe sameperiod.The ETRK hasrisenbymorethan5percentagepointsin13ofthe19largest LMICssince1989,andhasonlyfalleninonecountry(Russia).23
Inshort,theriseineffectivecapitaltaxesismorepronouncedinlargercountries, includingChina,butisageneralpatternindevelopingcountries,exceptforoil-richones.
23The supplementaryappendix showstheindividualcountries’ ETRK and ETRL timeseries.
15
4.4Suggestiveevidencefortheroleofglobalization
Wesawthat ETRK fellinHICsbutroseinLMICs.Importantly,theriseinLMICsstarts intheearly1990s,whichcoincideswiththeonsetofthe"hyper-globalization"period thatcouldapriorihavemadecapitalmoremobileandhardertotax.24 Instead,could tradeglobalizationhavecaused ETRK toriseinLMICs?Herewetakeafirstpassat investigatingthisquestion.Wecreate5-yeargrowthrateswithincountriesintradeand ETRs.Weplotbinnedscattersof ETR againsttradeopenness(measuredastheshareof importsandexportsinNDP),afterresidualizingallvariablesagainstyearfixedeffects.
Figure 5 depictsthesewithin-countryassociations,whichconditiononglobaltimetrends. Mirroringtheheterogeneityinlong-runtrends,weobservedifferencesbydevelopment levelintheassociationbetweentradeand ETRK :opennessisassociatedwithincreases in ETRK inLMICs,butwithdecreasesin ETRK inHICs.25 Insum,fromaglobaland historicalperspective,thecorrelationalevidencesuggeststhattrademayhavecontributed tothenewlydocumentedrisein ETRK indevelopingcountries.
Naturally,LMICshaveundergonesignificantdevelopmentsincethe1960sandthis growthislikelytoalsohavecontributedtothelong-runrisein ETRK .Inthe supplementaryappendix,wefindthattheassociationsinFigure 5 holdinLMICswhencontrolling forGDPpercapitagrowth.Thiscorrelationalevidence,combinedwiththeobservation thatwhileglobalizationisamajorprocessinLMICs,itsrevenueimpactsarestillnotestablished(Section 1),motivateustoinvestigatetradeasadeterminantof ETR andstudy itsmechanisms.
5TradeGlobalizationandCapitalTaxation
Inthissection,weimplementtwodistinctresearchdesignstoinvestigatetheimpactof tradeopennessoncapitalandlabortaxationindevelopingcountries.
5.1Event-studiesfortradeliberalization
5.1.1Empiricaldesign
Inthefirstdesign,weimplementeventstudiesoftradeliberalizationpolicyeventsin keydevelopingcountries.Todiscernsharpbreaksfromtrendsinouroutcomes,our selectioncriteriawastoselecteventsthatcausedlargetradebarrierreductionsandwhich
24IndividualtrendsinthefourlargestLMICs(Figure 4)alsosuggestanassociationbetweenliberalization episodesandanuptickin ETRK (Brazilin1988;Chinain2001;Indiain1991;Indonesiainthemid-1980s).
25The supplementaryappendix furthershowsthatearlyglobalizedLMICssawtradeand ETRK risein tandempriortothe1990sandstagnatethereafter.Bycontrast,LMICswhichparticipatedinthesecond waveofglobalizationpost-1990sawariseintradeand ETRK inthe1990-2018period.
16
havebeenstudiedintheliterature.Thisledustoselectthesixeventsfromthereview papersby GoldbergandPavcnik(2007, 2016) (Colombiain1985,Mexicoin1985,Brazilin 1988,Argentinain1989,Indiain1991,Vietnamin2001),andaddthewell-knownevent ofChina’saccessiontoWTOin2001 (Brandtetal., 2017). Theseliberalizationevents ledtolargereductionsintariffs:from59%to15%inBrazil;80%to39%inIndia;and, 48%to20%inChina.Wecanrelyonpre-existingnarrativeanalysestodiscussthreatsto identificationandinterpretationofresults.26 Appendix C.1 providesmoredetailsonour selectioncriteriaandtheliberalizationevents.
Foreachoftheseventreatedcountriesandoutcomes,weconstructasyntheticcontrol country,asaweightedaverageoverthedonorpoolofnever-treatedcountries(Abadie, Diamond&Hainmueller,2010).27 Wematchonthelevelofeachoutcomeinthe10years priortotheevent,whileminimizingthemeansquaredpredictionerrorbetweentheeventcountryandthesyntheticcontrol.28 Weplottheaveragelevelsoftheoutcomefortreated andsyntheticcontrolcountriesbyrelativetimetotheevent.Moreover,weestimatethe event-studymodelin10yearsbothbeforeandaftertheevents:
whereweincludefixedeffectsforevent-time, θt,country κc,andcalendaryear, πYear(t) (thelattercontrolforshocksthatcorrelatewitheventsclusteredincalendartime). Dc is adummyequaltooneifcountry c istreated.Thecoefficient βe capturesthedifference betweentreatedandsyntheticcontrolcountriesineventtime e,relativetothepre-reform year e = 1 (omittedperiod).Sinceinferencebasedonsmallsamplesischallenging,we plot95%confidenceboundsusingthewildbootstrap,clusteredatthecountryeventlevel. InTable A1 weestimatethesimpledifference-in-differences,whichcapturestheaverage treatmenteffectinthe10yearspost-liberalization,andtheimputedtreatmenteffectbased on Borusyak,Jaravel,andSpiess(2021), whichaddresseschallengesfromtwo-wayfixed effectsandheterogeneousevent-times.
5.1.2Event-studyresults
Figure 6 displaystheeventstudiesinlevels(left-handpanels)andthedynamicregression coefficients(right-handpanels).Thetoppanelsshowthat,asexpected,tradeopenness
26Thereductionsintradebarriersaresometimesimplementedoverseveralyears.Tobeconservative,we focusontheearlieststartyearforeacheventasdefinedinpublishedstudies.
27Foreachcountry-event,wecanincludeeventually-treatedcountriesinthedonor-pool(excludingthose withtreatmentwithin5yearsoftheevent);theresults,availableuponrequest,aresimilar.
28The supp.appendix liststhecountriesincludedinthesyntheticcontrolforeacheventandeachoutcome.
yct = 10 e= 10,e= 1 βe 1(e = t)t Dc + θt + κc + πYear(t) + ϵct (4)
17
risesintheyearspost-eventby10percentagepoints,anditstrendchangesinpost-reform yearscomparedtopre-liberalizationyears.29 Themiddlepanelsshowthat ETRK followed stablepre-trendsandsharplyrisespost-liberalization,by4to5percentagepoints.The bottompanelsshow ETRL alsorose,butonlyby2percentagepoints.Despitethesmall samplesize,thedynamicpost-treatmentcoefficientsforeachperiodareoftensignificant atthe5%level.Thep-valuesforthejointsignificanceofallpost-reformdummiesare wellbelow5%.Table A1,PanelA,reportstheDiDresults,whicharemarginallymore significantwhenestimatedfromimputedtreatmenteffects.PanelBshowsthatresultsare comparablewhenwejointlymatchonalloutcomesforeachcountry-event.
Theidentifyingassumptionisthattherearenochangesinconfoundingdeterminants of ETR thatcoincidewiththeliberalizationevents.Thebreaksfromstablepre-trends implythatconfoundingchangeswouldhavetosharplycoincidewiththeeventonset. Narrativeanalysesofthetimingforeachevent(Appendix C.1)donotsuggestobvious concurrentchanges.Moreover,usingdatafrom WacziargandWallack(2004), weverify thatothercross-borderreforms(e.g.capitalliberalization)ordomesticreforms(e.g.privatization)donotoccurinthesameyearasthetradeevents.30 However,reformssometimes occurafewyearsafter:forexample,MexicojoinedNAFTAandremovedcapitalinflow restrictions,ArgentinaandBraziljoinedMERCOSUR,andIndialiberalizeditsFDIrules (Appendix C.1).Thesereformsoccurredseveralyearspost-tradeliberalization,but ETRs sharplyriseintheimmediatepost-eventyears.Thisdiscussionhighlightsthatthecausal interpretationoftrade-centeredmacroeconomicreformsrequirescaution.Aplausible interpretationisthattheshort-runrisein ETRswithsharpbreaksfromstablepre-trends reflectstheimpactoftradereforms,butthatthemedium-runcoefficientsalsoreflectthe impactsofadditional,mainlycross-border,reforms.
Ourresultsarebasedona(small)sampleofliberalizationeventsthatsatisfiedspecific criteria.InAppendix C.3,westudytherobustnesstousingverydifferentselection criteriafortradeliberalization.Specifically,were-estimatetheevent-studyusingthe68 liberalizationeventsinLMICsfrom WacziargandWelch(2008). Wefindverysimilar impactsoftradeon ETR usingthisalternativeandexpandedsetofliberalizationevents.
Wefurtherprobetheidentificationandrobustnessofourresults.First,giventhe limitednumberofliberalizationevents,weinvestigateiftheaverageeffectsareinfluenced byoneparticularevent.Removingonetreatedcountryatatime,wefindthedynamic treatmenteffectsforallsubsetsofeventsaresimilartothefullsample(supp.appendix).
29Theabsenceofapre-reformdiplimitsconcernsaboutinter-temporalsubstitution,althoughsomeofthe liberalizationeventsmayhavebeenpredictable,includingChina’sWTOaccession.
30OnlyMexicohadaconcurrentdomesticreform,andresultsholdwithoutit:see supp.appendix.
18
Second,Table A1 addressesconcernsrelatedtothecontrolgroup.Wefindsimilarresults whenweremovefromthedonorpooleachliberalizingcountry’s5majorexportand importtradingpartners(measuredintheimmediatepre-eventyears),alleviatingconcerns ofspilloverstocountriesinthecontrolgroup.31 Resultsarealsocomparablewhenthe donorpoolexcludescountriesthathavealreadyliberalized (basedonWacziarg&Welch, 2008), toguardagainsttheconcernthatthetrendsinthesyntheticcontrolgroupreflect thelonger-runeffectsofthetreatment(liberalization).Finally,tolessentheconcernthat treatedandcontrolcountriesexperiencedifferentunobservableshocks,wefindsimilar resultswhenthedonorpoolforeachtreatedcountryisrestrictedtothesameregion(or toLMICsonly).
5.2Regressionswithinstrumentalvariablesfortrade
5.2.1Empiricaldesign
Ourseconddesignemploysinstrumentalvariablesfortrade.Oneattractivefeatureis thattheIVprovidescausalestimatesunderdifferentidentifyingassumptionsthanthe event-study.Weestimatethefollowingmodelindevelopingcountries:
where yct isthe ETR (oranotheroutcome)incountry c inyear t, tradect istheshareof importsandexportsinNDP,and πc and πt arecountryandyearfixedeffects.32 Wecluster ϵct atthecountrylevel. Xct containsconfoundingdeterminantsof ETR:theexchange rate,grosscapitalformation,logofpopulation,andcapitalopenness (Chinn&Ito,2006 Rodrik, 1998). ETR timeseriesaresometimesvolatile(Figure 4),sowewinsorize ETR atthe5%-95%levelbyyearseparatelyforLMICsandHICs.
OLSestimationofequation(5)maybebiasedduetoreversecausalityandunobservable confoundingfactorsthatcorrelatewithtrade.Totrytoaddresstheseissues,weusethe twoinstrumentsfortradefrom Eggeretal.(2019). Thefirstinstrument,denoted Zgravity , reliesonthestructureofgeneralequilibriummodelsoftrade.Underthestandardgravity modelassumptions,itusestheaveragebilateraltradefrictionsbetweenexportingand importingcountriesasvariation(aggregatedtothecountry-yearlevel).Thisinstrument
31Wealsoverifythatnoneofthemaincountriesinthesyntheticcontrol(supp.appendix)hadexternalor domesticreformsintheevent-yearorinthepost-eventperiods (usingthedatainWacziarg&Wallack, 2004). Consistentwiththis,thelevelsoftheoutcomesinthesyntheticcontrolarerelativelystable throughouttheeventperiods.Finally,notethatifthespilloverscorrespondtocoordinationofpolicies, thiswouldlikelybiasourestimationtowardsfindingnulleffects.
32Weincludefixedeffectsforimputedandinterpolatedvalues,aswellasforeachtaxandnationalaccount datasource(Section 3.2),toensureresultsarenotdrivenbychangestodataquality.Resultsalsohold withoutimputedvaluesandwithineachdatasource(Table A3).
yct = µ · tradect +Θ · Xct + πc + πt + ϵct (5)
19
isvalidifthedistribution(notthelevel)oftradecostsamongindividualcountry-trading pairsisnotinfluencedby ETRsintheimportorexportcountry.Thesecondinstrument, denoted Zoil distance,interactstime-seriesvariationinglobaloilpriceswithacountryspecificmeasureofaccesstointernationalmarkets.Accessiscapturedbythevariance ofdistancetotheclosestmaritimeportforthethreemostpopulatedcities.Thistimeinvariantmeasurecapturestheinternalgeographyofacountryandimpactstransportation costs:followingaglobalshocktooilprices,transportationcostswillbehigherincountries withlessconcentratedaccesstoports,leadingtoalargerdropinimportsandexports. Thisinstrumentisvalidiftheinteractionbetweenglobaloilpricesandcountry-specific measuresofspatialconcentrationisuncorrelatedwithchangesin ETRs.Conceptually, bothinstrumentscapturevariationintradecostsdrivenbyeconomicforcesthatare plausiblyexogenousto ETRsandtheirdeterminants(detailsin supp.appendix).
InLMICs,the 1st-stageisstrongerinthe2000sandathigherincomelevelsfor Zoil,and inearlierperiodsandatlowerincomelevelsfor Zgravity (supp.appendix).Restrictingthe analysistosub-sampleswhereoneoftheinstrumentshasastrongfirst-stageintroduces bias(Mogstad,Torgovistky,&Walters,2021).Instead,wecombinethetwoinstruments toestimatealocalaveragetreatmenteffectthatisrepresentativeofLMICsacrossincome levelsandtimeperiods.Table A2 showsthe 1st-stage.33
5.2.2Instrumentalvariableresults
Table 1 presentstheresultsinLMICsfor ETRK inPanelA,and ETRL inPanelB.34 In column(1),theOLSuncoverspositive,significantassociationsbetweentradeandboth ETRs.Incolumn(2),weemploythetwoinstruments.The 1st-stageKleibergen-Paap F-statisticis24.59.TheIVshowsthattradecausesanincreaseinbotheffectivetaxrates, andthecoefficientfor ETRK (0.151)isthreetimeslargerthanfor ETRL (0.047).These magnitudesareeconomicallymeaningful:movingfromthe 25th tothe 75th percentileof tradeopennessinLMICswouldcausea8.9percentagepointsincreasein ETRK .
TheremainingcolumnsofTable 1 presentthreesetsofrobustnesschecks.Inthefirst set(Columns3to7),wemodifythespecification.Themostnotabledifferenceisthat thecoefficienton ETRK increases(to0.211)whenweweightheregressionusingNDP (Column4),puttingthusmoreweightonthevariationinlargerdevelopingcountries. Theresultshardlychangewhenwe:usenon-winsorized ETRs(Column3);include
33Table D1 showstheinstrumentsimpactimportsandexports,andtradeinintermediategoods-services (G-S)andfinalG-S.Thus,ourIV-estimatescomprehensivelyreflecttheimpactsoftradethroughrisesand fallsinfinalandintermediategoodsandservicesthatflowbothinandoutofthecountry.
34Relativeto ETR coverage,thesamplesizedropsby4.5%duetodata-availabilityofinstruments.
20
controls(Column5);35 allowoil-richcountriestobeonaseparatenon-parametrictime path(Column6),whichaddressestheconcernthattheidentifyingvariationfor Zoil dist iscorrelatedwithtrendsin ETRsspecifictooil-richcountries(Figure 4);winsorizetrade openness(Column7).
Inthesecondsetofrobustnesschecks,weimplementthealternativecapitalandlabor assignmentstoPITandmixed-income,describedinSection 4.2.Inourbenchmark,the capitalshareofmixedincomeistime-invariant,yettrademaycausefactorsharesto change.Incolumns(8)-(9),weallowfactorsharestorespondtotradebyimplementing thetwomethodswhichcreatecountry-yearvaryingcapital-sharesofmixedincome:the resultsarecomparable.TheyalsoremainsimilarwhenwefixthecapitalshareofPITat 0%(column10)orat30%(column11)inallcountriesovertime.Inthethirdrobustnessset (columns12-13),weestimateIVsusingeachinstrumentseparately.The 1st-stageF-statistic is45.13for Zgravity and10.75for Zoil.TheIVestimatesarecomparable,thoughlargerwhen basedon Zoil.Leveragingtheoppositesigneffectsofthetwoinstrumentsontrade,the reducedformresults(Table A2)suggestthatopennesseffectsaresymmetric:increased tradeincreasesboth ETRL and ETRK ,whilereducedtradedecreasesboth ETRs.
Finally,ourresultsarebasedonanunbalancedpanelcombiningseveraldatasources (Section 3.2- 3.3).Table A3 showsthattheresultsarequalitativelysimilarwithineach data-sourcefortaxes(newlydigitizedgovernmentrecords;OECD;ICTD)andnational accounts(SNA1968;SNA2008),aswellasinbothquasi-balancedpanels(preandpost1994)andinastronglybalancedpanel(1965-2018).36
Quantifyingtheroleoftrade Howmuchofthe ETRK riseinLMICssince1989canbe accountedforbyrisingtrade?Between1989and2018,theweighted ETRK inLMICsrose by8.7ppt(Section 4.2)andtradeopennessby13.6ppt.TheNDP-weightedIVfortrade’s impact(col.4ofTable1)isarguablythemostcomparable,sincethe ETRK trendsinSection 4 arealsoweighted.Usingthisestimatewouldimplythattradeopennessaccountsfor 33%oftherisein ETRK (0.211 ∗ 0.136/0.087=0.329).ConsideringallestimatesinTable 1 generatesarangeof21-42%.37
5.3Impactsoftradeopennessontotaltaxrevenues
Wefindpositiveeffectsoftradeoncapitalandlabortaxation,buthowdoestradeimpact overall taxrevenues,includingindirecttaxes?Thisisarelevantquestion,astrade-induced taxlossesfromliberalizationremainanimportantconcernforpolicymakers(Hallaert,
35ResultsalsoholdwhencontrollingforGDPpercapita(notshown).
36Variationbetweencoefficientsmayreflectdataqualityor 1st-stageandtreatmentheterogeneity.
37Forreasonsdiscussedin 5.1.2,wedonotusetheevent-studyestimatesforthisexercise.
21
2010;WorldBank,2020).Table 2 presentstheOLSandtheIVestimationoftheeffectof tradeontotaltaxes(%ofNDP),inLMICs,aswellasonindividualtaxrevenuestreams. Totaltaxesincludedirecttaxesoncapitalandlabor,aswellasindirecttaxes(sumoftaxes ontradeanddomesticconsumption).38
ThetradecoefficientfortotaltaxcollectionispositiveandsignificantinboththeOLS andtheIV.TheIVcoefficient(0.101)iseconomicallylarge:movingfromthe 25th tothe 75th percentileofopennessinLMICswouldcausea5.9pptincreaseintotaltaxes(the unweightedaveragetax/NDPratioinLMICsis17.6%).Thisresultismainlydrivenby highercorporateincometaxes,whichaccountforjustoverhalfoftheincreaseintotal taxes,andtoalesserextentbysocialsecurityandpersonalincometaxes.39 Tradehasa positive,butstatisticallyinsignificant,effectonindirecttaxes.
Trade’simpactontotaltaxesisrobusttousingNDP-weights;includingcontrols; winsorizingtrade;andusingeachinstrumentseparately(Table A4).
WecanalsostudytheimpactofthetradeliberalizationeventsfromSection 5.1 ontotal taxrevenue.Usingtheevent-studymethodology,Figure A3 showsthatthetradeevents ledtoanincreaseinoveralltaxcollection,withabreakfromthestablepre-trend.
Onelimitationisthatwedonotseparatelystudytrade’simpactontariffrevenues versusdomesticconsumptiontaxes,asourdatadoesnotcontainasystematicbreakdown betweenthesetwoindirecttaxes.Thisreflectsourinitialfocusondirectcapitalandlabor taxes,butadditionaldataworkwouldpermitaseparationoftheseindirecttaxes.
40
BoththeeventstudyandtheIVindicatethattradeleadstohigheroveralltaxationin LMICs.Thisfindingrelatestotheliteratureonthenetimpactofopennessontaxrevenues, whichfindsmixedresultsduetodifferencesinsample,empiricalstrategyanddefinitionof openness(Section 2);41 moreover,someofthesestudiesfocusonthenetimpactoftradeon indirecttaxesandabstractfromdirectdomestictaxes.Wecontributebycomprehensively studyingthetotaltaximpactofopenness,basedonimplementingseveralidentification strategiesinthelargestsampleofdevelopingcountriestodate.
6Mechanisms
Thissectioninvestigatesmechanismsfortrade’simpactontaxes,especially ETRK
38Long-runtrendsintaxationbytypeanddevelopmentlevelareinthe supplementaryappendix
39CITgrewsignificantly,asashareofNDP,between1989and2018:seeFigure A2
40Whilethesignofopenness’impactontariffrevenuecouldinprincipledifferdependingonwhetherthe reductionintradecostsisinitiallyduetoeconomicforces(asintheIV)orpolicychanges(asintheevent study),wefindpositiveimpactsinbothcasesondomesticcapitalandlabortaxes,andontotaltaxes.
41Animportantstudyinthisliterature, BaunsgaardandKeen(2009) writesintheconclusion:"itispossible thatindirecteffectsoperatingthroughhigherlevelsofopennessandincomeconsequentupontradereform havemorethanoffsetthedirectlossofrevenueidentifiedhere."
22
6.1Outliningthetaxcapacitymechanism
The taxcapacity mechanismcombinestwodistinctinsightsfromthetradeandpublic financeliterature(Section 2):first,tradeexpandsactivityincorporatestructuresand largerfirmsrelativetosmallerbusinessesandself-employment;second,effectivetaxation increaseswithfirmsize.Tofixideas,considerthefollowingdecompositionof ETRK :
Thisdecompositionshowsthattheeffectivetaxrateoncapital ETRK iscomposedof twoparts.42 Thefirstpartcapturescapitaltaxationwithinthecorporatesector.Itisthe productofthecorporatesector’sshareofNDP, µK C ,andtheaverageeffectivetaxrate oncapitalinthecorporatesector, ETRK C .Theformerisdirectlymeasuredinnational accounts(employeecompensationpluscorporateprofitsnetofdepreciation),whilethe latteriscomputedastheratioofcorporateincometaxrevenuetocorporateprofits.Inthe secondpart, ETRK NC measurestheeffectivetaxrateoncapitalinthenon-corporatesector; itismultipliedbythenon-corporatesector’sincomeshare, 1 µK C ,whichincludesmixed incomeofunincorporatedenterprisesandhouseholdsurplus(rentsandimputedrents).43 InLMICs, ETRK C is50%largerthantheoverall ETRK (19.9%versus13.3%).This stemsfrombothstrongerenforcementandhigherstatutorytaxburdensinthecorporate sector.44 Hence,theexpansionofthecorporatesectorrelativetothenon-corporatesector (i.e.anincreasein µC )couldincrease ETRK .
Theconjecturethattradeexertsataxcapacityeffectisrootedintheliteratureon tradeandfirmsize (describedinDix-Carneiroetal., 2021). First,tradecanleadto increasedmarketopportunitiesthatdisproportionatelybenefitlargeexporters(Melitz, 2003).Second,tradecanexpandtheavailabilityofintermediategoodsandlowertheir prices,whichcoulddisproportionatelybenefitinitiallylargerfirms (forexampledueto fixedcostsasinKugler&Verhoogen, 2009). Throughthesetwochannels,tradecould expandthecorporatesector’sshareofnationalincome(µC ),aslargerfirmsaremore likelytobeincorporated.Moreover,bybenefitinginitiallylargerfirmsorleadingtofirm
42Inthissection,capitaltaxationisdenotedwitha K-superscripttoaccommodateadditionalnotation.
43ETR K NC ismeasuredastheratiooftaxrevenuefrompropertyandwealth,self-employment,andthePIT assignedtocapital,overcapitalmixed-incomeandthesurplusofthehouseholdsector.Itisthuscomposed ofamixofvariables,whicharearguablynotaswellmeasuredasthosefromthecorporatesector.
44Theabilitytolevyhighertaxratesisendogenoustoenforcement (Bergeron,Tourek,&Weigel, 2024). Our notionoftaxcapacityisthattheseco-determinedforcesjointlycontributetoeffectivetaxation.
ETRK = i∈C ETRK i f (i) di + i∈NC ETRK i f (i) di (6) = µ K C · ETRK C +(1 µ K C ) · ETRK NC (7)
23
sizegrowthwithinthecorporatesector,tradecouldalsoincreasetheaverageeffective corporatetaxrate, ETRK C .Thiseffectwouldbedrivenbyapositivefirmsize-ETRK i gradient,wheresizeismeasuredasfirmrevenue.Thepositivegradientarisesbecause complianceandenforcementincreasewithsize.45 Italsoarisesbecausethetaxcodein LMICsoftenleadstohigherstatutorytaxburdensforlargerfirms (R.Kumar&James, 2022): usingadministrativetaxdata,Bachasetal.(2023)findapositiveassociationbetween firmsizeandthestatutoryeffectivetaxrateforcorporatefirmsin15LMICs.46
6.2Resultsonmechanisms:Taxcapacityandracetothebottom
Weinvestigatemechanismsrelatingtradeto ETR,focusingonthetaxcapacityand’race tothebottom’channels.Intheracetobottom,internationaltaxcompetitionleadsgovernmentstoreducestatutorycorporatetaxrates,whichwouldreduce ETRK C (Section 2). WestudybothmechanismsinLMICswiththeempiricalstrategiesofSection 5.
Table 3 showstheOLS(PanelA)andtheIV(PanelB)fromequation 5.Consistent withrace-to-bottom,column(1)showsthattradecausesadecreaseinthestatutoryCIT rate(significantat10%).47 TheCITrateisanimperfectproxyoffirms’taxincentivesasit ignoresthetaxbase (Abbas&Klemm, 2013), butitcanbemeasuredinourfullsample.
Inlinewiththetaxcapacitymechanism,traderaisesthecorporateshareofdomestic output(µC ),andreducesmixedincomebyanequivalentmagnitude.48 Thisisconsistent withtheconjecturethattradedisproportionatelybenefitslargerfirms,whicharemore likelytobeincorporated.Tradealsoraises ETRK C (column6),consistentwiththetradeinducedcorporateoutputaccruingtofirmswhose ETRK -sizegradientispositive.
Howistheadditionalincomeofthecorporatesectorallocatedbetweencapitaland labor?Columns(4)-(5)showthatthecorporatesectorriseisentirelydrivenbyhigher corporateprofits,whilethechangeinemployeecompensationgrowthissmallandsta-
45SeestudiescitedinSection 2.Forexample, Bestetal.(2021) uncoveranegativesize-evasiongradientusing randomizedauditdataonfirmsinPakistan,findingalsothatfirm-sizeisthemostsignificantpredictor ofevasion.Modelsoftaxcomplianceprovidemicro-foundationsforthenegativesize-evasiongradient (includingKlevenetal., 2016;Kopczuk&Slemrod, 2006).
46Thegradientispositiveeverywhereexceptattheverytopofthesize-distribution,whereitbecomes negative.Thegradientisdrivenbypreferentialtaxtreatmentsthatincreasewithfirmsizeandwith characteristicsthatcorrelatewithsizesuchastotalprofits.Thegradientcanalsoreflectavoidance behavior,iflargerfirmsareonaveragelessabletotakeactionsthatreducetheirlegaltaxliability.
47Theoutcomeisthefirst-differencedtaxrate(Romer&Romer,2010).Table A4 showsresultswiththelevel oftheCITrate.WecombinedatafromVéghandVuletin(2015), Eggeretal.(2019), TaxFoundation (link) andcountry-specificsources.Anextstepcouldbetostudytrade’simpactonthemoredetailedstatutory measures(Section 2).ThedownwardtrendinCITratesinLMICs(supp.appendix)isrelatedto,butdoes notfullycapture,changesovertimeinthedetailedstatutorymeasures.
48Thequalityofdata-sourcesusedbynationalstatisticsofficescanaffectthemeasurementofmixedincome inLMICs,butwefindnoimpactoftradeoncountries’statisticalcapacity (WorldBanklink).
24
tisticallyinsignificant.49 This,inturn,causestradetoexpandthecapitalshare,bothof nationalincomeandofthecorporatesector(columns7-8).50
ThemechanismIV-resultsarerobusttoseveralchecks(Table A4):usingNDPweights; includingcontrols;winsorizingthetradevariable;and,estimatingIVsseparatelybased oneachinstrument.TheCITrateresultremainslessrobustthanthetaxcapacityresults.
Figure A3 studiesthesamemechanism-outcomesbutusingtheevent-studydesign (Section 5.1).ThetradeliberalizationeventsledtoadecreaseintheCITrateandraised bothcorporateincome(µC )andtheeffectivecorporatetaxrate(ETRK C ).Someindividual event-timecoefficientsarelesspreciselyestimated,butthepost-eventdummiesarejointly statisticallysignificantforalloutcomes.Althoughtheyarebasedondifferentidentifying variationintrade,theevent-studyandIVresultsarethereforebothconsistentwiththe existenceofthetax-capacityandrace-to-bottommechanismsindevelopingcountries.
6.3Firm-levelinvestigationoftaxcapacitymechanism
Thetaxcapacitymechanismisbasedonafirmlevelchannel,combiningapositiveimpact oftradeonfirmsizewithapositivefirmsize-ETRK gradient.Whilethemacro-results on µC and ETRK C intheprevioussubsectionareconsistentwithit,inthissubsectionwe directlyinvestigatethetaxcapacitymechanismatthefirmlevel.
WeconducttheanalysisinRwandabetween2015and2017,whereweleveragemultiple administrativedatasetstoobserveeachformalRwandanfirm’sexposuretotradeand domestictaxpayments.Toourknowledge,thereislimitedfirmlevelevidenceinLMICs onhowtradeimpactsafirm’sdomesticeffectivetaxrate.Rwandaisaninteresting settingasthecorporatesector,startingfromacomparativelylowoutputshare,hasgrown significantlysincethe1990s,intandemwithariseintradeopennessandtaxrevenues.
Weusecorporateincometaxreturnstomeasureeachfirm’seffectivetaxrate ETRK i as theratioofcorporatetaxespaiddividedbyreportednetprofit.Netprofitisrevenueminus material,labor,operational,depreciationandfinancialcosts.InRwanda,thisfirm-level ETRK i variesduetofirmcharacteristics(includingrevenue,ourproxyforsize),reduced ratesandexemptions(Mascagni,MonkamandNell,2016).This ETRK i canalsovarydue totaxavoidancebut,sincethedenominatorisbasedontaxreturns,itwillnotcapture
49Thereisalsoanulleffectoftradeonhouseholds’operatingsurplus OSHH (resultnotshown).
50Thiscouldoccurduetoanincreaseinmarkups. DeLoeckerandEeckhout(2021) findthatmarkupshave riseninmostregionsoverthepast40years. DeLoecker,Goldberg,Khandelwal,andPavcnik(2016) and Goldberg(2023) studytheimpactoftradeonmarkups. Gupta(2023) andAtkinetal.(2015)findthat markupsincreasewithfirmsize,respectivelyinIndiaandPakistan.Theriseincorporateprofitsand limitedchangeinemployeecompensationmayalsoariseiftraderaisesfirms’labormarketpower (Felix, 2022). Finally,itmayariseiftradebenefitsmorecapital-intensiveproductionindevelopingcountries, includingthroughareductioninCITrates(KaymakandSchott,2023).
25
outrightevasion.51 Thecorporate ETRK i inRwandaiseverywherepositivelyassociated withsize(proxiedbyfirmrevenue),apartfrominthetoppercentile (Bachasetal., 2023). Outsideoftheverytop,anincreaseinfirm i’ssizemaycause ETRK i torise. WemergetheCITreturnswithcustomsdatatorecordfirms’directexposuretotrade. Followingrecentwork(reviewedin AtkinandKhandelwal, 2020, Bernard&Moxnes, 2018),wemeasureafirm’stotalexposuretotradebyalsoaccountingforthefirm’s indirectexposureviaitslinkagestodomesticsuppliersthatusetradedgoodsintheir production.52 Wemergeadministrativedatathatrecordtransactionlinkagesbetween formalfirms(detailsondataandsampleinAppendix D.1).Tomeasureafirm’stotaltrade exposureinanetworksetting,wefollowthemethodologyin Dhyne,Kikkawa,Mogstad, andTintelnot(2021) thatusessimilardatasetstomeasureBelgianfirms’exposureto trade.Specifically,wedefinefirm i’stotalforeigninputshareastheshareofinputsthat itdirectlyimports(sFi),plustheshareofinputsthatitbuysfromitsdomesticsuppliers l (sli),multipliedbythetotalimportsharesofthosefirms:
where Vi isthesetofdomesticsuppliersoffirm i,and Vl isthesetofdomesticsuppliers offirm l.Thedenominatoroftheinputsharesisthesumofimportsandpurchasesfrom otherfirms.Welimittherecursivecalculationin(8)toinputsfromafirm’simmediate suppliers l andthesupplierstotheirsuppliers r (addingmorelevelsonlymarginallyraises sTotal i ).53 Inspecting sTotal i and sFi revealsthatwhilejustunder30%ofRwandanformal firmsimportdirectly,93%relyontradedirectlyorindirectlythroughsupplierswhich useforeigninputsintheirproduction.Mostfirmsarethereforedependentonforeign trade,butonlyalimitednumbershowthatdependencethroughthedirectforeigninputs observedincustomsdata.Themediantotalforeigninputshareis48%.
Weestimateregressionsinthesampleofcorporatefirmsoftheform:
51Forthisreason, ETR K C measuredinnationalaccountsdiffersfromthe(appropriatelyweighted)corporate ETRK i measuredintaxreturns.Theyalsodifferbecauseofconceptualdifferencesinthemeasurementof profits:seethe supplementaryappendix foradetaileddiscussion.
52RecentpapersstudydomesticlinkagesinLMICsandtheirroleinpropagatingtradeshocks (including Almunia,Hjort,etal., 2023;Fieler,Eslava,&Xu, 2018;Javorcik, 2004).
53Wefocusonfirms’exposuretoimportsthroughtheirsuppliernetwork;wefindqualitativelysimilar resultswhenwestudyfirms’exposuretoexportsthroughtheirclientnetwork(resultsavailable).
s Total i = sFi + l∈Vi sli [sFl + r∈Vl srl (sFr + )] (8)
ETRK it = µ s Total it +Θ Xit + πt + πi + ϵit (9)
26
where ETRK it and sTotal it arethecorporateeffectivetaxrateandtotaltradeexposureoffirm i inyear t,and πt and πi areyearandfirmfixedeffects. Xit includesnumberofemployees andnumberofclientsandsuppliers,and ϵit isclusteredatthefirmlevel.
InTable4,theOLSestimationof(9)showsthatawithin-firmincreaseintradeexposure isassociatedwithahighercorporateeffectivetaxrate.Thisresultholdswithonlyyear fixedeffects πt (column1);withindustry-geographyfixedeffects(column2);withfirm controls Xit (column3);withfirmfixedeffects πi (column4).
InTable 4,column(5),weimplementanIVthatgeneratesfirm-levelvariationin tradeexposureusingtheshift-sharedesignfrom Hummelsetal.(2014). Theidentifying variationistradeshocksfromchangesintheworldexportsupplyofspecificcountryproductcombinationsinwhichaRwandanfirmhadapreviousimportrelationship. Specifically,thedirectimporttradeshockforfirm i inyear t is:
where sa,M ic,t 1 istheshareofimportsoffirm i inyear t 1 thatfallsonproduct a from country c,and WESa,c,t istheworldexportsupply(excludingsalestoRwanda)ofcountry c forproduct a.Product a ismeasuredatthedetailedsix-digitHSlevel.Rwandanfirms importover3,510distinctproductsfrom174differentcountriesoforigin.
TheshockstoRwandanfirms’tradingenvironmentaretime-varyingandspecificto eachpartner-country × productbeingtraded.Theycapturetransportationcostsand worldwideshockstoexportsupplyfortherelevantcountry × product,andcontain granularvariationacrossproductsandcountries.Theidentificationstrategyrestson thejointhypothesesthattheseshocksareplausiblyexogenoustoRwandanfirms’trading environmentandthattheycreatevariedimpactsacrossfirmsbecauseRwandanimporters havefewimportedinputsincommon.Indeed,thecustomsdatashowsthatthemedian numberofuniqueimportingfirmsinagivenHS6product × countryandtimeperiodis 1;the 95th percentileis3.Hence,ifonlyoneRwandanfirmimportsmetalcoredwires fromTurkey,anidiosyncraticshocktoTurkey’sglobalexportsupplyofthosewireswill affectjustonefirminRwanda.Notealsothat,toconstructthetradeshocks,werely onpriorinformationaboutimporters’sourcingpatterns,whichremovesconcernsover contemporaneousshocksaffectingboththechoiceofimportedgoodsandfirmoutcomes.
Webuildthetradeshocksforallfirms.Inturn,the 1st-stageinstrumentsarethefirm’s owntradeshocks,aswellasthetradeshockstoitssuppliersandtothesuppliersofits suppliers.Specifically,the 1st-stageregressionis:
logM
a,M ic,t 1 · WESa,c,t (10)
D it = log a,c s
s Total it = β1 logM D it + β2 logM S it + β3 logM SS it + κt + κi + ϵit (11) 27
where logM D it , logM S it ,and logM SS it arethetradeshockstofirm i,tofirm i’ssuppliers,and tothesuppliersoffirm i’ssuppliers.Weconstructweightedaveragesoftradeshocksin thesuppliernetworkusingtherecursiveformulationin(8)(detailsinAppendix D.1).
Wefindthatbothdirecttradeshockstoafirm’sownimportsandindirectshocksto afirm’snetworkofsupplierscausesignificantchangestothefirm’stotalexposure sTotal it , generatingastrong 1st-stage(Kleibergen-PaapF-statisticof18.17).
TheIVspecificationshowsthattradecausesanincreaseintheindividualfirm’seffectivetaxrateoncapital(column5).InPanelB,theIVrevealsthattradecausesanincrease infirmsize(proxiedbyrevenue).PanelCshowsapositiveOLSassociationbetweenfirm sizeand ETRK i (wecannotusetheIVinthispanelduetotheexclusionrestriction).
InAppendixD.1,wefindthatthemainresultsarerobusttocontrollingfortradeshocks tofirm i’spotentialsuppliers(firmsthatoperateinthesameindustryandgeographical areaas i’scurrentsuppliersbutarenotcurrentlysupplyingto i)andhorizontalsuppliers (firmsthataresupplierstofirm i’scurrentclients).Theseresultsprovideadditional supportfortheexogeneityassumption.54
ThoughtheanalysisinRwandaisbasedwithinasinglecountryoveralimitedtime range,itsupplementsthemacro-levelresultsintwoways.First,itprovidesfirm-level identifiedevidencethattradeexertsapositiveimpactoneffectivecorporatetaxationina developingcountry,whichcomplementsthecountry-levelresultsinLMICs.Second,by showingthattradeincreasesfirmsizeandthatsizeispositivelyassociatedwith ETRK , itsupportsthetaxcapacitymechanisminterpretationthattrade’simpacton ETRK is mediatedbyapositivesize-ETRK gradient.
Discussion:Linkstotrade-formalityliterature Atthefirm,sectorandcountrylevel,we findpositiveeffectsoftradeonoutcomesrelatedtoformalization.Recentstudiesfocused onthenumberofformalversusinformalfirmsorformalversusinformalworkers,and foundmixedevidencethattradeincreasesformalitybythesemeasures (reviewsinEngel &Kokas, 2021;Ulyssea, 2020).55 Onewaytoreconcileourresultswiththesestudiesisto notethatourfocusisontheshareofoutputproducedinlargerandformalfirms:output expansioninthesefirmsmayoccurwithoutchangestothenumberofformalorinformal firms,anddoesnotimplyanincreaseinthenumberofformalworkers,sinceinformal workersmayworkinformalfirmsandcontributetotheiroutput (Ulyssea, 2018). In 6.4, wealsoshowthatopenness’impactonourformal-outcomesdependsonthenatureofthe tradeshock,consistentwithrecenttheoreticalworkintrade (Dix-Carneiroetal., 2021).
54Inanextension,wefindthatincreased output exposuretoimportsthroughtheclientnetworkhaspositive effectson ETRK ,thoughthisaverageeffectcouldmaskheterogeneityacrossfirms.
55GoldbergandPavcnik(2003),Boschetal.(2012),Crucesetal.(2018),Dix-CarneiroandKovak(2019).
28
6.4Sourcesofheterogeneityintrade’spro-taximpacts
Wereturntothecountry-levelIV(equation 5)tostudysourcesofheterogeneityintrade’s pro-taximpactsonthetaxcapacitymechanismand ETR.
Heterogeneity:Domesticenforcementreforms Overoursampleperiod,LMICshave implementedtaxenforcementpolicies.Achallengeforthemechanisminterpretation isthattrade,potentiallyduetorevenueconcerns,mayhavepromptedgovernmentsto implementthesepoliciesthatincrease ETRK .Toinvestigatethis,wemeasuretheyear ofadoption(ifany)inLMICsoffourpoliciesthatincreasedomestictaxenforcement:(i) largetaxpayerunit;(ii)organizationalintegrationofcustomsanddomestictaxauthorities; (iii)VAT;(iv)internationalaccountingstandards(IAS).56 WeestimateheterogeneousIV effectsbyincludinganinteractiontermbetweentradeandthepolicyadoptionvariablein (5).57 Table A5 showsapositiveeffectoftradeon ETRK withoutthesepolicies,though theeffectislargerfollowingtheiradoption.Tradehasasimilarimpactonthecorporate income-share(µC )withandwithouttheenforcementpolicies,buttrade’spositiveimpact on ETRK C issignificantlyamplifiedwhenenforcementpoliciesareinplace.58 Thatis,the trade-inducedexpansionofthecorporatesectorseemstooccurregardlessofenforcement policies,buttheextenttowhichtheadditionalcorporateoutputtranslatesintohigher effectivecorporatetaxationisreinforcedwhensuchpolicieshavebeenenacted.59 GovernmentsinLMICsmayhavesoughttoraisedomesticrevenue,possiblyinresponsetoopenness,throughotherchannelsapartfromthesespecificenforcementpolicies. WeinvestigatethisinTable A6,findingthattrade’spositiveimpactonthetaxcapacity mechanismand ETRK holdoutsideofperiodsofsignificantrevenueloss,whendefined invariouswaysincludingtheepisodesoftraderevenuelossin CagéandGadenne(2018). Thus,trade’spro-taximpactsappeartobebroadlypresentintheglobalizationprocessin LMICs,anddonothingeongovernment’srevenueneedorenforcementinvestments.
Heterogeneity:Natureoftradeshock Tradetheorieshighlightthattheimpactsoftrade onformality-relatedoutcomesdependonthenatureofthetradeshock.InAppendix D.2,weusebothinstrumentsandequation(5)inLMICstoinvestigateifthe ETR and
56Theenforcementfocusonlargefirmsincreasescollection (Almunia&Lopez-Rodriguez, 2018;M.C. Basri,Felix,Hanna,&Olken, 2021). Thecustoms-taxunificationimprovesdomesticauditcapacity(IMF, 2022).TheVATcreatesinformationtrails (Almunia,Henning,Knebelmann,Nakyambadde,&Tian, 2023; Waseem, 2020). IASdeepenaccountingrequirementsfortaxreporting(Barthetal.,2008).
57Thetimingofadoptionforeachreformisendogenous;however,ourfocusisonthetradecoefficientswith andwithoutthesereformsinplace,whichareidentified(BunandHarrison,2019).
58OnlytheVATwasadoptedinallliberalizingcountriesbythetimeoftheeventsstudiedinSection 5.1
59Intuitively,theenforcementpoliciesalldisproportionatelyraiseenforcementonlargerfirms,thereby furtherincreasingtheslopeofthe ETRK -sizegradientinsidethecorporatesector.Whethertheseenforcementpoliciesarethemselvesdrivenbyglobalizationisatopicforfutureresearch.
29
mechanismimpactsdifferalongtwodimensions (Dix-Carneiroetal., 2021): imports versusexports;and,tradeinintermediateversusfinalgoodsandservices(G-S).Wefind that exports increase ETRK andthecorporateincome-share(µC ),while imports decrease bothoutcomes.Theseresultsareconsistentwith’Melitz-type’demandeffects,whereby increasedexportsrepresentapurepositivedemandshockforexport-orientedfirms, whileincreasedimportsmayconstituteanegativedemandshockfordomesticfirms, disproportionatelyaffectinglargerones.InadditionalIVregressions,tradein intermediate G-S increases ETRK and µC ,whiletradein finalG-S decreasesbothoutcomes.60 Results aresimilarfor ETRK C .Theseresultsareconsistentwiththeincreasedavailabilityof intermediategoodsbenefitinglargerfirms;bycontrast,theincreasedavailabilityoffinal goodsmayconstituteanegativedomesticdemandshock,particularlyforlargerfirms. Theseresultssuggesttrade’spro-taximpactsdependonthenatureofthetradeshock.
Heterogeneity:Developingvsdevelopedcountries Weinvestigateiftrade’simpacts onmechanismsand ETR differacrossdevelopmentlevels,byexpandingoursample toincludeHICs.Weexpectthatthetaxcapacitymechanismislesslikelytooperate inHICs,whereenforcementconstraintsoneffectivetaxationarelessbindingandthe corporatesector’ssizehasbeenstablesincethe1970s(Figure 1).Ontheotherhand,the race-to-bottomislikelytobeactiveinHICs,givenpreviousresearch(Section 2).Table A7 reportsheterogeneousIVeffectsbyaugmenting(5)withaninteractionbetweentrade andadummyforhigh-incomecountries.61 Tradeonlyraises ETRK inLMICs,butraises ETRL everywhere.Thenegativerace-to-bottomeffectontheCITrateismuchstrongerin HICsthaninLMICs.Thepositiveimpactoftradeontaxcapacityoutcomes(µC , ETRK C ) islimitedtoLMICs,withnulleffectsinHICs.62 Theseresultssuggestcountervailing mechanismsthatdifferbydevelopmentlevel,throughwhichtrademayhavecontributed tothedivergingtrendsin ETRK betweenHICsandLMICsdocumentedinFigure 2. Westudyadditionalcountrycharacteristicsinthe supplementaryappendix.Wefind thattrade’snegativeimpactontheCITrateislargerincountriesthataresmallerand withfewercapitalrestrictions–twosettingswherecapitalflightconcernsaremorepronounced (Hines, 2006). Mirroringthisresult,trade’spositiveimpacton ETRK occursin largercountriesandwithmorecapitalrestrictions.Thetaxcapacityandrace-to-bottom mechanismsthereforeappeartooccursimultaneously:countrieswithlargermarketsand lowercapitalmobilityreapmoreofthetax-capacitybenefitsoftrade.
60Whichsuggeststhatimportsofintermediate(final)G-Sincreases(decreases) ETRK and µC
61Wenotetheseresultsshouldbeinterpretedwithcaution,giventheeconometricchallengesofestimating IVeffectswithmultipleendogenousregressors (Andrews,Stock,&Sun, 2019).
62TheIV-coefficientsfordevelopingcountriesdifferqualitativelybetweenTable A7 andTables 1-3.Thisis becausethetwoinstruments’strengthchangesinthe 1st-stageregression(Table A2).
30
Extension:Capitalopenness Wefocusedontradeopennessbutanotherrelevantdimensionofglobalizationiscapitalopenness(Ilzetzki,Reinhart,&Rogoff, 2019;VanPatten, 2022). Duetodifferencesinreportingrequirements,dataoncapitalopennessisnotas availableandcomparableastradedata,andfindingcredibleexogenousvariationforcapitalopennessischallenging.Notwithstanding,wetrytoinvestigatetheimpactsofcapital opennessinAppendix E.Werelyoncapitalinflowliberalizationeventsfor25developing countriesfrom Chari,Henry,andSasson(2012), whichcapturethefirsttimethatforeign investmentinthedomesticstockmarketisallowed.Employingtheevent-studydesign ofSection 5.1,wefindthatcapitalliberalizationeventsraisecapitalopennessandpositivelyimpact ETRK andthetaxcapacitymechanism(µC , ETRK C ).Thepro-taximpactsof globalizationinLMICsmayberobusttousingcapitalinsteadoftradeopenness.
7Conclusion
Thispaperprovidesevidenceonlong-runtrendsincapitaltaxationandcausaleffects ofglobalization.Basedonanewmacro-historicaldatabase,wedocumentthateffective capitaltaxrateshaveincreasedindevelopingcountriesinthepost-1990eraofhyperglobalization.Byexpandingtheshareofeconomicactivityinincorporatedandlarger firms,wefindthattradeimprovestheeffectivecollectionoftaxes,particularlycorporate incometaxes.Weprovideevidenceonthistaxcapacityeffectacrossmultipleresearch designsandatthecountry,corporatesectorandfirm-level.Despiteasimultaneous negativeeffectoncorporatestatutorytaxratesinducedbyinternationaltaxcompetition, thepositivetaxcapacityeffectissufficientlylargethattradeincreasestheeffectivetaxrate oncapitalandoverallgovernmentrevenues(%ofGDP)indevelopingcountries.
Duetolimiteddata,therevenueconsequencesofglobalizationindevelopingcountries hadnotbeensystematicallyinvestigatedandpolicyconcernsoverrevenuelosseshave persistedinacontextofuncertaintysurroundingthefutureofglobalization (Goldberg &Reed, 2023). Wefindthatglobalizationhaspro-taximpactsthathavesupportedthe effectivetaxationofcapitalandoverallrevenuecollectioninmanycountries.
Ourresultsshowthatopennessincreasedtheshareofmarketincomegoingtocorporations,profits,andcapital.Simultaneously,trade’spro-taximpactsmeanthatdeveloping countriesraisedmoretaxesfromcapital.Asaresult,opennessislikelytohavewidened pre-taxincomeinequality,butitseffectonpost-taxincomeinequalityismorenuanced.We adoptedamacrofocus,butanextstepcouldbetocombinethe ETRswithindividual-level estimatesoftheprogressivityofcapital(andlabor)taxes.Thiswouldallowacomparisonofthedistributionaleffectsofglobalizationonpreversuspost-taxincome,raising empiricalquestionsforfutureresearch (Goldberg, 2023;Pavcnik, 2017).
31
References
Abbas,A.,&Klemm,A.(2013).Apartialracetothebottom:Corporatetaxdevelopments indevelopingeconomies. InternationalTaxandPublicFinance, 20. Abramovsky,L.,Klemm,A.,&Phillips,D.(2014).Corporatetaxindevelopingcountries: Currenttrendsanddesignissues. FiscalStudies, 35(4),559–588. Adam,A.,Kammas,P.,&Rodriguez,A.L.(2013).Theeffectofglobalizationoncapital taxation. JournalofMacroeconomics, 35. Alesina,A.,&Wacziarg,R.(1998).Openness,countrysizeandgovernment. Journalof PublicEconomics, 69.
Alfaro-Ureña,A.,Manelici,I.,&Vasquez,J.(2022).Theeffectsofjoiningmultinational supplychains. QuarterlyJournalofEconomics, 137(3).
Almunia,M.,Henning,D.,Knebelmann,J.,Nakyambadde,D.,&Tian,L.(2023).Leveragingtradingnetworkstoimprovetaxcompliance. WorkingPaper. Almunia,M.,Hjort,J.,Knebelmann,J.,&Tian,L.(2023).Strategicorconfusedfirms? EvidencefrommissingtransactionsinUganda. ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics. Almunia,M.,&Lopez-Rodriguez,D.(2018).Undertheradar:Theeffectsofmonitoring firmsontaxcompliance. AmericanEconomicJournal:EconomicPolicy, 10(1).
Andrews,I.,Stock,J.,&Sun,L.(2019).WeakinstrumentsinIVregression:Theoryand evidence. AnnualReviewofEconomics, 11. Atkin,D.,&Khandelwal,A.(2020).Howdistortionsaltertheimpactsofinternational tradeindevelopingcountries. AnnualReviewofEconomics, 12
Bachas,P.,Fattal,R.,&Jensen,A.(2019).Size-dependenttaxenforcementandcompliance. JournalofDevelopmentEconomics, 140,203–222.
Bachas,P.,Brockmeyer,A.,Dom,R.,&Semelet,C.(2023).Effectivetaxratesandfirmsize. WorkingPaper
Basri,C.,Felix,M.,Hanna,R.,&Olken,B.(2019).Taxadministrationvs.taxrates. NBER WorkingPaper,(26150).
Basri,M.C.,Felix,M.,Hanna,R.,&Olken,B.(2021).Taxadministrationversustaxrates. AmericanEconomicReview, 111(12).
Baunsgaard,T.,&Keen,M.(2009).Taxrevenueand(or?)tradeliberalization. Journalof PublicEconomics, 94(9).
Benzarti,Y.,&Tazhitdinova,A.(2021).Dovalue-addedtaxesaffectinternationaltrade flows? AmericanEconomicJournal:EconomicPolicy, 13(4),469–89.
Bergeron,A.,Tourek,G.,&Weigel,J.(2024).Thestatecapacityceilingontaxrates. Econometrica, Forthcoming. Bernard,A.,Jensen,B.,Redding,S.,&Schott,P.(2007).Firmsininternationaltrade. Journal ofEconomicPerspectives, 21(3).
Besley,T.,&Persson,T.(2014).Whydodevelopingcountriestaxsolittle?JournalofEconomic Perspectives, 28(4).
Best,M.,Shah,J.,&Waseem,M.(2021).Detectionwithoutdeterrence. WorkingPaper. Bilicka,K.A.(2019).ComparingUKtaxreturnsofforeignmultinationalstomatched domesticfirms. AmericanEconomicReview, 109(8).
Blanchet,T.,Chancel,L.,Flores,I.,&Morgan,M.(2021). Distributionalnationalaccounts.
32
Borusyak,K.,Jaravel,X.,&Spiess,J.(2021).Revisitingeventstudydesigns:Robustand efficientestimation. WorkingPaper.
Brandt,L.,Biesebroeck,J.V.,Wang,L.,&Zhang,Y.(2017).WTOaccessionandperformance ofChinesemanufacturingfirms. AmericanEconomicReview, 107(9).
Buettner,T.,&Madzharova,B.(2018).WTOmembershipandtheshifttoconsumption taxes. WorldDevelopment, 108(1).
Cagé,J.,&Gadenne,L.(2018).Taxrevenuesandthefiscalcostoftradeliberalization, 1792-2006. ExplorationsinEconomicHistory, 70 Carey,D.,&Rabesona,J.(2004).Taxratiosonlaborandcapitalincomeandonconsumption.InP.B.Sørensen(Ed.), Measuringthetaxburdenoncapitalandlabor. Carillo,P.,Pomeranz,D.,&Singhal,M.(2017).Dodgingthetaxman:Firmmisreporting andlimitstotaxenforcement. AmericanEconomicJournal:AppliedEconomics, 9(2).
Chari,A.,Henry,P.,&Sasson,D.(2012).Capitalmarketintegrationandwages. American EconomicJournal:Macroeconomics, 4(2).
Clausing,K.(2007).CorporatetaxrevenuesinOECDcountries. InternationalTaxandPublic Finance, 14.
Cogneau,D.,Dupraz,Y.,Knebelmann,J.,&Mesplé-Somps,S.(2021).TaxationinAfrica fromcolonialtimestopresent. WorkingPaper. DeLoecker,J.,&Eeckhout,J.(2021).Globalmarketpower. WorkingPaper. DeLoecker,J.,Goldberg,P.,Khandelwal,A.,&Pavcnik,N.(2016).Prices,markupsand tradereform. Econometrica, 84(2).
Devereux,M.,&Griffith,R.(1999).Thetaxationofdiscreteinvestmentchoices. Institute forFiscalStudiesWorkingPaperSeries, No.W98/16.
Devereux,M.,Griffith,R.,&Klemm,A.(2002).Corporateincometax:Reformsandtax competition. EconomicPolicy
Dhyne,E.,Kikkawa,A.,Mogstad,M.,&Tintelnot,F.(2021).Tradeanddomesticproduction networks. ReviewofEconomicStudies, 88(2).
Dix-Carneiro,R.,Goldberg,P.,Meghir,C.,&Ulyssea,G.(2021).Tradeandinformalityin thepresenceoflabormarketfrictionsandregulations. NBERWorkingPaper
Dyreng,S.D.,Hanlon,M.,Maydew,E.L.,&Thornock,J.R.(2017).Changesincorporate effectivetaxratesover25years. JournalofFinancialEconomics, 124(3).
Egger,P.,Nigai,S.,&Strecker,N.(2019).Thetaxingdeedofglobalization. American EconomicReview, 109(2).
Engel,J.,&Kokas,D.(2021).Thedistributionalimpactsoftrade. WorkingPaper Felix,M.(2022).Trade,labormarketconcentration,andwages. WorkingPaper.
Fieler,A.,Eslava,M.,&Xu,D.(2018).Trade,qualityupgradingandinputlinkages:Theory andevidencefromColombia. AmericanEconomicReview, 108(1).
Fisman,R.,&Wei,S.-J.(2004).Taxratesandtaxevasion:Evidencefrom"missingimports" inChina. JournalofPoliticalEconomy, 112(2).
Fisunoglu,A.,Kang,K.,Arbetman-Rabinowitz,M.,&Kugler,J.(2011).Relativepolitical capacitydataset.Version2.4.HarvardDataverse.
Garcia-Bernardo,J.,Janský,P.,&Tørsløv,T.(2022).Decomposingmultinationalcorporationsdecliningeffectivetaxrates. IMFEconomicReview, 70(2).
Goldberg,P.(2023). Theunequaleffectsofglobalization.MITPress.
33
Goldberg,P.,&Pavcnik,N.(2007).Distributionaleffectsofglobalizationindeveloping countries. JournalofEconomicLiterature, 45(1).
Goldberg,P.,&Pavcnik,N.(2016).Theeffectsoftradepolicy. NBERWorkingPaper. Goldberg,P.,&Reed,T.(2023).Istheglobaleconomydeglobalizing? BrookingsPaperon EconomicActivity.
Gollin,D.(2002).Gettingincomesharesright. JournalofPoliticalEconomy, 110(2). Griffith,R.,&Miller,H.(2014).Taxablecorporateprofits. FiscalStudies, 35. Guerriero,M.(2019).Laborshareofincomearoundtheworld. WorkingPaper Gupta,A.(2023).Demandforquality,variablemarkupsandmisallocation:Evidencefrom India. WorkingPaper.
Hines,J.(2006).Corporatetaxationandinternationalcompetition. WorkingPaper. Hummels,D.,Jørgensen,R.,Munch,J.,&Xiang,C.(2014).Thewageeffectsofoffshoring. AmericanEconomicReview, 104(6).
ILO.(2019). Thegloballabourincomeshareanddistribution. Intl.LaborOrganization. Ilzetzki,E.,Reinhart,C.,&Rogoff,K.(2019).Exchangearrangementsenteringthetwentyfirstcentury. QuarterlyJournalofEconomics, 134(2).
IMF.(2014).Spilloversininternationalcorporatetaxation. IMFStaffReport
Javorcik,B.(2004).Doesforeigndirectinvestmentincreasetheproductivityofdomestic firms? AmericanEconomicReview, 94(3).
Javorcik,B.,&Narciso,G.(2017).WTOaccessionandtariffevasion. JournalofDevelopment Economics, 125,59–71.
Jensen,A.(2022).Employmentstructureandtheriseofthemoderntaxsystem. American EconomicReview, 112(1).
Karabarbounis,L.,&Neiman,B.(2014).Theglobaldeclineofthelaborshare. Quarterly JournalofEconomics, 129(1).
Kleven,H.,Kreiner,C.,&Saez,E.(2016).Whycanmoderngovernmentstaxsomuch? Economica, 83(330).
Kleven,H.,Knudsen,M.,Kreiner,C.,Pedersen,S.,&Saez,E.(2011).Unableorunwilling tocheat?Evidencefromataxauditexperiment. Econometrica, 79(3).
Kopczuk,W.,&Slemrod,J.(2006).Puttingfirmsintooptimaltaxtheory.AmericanEconomic Review, 96(2).
Kostarakos,I.,&Varthalitis,P.(2020).EffectivetaxratesintheEU. WorkingPaper. Kugler,M.,&Verhoogen,E.(2009).Plantsandimportedinputs:Newfactsandaninterpretation. AmericanEconomicReview, 99(12).
Kumar,M.M.S.,&Quinn,M.D.P.(2012). Globalizationandcorporatetaxation.International MonetaryFund.
Kumar,R.,&James,S.(2022).WorldBankglobalmarginaleffectivetaxratedatabase report. WorldBankTechnicalReport
Londoño-Vélez,J.,&Tortarolo,D.(2022).Revealing21%ofGDPinhiddenassets:Evidence fromArgentina’staxamnesties. UNUWIDERWorkingPaper,(103).
McCaig,B.,&Pavcnik,N.(2018).Exportmarketsandlaborallocationinalow-income country. AmericanEconomicReview, 108(7).
McDaniel,C.(2007).Averagetaxratesonconsumption,investment,laborandcapitalin theOECD1950-2003. WorkingPaper.
34
McDaniel,C.(2020).Averagetaxratesonconsumption,investment,laborandcapitalin theOECD1995-2018. WorkingPaper.
Méndez,E.,&VanPatten,D.(2022).Multinationals,monopsony,andlocaldevelopment. Econometrica, 90(6).
Mendoza,E.G.,Razin,A.,&Tesar,L.L.(1994).Effectivetaxratesinmacroeconomics. JournalofMonetaryEconomics, 34(3).
Mrázová,M.,&Neary,P.(2018).Selectioneffectswithheterogeneousfirms. Journalof EuropeanEconomicAssociation, 17
Naritomi,J.(2019).Consumersastaxauditors. AmericanEconomicReview, 109(9).
Parenti,M.(2018).Largeandsmallfirmsinaglobalmarket:Davidvs.Goliath. Journalof InternationalEconomics, 110.
Pavcnik,N.(2017).Theimpactoftradeoninequalityindevelopingcountries. Proceedings ofJacksonHoleEconomicSymposium
Piketty,T.,Saez,E.,&Zucman,G.(2018).Distributionalnationalaccounts.QuarterlyJournal ofEconomics, 133(2).
Piketty,T.,Yang,L.,&Zucman,G.(2019).Capitalaccumulation,privateproperty,and risinginequalityinChina. AmericanEconomicReview, 109(7).
Pomeranz,D.(2015).Notaxationwithoutinformation. AmericanEconomicReview. Quinn,D.(1997).Thecorrelatesofchangeininternationalfinancialregulation. American PoliticalScienceReview, 91(3),531–551.
Rodrik,D.(1998).Whydomoreopeneconomieshavebiggergovernments? Journalof PoliticalEconomy, 106(5).
Sequeira,S.(2016).Corruption,tradecosts,andgainsfromtariffliberalization:Evidence fromSouthernAfrica. AmericanEconomicReview, 106. Slemrod,J.(2004).Arecorporatetaxrates,orcountries,converging? JournalofPublic Economics, 88(6),1169–1186.
Slemrod,J.,&Velayudhan,T.(2018).Dofirmsremitatleast85%oftaxeverywhere?New evidencefromIndia. JournalofTaxAdministration, 4(1).
Sørensen,P.(2007).Cancapitalincometaxessurvive? CESifoEconomicStudies, 53
Steinmüller,E.,Thunecke,G.U.,&Wamser,G.(2019).Corporateincometaxesaroundthe world. InternationalTaxandPublicFinance, 26,418–456.
Ulyssea,G.(2018).Firms,informality,anddevelopment. AmericanEconomicReview. Ulyssea,G.(2020).Informality:Causesandconsequencesfordevelopment. AnnualReview ofEconomics, 12
VanPatten,D.(2022).ThedismantlingofcapitalcontrolsafterBrettonWoodsandLatin Americanproductivity. AEAPapersandProceedings, 112.
Wacziarg,R.,&Wallack,J.(2004).Tradeliberalizationandintersectorallabormovements. JournalofInternationalEconomics, 64
Wacziarg,R.,&Welch,K.H.(2008).Tradeliberalizationandgrowth:Newevidence. World BankEconomicReview, 22(2),187–231.
Waseem,M.(2020).Theroleofwithholdingintheself-enforcementofavalue-addedtax. ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics, 104(2).
Wier,L.(2020).Tax-motivatedtransfermispricing. JournalofPublicEconomics. WorldBank.(2008). PublicfinanceinChina (J.Lou&S.Wang,Eds.).WBGroup. WorldBank.(2020). TheAfricancontinentalfreetradearea:Economiceffects.WBGroup.
35
Notes: Thesepanelsplotthetimeseriesofcorporatesectorincomeandofmixedincomebetween1965 and2018bylevelofdevelopment,fromnationalaccountsstatistics.Bothoutcomesareexpressedas apercentofnetdomesticproductandweightedbycountries’netdomesticproductinconstant2010 USD.Corporateincomeisthesumofcorporateprofitsandcorporateemployeecompensation.Mixed incomeaccountsforincomefromself-employedandunincorporatedbusinesses.Theleftpanelshow theresultsforlowandmiddle-incomecountries(N=117),andtherightpanelshowtheresultsforhigh incomecountries(N=37),basedontheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.
Corporate Sector VA Mixed Income 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 % of Net Domestic Product 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Low & Middle−Income Countries Corporate Sector VA Mixed Income 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 High Income Countries
Figure1:CorporateSectorIncomeandMixedIncome(1965-2018)
36
Notes: Thisfigureplotsthetimeseriesofaverageeffectivetaxratesonlabor(red)andcapital(blue), aswellastheaverageeffectivetaxrateoncorporateprofits(bluedashedline).Thetop-leftpanel correspondstotheglobalaverage,weightingcountry-yearobservationsbytheirshareinthatyear’s totalfactorincome,inconstant2019USD(N=154).Thebottom-leftpanelshowstheresultsforhighincomecountries(N=37),andthebottom-rightpanelforlow-andmiddle-incomecountries(N=117). IncomeclassificationisbasedontheWorldBankincomegroupsin2018.Thedatasetiscomposedof twoquasi-balancedpanels.Thefirstcoverstheyears1965-1993andexcludescommunistregimes.It accountsfor85-90%ofworldGDPduringthoseyears.Thesecondcovers1994-2018andintegrates formercommunistcountries,inparticularChinaandRussia,andaccountsfor97-98%ofworldGDP. ThisfigureisdiscussedinSection 4.1
Figure2:EffectiveTaxationofCapitalandLabor(1965-2018) 0 10 20 30 40 Effective Tax Rate (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Global 0 10 20 30 40 Effective Tax Rate (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 High−Income Countries 0 10 20 30 40 Effective Tax Rate (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Low & Middle−Income Countries on Labor on Capital on Corporate Profits
37
Figure3:RobustnessofEffectiveCapitalTaxationinDevelopingCountries
(a)PITrevenueallocation
(b)Mixed-incomeallocation
(c)Panelbalancedness
(d)Weightsforaggregation
(e)All54combinations
Notes: Thesepanelsshowtrendsintheeffectivetaxrateoncapitalinthe117developingcountriesinour sample.Thepanelsvaryourfourkeymethodologicalchoices:theallocationofpersonalincometaxrevenue tocapitalvslabor(panela);theallocationofmixedincometocapitalvslabor(panelb);presentingresults foranunbalancedpanelofcountriesvsabalancedpanelviaimputations(panelc);and,theuseofweights toaggregateindividualcountries’time-series(paneld).Panel(e)showsall54possiblecombinationsthat canbeconstructedbycombiningthesechoices.Inallpanels,thebluelinecorrespondstoourbenchmark series.Developingcountriesarelowandmiddle-incomecountriesaccordingtotheWorldBankincome classificationin2018.ThisfigureisdiscussedinSection 4.2
5 10 15 20 25 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 196519751985199520052015 Country-year(benchmark) 0%toCapital 30%toCapital
5 10 15 20 25 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 196519751985199520052015 25%capital(benchmark) Proportioncorporatesector ILOimputationmethod
5 10 15 20 25 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 196519751985199520052015 Unbalanced(benchmark) Balanced(viaimputations)
5 10 15 20 25 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 196519751985199520052015 %worldcapital,time-varying(benchmark) %worldGDP,time-varying %worldGDPin2010
5 10 15 20 25 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 196519751985199520052015 Benchmark Allpermutations
38
Figure4:HeterogeneityofEffectiveCapitalTaxationinDevelopingCountries
(a)Fourlargestcountries
(b)ExcludingChina
(c)OilRichCountries
Notes: Thesepanelsshowtheevolutionoftheeffectivetaxrateoncapital, ETRK ,formajordeveloping countriesandsub-samplesofdevelopingcountries.Developingcountriesarelowandmiddle-income countriesaccordingtotheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.Panel(a)plotsthe ETRK seriesforthe fourlargest(mostpopulous)developingcountries:Brazil,China,India,Indonesia.Panel(b)comparesour benchmarkseriestotheseriesthatexcludesChina.Panel(c)plotsthe ETRK seriesforasampleofoil-rich countries(countrieswithmorethan7%ofGDPfromoilin2018),andthebenchmark ETRK serieswithout thesecountries.Withinthesampleofnon-oilrichdevelopingcountries,panel(d)compareslargecountries tosmallcountries.Largecountriesaredefinedashavingapopulationabove40millionin2018.Thisfigure isdiscussedinSection 4.3.
China India Indonesia Brazil 5 10 15 20 25 30 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015
Benchmark Excl. China 10 15 20 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015
Benchmark Oil Rich Excl. Oil Rich 10 15 20 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015
Large Countries Small Countries Large, excl. China 10 15 20 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015
(d)Largevssmallcountries(non-oilrich)
39
Figure5:Within-CountryAssociationsbetweenEffectiveTaxRatesandTrade
(a) ETRK :Allcountries (b) ETRL:Allcountries
(c) ETRK :High-income
(e) ETRK :Low&middle-income
(d) ETRL:High-income
(f) ETRL:Low&middle-income
Notes: Thesepanelsshowstheassociationbetweentradeandeffectivetaxrates.Theoutcomeistheeffective taxrateoncapital, ETRK ,andonlabor, ETRL,intheleft-sideandright-sidepanels,respectively.The toppanelsshowtheassociationsinallcountries;themiddlepanelsshowtheassociationsinhigh-income countries(basedonWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018);thebottompanelsshowtheassociations inlowandmiddle-incomecountries.Tradeismeasuredasthesumofimportandexportsasashareof netdomesticproduct.Boththex-axisandy-axisaremeasuredaswithin-countrypercentchangesover5 years.Eachgraphshowsbinnedscatterplotsofeachoutcomeagainsttrade,afterresidualizingallvariables againstyear-fixedeffects.Eachdotcorrespondstoaventile(20equal-sizedbins)oftheresidualizedtrade variable,withaveragevaluesoftradeand ETR calculatedbyventile.Ineachgraph,thelinerepresents thebestlinearfitbasedontheunderlyingcountry-yeardata,withthecorrespondingslopecoefficientand standarderrorreportedinthetop-leftcorner.Formoredetails,seeSection 4.4.
40
Figure6:EventStudyofTradeLiberalizationReforms
Notes: Thesefiguresshowevent-studiesfortradeliberalizationinsevenlargedevelopingcountries:Argentina,Brazil,China,Colombia,India,MexicoandVietnam.Thepanelscorrespondtodifferentoutcomes: trade(toppanels);effectivetaxrateoncapital(middlepanels);effectivetaxrateonlabor(bottompanels). Theleft-sidegraphsshowtheaverageleveloftheoutcomeineveryyearto/sincetheeventforthetreated groupandforthegroupofsyntheticcontrolcountries.Theright-handgraphsshowthe βe coefficients ontheto/sincedummies,basedonestimatingthedynamicevent-studyregressioninequation(4).The barsrepresentthe95%confidenceintervals.Standarderrorsareclusteredatthecountry-eventleveland estimatedwiththewildbootstrapmethod.Thetop-leftcornersreporttheF-statisticonthejointsignificance ofthepost-eventdummies,withthep-valueinparentheses.DetailsonmethodologyinSection 5.1.1.
.2 .3 .4 .5 .6 Trade (% of NDP) −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Years to/from Event TreatedCountries SyntheticControl Joint significance of event dummies: 4.52 (.006) −.2 −.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 Coefficient on Trade −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Years to/from Event .04 .08 .12 .16 Effective Tax Rate on Capital −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Years to/from Event TreatedCountries SyntheticControl Joint signif. of post−event dummies: 4.56 (.006) −.08 −.04 0 .04 .08 .12 Coefficient on ETR_K −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Years to/from Event .04 .08 .12 .16 Effective Tax Rate on Labor −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Years to/from Event TreatedCountries SyntheticControl Joint significance of event dummies: 4.82 (.005) −.08 −.04 0 .04 .08 .12 Coefficient on ETR_L −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Years to/from Event
41
Table1:TradeImpactsonEffectiveTaxationofCapitalandLaborinDevelopingCountries
Robustness:Specification
PanelA: ETRK
Robustness: K L assignment
Robustness:Individual
PanelB: ETRL
Modifications ETR NDPInclude IncludeWinsorizeAssign Assign AssignAssign OnlyuseOnlyuse toIVincol.(2) winsorizeweightscountry-year 1(oil-rich)*yeartrade basedonbasedon0%ofPIT30%ofPIT Zgravity ZOil Dist controlsfixedeffects ILO(2019) corp. K-sharetocapitaltocapitalinstrumentinstrument
Notes: Thistablepresentsresultsfromestimatingtheeffectoftradeoneffectivetaxratesindevelopingcountries.Developingcountriesarelowand middle-incomecountriesaccordingtotheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.Theoutcomeistheeffectivetaxrateoncapital, ETRK ,inPanel Aandtheeffectivetaxrateonlabor, ETRL,inPanelB.Tradeismeasuredasthesumofexportsandimportsdividedbynetdomesticproduct(NDP). Column(1)presentstheOLSresultsfromestimatingequation(5).AllothercolumnsuseIV;atthebottomofeachcolumn,wereportthe 1st-stage Kleibergen-PaapF-statistic.ThebenchmarkIVspecificationisincolumn(2),withthecorresponding 1st-stageregressionreportedinTable A2.The remainingcolumnsmodifythebenchmarkspecificationofcolumn(2).Incolumn(3),theoutcomeisnon-winsorized,whileincolumn(4)weinclude country-yearNDPweights.Incolumn(5),weincludethecountry-yearcontrolsdescribedinSection 5.2.1.Incolumn(6),weincludeinteractive fixedeffectsbetweenadummyforoil-richcountriesandyeardummies.Oil-richcountriesderivemorethan7%ofGDPfromoilin2018.Incolumn (7),weusethetradevariablewhichiswinsorizedatthe5%-95%percentileonayearlybasis.Incolumns(8)-(9),wemodifytheassignmentrule formixedincome’scapitalfactorshare,respectivelybyusingthe ILO(2019) methodandbyassigningthecapitalshareinthecorporatesector.In columns(10)-(11),weassignrespectively0%and30%ofpersonalincometaxes(PIT)tocapitaltaxes.Incolumns(12)-(13),weestimatetheIVusing theindividualinstruments Zgravity and Zoil distance,respectively.Formoredetails,seeSection 5.2.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01.Standarderrorsin parenthesesareclusteredatthecountrylevel.
Benchmark
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13)
andcovariates totaxesandfactorshares instruments
Trade 0.048***0.151*** 0.135***0.211*0.141** 0.136*** 0.159*** 0.161*** 0.140***0.147***0.158*** 0.148***0.277*** (0.013)(0.047) (0.037)(0.121)(0.055) (0.044) (0.046) (0.052) (0.045) (0.045)(0.047) (0.047)(0.095)
Trade 0.009*0.047*** 0.052***0.059 0.037* 0.048*** 0.049*** 0.048*** 0.051***0.049***0.042*** 0.044***0.214*** (0.005)(0.016) (0.016)(0.043)(0.019) (0.016) (0.016) (0.016) (0.017) (0.016)(0.015) (0.016)(0.067) Specification OLSIV IV IV IV IV IV IV IV IV IV IV IV 1st stageKleibergen- 24.59 24.5934.51 14.14 23.24 34.84 24.59 24.59 24.59 24.59 45.13 10.75 PaapF-statistic
N 49164916 49164916 3938 4916 4916 4916 4916 4916 4916 4916 4916
PanelB:IV
Notes: Thistableshowstheimpactsoftradeoncollectionoftypesoftaxes,expressedasapercentof netdomesticproduct(NDP),indevelopingcountries.OLSresultsareinPanelAandIVresultsarein PanelB.Developingcountriesarelowandmiddle-incomecountriesaccordingtotheWorldBankincome classificationin2018.TradeismeasuredasthesumofexportsandimportsdividedbyNDP.Allregressions inPanelBarebasedontheIVmodeldescribedinSection 5.2.Atthebottomofeachcolumn,wereportthe 1st-stageKleibergen-PaapF-statistic.Thecorresponding 1st-stageregressionisreportedinTable A2.The outcomediffersacrosscolumns:Column(1)istotaltaxes,whichisthesumofdirecttaxesoncapitaland laborandindirecttaxesontradeanddomesticconsumption;column(2)iscorporateincometaxes(CIT); column(3)istaxesonproperty,wealthandinheritance;column(4)ispersonalincometaxes(PIT);column (5)issocialsecurityandpayroll;column(6)isindirecttaxes,whichcombinestradetaxesanddomestic consumptiontaxes.Formoredetailsonthesetypesoftaxes,seeTable B2 andAppendix B.1.Formore detailsontheIV,seeSection 5.2.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01.Standarderrorsinparenthesesareclustered atthecountrylevel.
Total Propertyand Social taxes CIT Wealth PITSecurityIndirect (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Trade 0.036*** 0.021***-0.0010.003*0.0010.010 (0.011) (0.003)(0.001)(0.002)(0.001)(0.006)
Table2:TradeImpactsonTypesofTaxes(%ofNDP)inDevelopingCountries
PanelA:OLS
Trade 0.101*** 0.053***0.0040.011**0.013**0.018 (0.033) (0.014)(0.003)(0.005)(0.006)(0.023) 1st-stageKleibergen-24.59 24.59 24.59 24.5924.5924.59 PappF-statistic N 4916 4916 4916 491649164916
43
PanelA:OLS
Table3:TradeImpactsonMechanismOutcomesinDevelopingCountries
PanelB:IV
First-diff.CorporateHouseholdCorporateEmployeeCorporateCapitalshareCapitalshare CITratetotl.incomemixedincomeprofitscompensation
Notes: Thistablepresentsresultsfromestimatingtheeffectsoftradeonmechanismoutcomesindevelopingcountries.Developingcountriesare lowandmiddle-incomecountriesaccordingtotheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.Tradeismeasuredasthesumofexportsandimports dividedbynetdomesticproduct(NDP).PanelApresentsOLSresultsandPanelBpresentstheIVresults,basedontheinstrumentsdescribedin Section 5.2.AtthebottomofeachcolumninPanelB,wereportthe 1st-stageKleibergen-PaapF-statistic.Acrossthecolumns,theoutcomediffers: column(1)isthefirst-differencedstatutorycorporateincometax(CIT)rate;column(2)isthecorporateincomeshareofnetdomesticproduct,where corporateincomeisthesumofcorporateprofitsandcorporateemployeecompensation;column(3)isthemixedincomeshareofnetdomestic product;column(4)isthecorporateprofitshareofnetdomesticproduct;column(5)istheemployeecompensationshareofnetdomesticproduct; column(6)istheaverageeffectivetaxrateoncorporateprofits;column(7)isthecapitalshareofnetdomesticproduct;column(8)isthecapitalshare ofcorporateincome.Forsakeofspace,weomitshowingtheinsignificantimpactoftradeon OSHH ,theremainingcomponentofnationalincome. Formoredetailsontheoutcomes,seeSection 3.1 andSection 6.2.Formoredetailsontheinstrumentalvariables,seeSection 5.2.*p<0.10**p<0.05 ***p<0.01.Standarderrorsinparenthesesareclusteredatthecountrylevel.
Nationalincomecomponents Factorshares
ETRK natl.incomecorp.sector (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Trade -0.003***0.038*** -0.016 0.026*** 0.006 0.074***0.020** 0.029** (0.001)(0.013) (0.011) (0.009) (0.011) (0.019) (0.008) (0.012)
Trade -0.012*0.179*** -0.184***0.176*** -0.014 0.163**0.150*** 0.192*** (0.007)(0.044) (0.041) (0.035) (0.036) (0.075) (0.034) (0.050) 1st stageKleibergen-24.59 24.59 24.59 24.59 24.59 24.59 24.59 24.59 PaapF-Statistic N 4916 4916 4916 4916 4916 4916 4916 4916
PanelAoutcome: ETRK
PanelBoutcome:Logrevenue
PanelCoutcome: ETRK
Notes: Thistablepresentsfirm-levelregressionresultsfromcorporatefirmsinRwandabetween2015and 2017.Theoutcomediffersacrosspanels:PanelsA)andC)istheeffectivetaxrateoncorporateprofits, ETRK i ;PanelB)islogofannualrevenue.InPanelsA)andB),thereportedregressioncoefficientisfortotal foreigninputshare, STotal;inPanelC),itisforlogannualrevenue.Columns(1)-(4)presentOLSresults fromestimatingvariationsofequation(9):Column(1)includesyearfixedeffects;column(2)addsindustrygeographyfixedeffects;column(3)addsfirm-yearcontrols(numberofemployeesandtotalnumberof clientsandsuppliers);column(4)addsfirmfixedeffects.Column(5)istheIVestimationwherethetotal foreigninputshare(STotal)isinstrumentedwithtrade-shockstofirmsandtheirsuppliernetworkbased ontheshift-sharedesignof Hummels,Jørgensen,Munch,andXiang(2014). Theinstrumentsaredescribed indetailinSection 6.3 andAppendix D.1.Incolumn(5),wealsoreportthe 1st-stageKleibergen-Paap F-statisticfromestimatingthe 1st-stageinequation(11).DetailsonthesampleareprovidedinAppendix D.1.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01.Standarderrorsinparenthesesareclusteredattheindustry-geography levelincolumns(1)-(3),andatthefirm-levelincolumns(4)-(5)(resultsarerobusttoclusteringatfirm-level inallcolumns).
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Table4:Firm-LevelRegressionsinRwanda: ETRK ,TradeandSize
Total 0.100***0.087***0.075***0.025*0.133** (0.021)(0.017)(0.017)(0.014)(0.060)
S
STotal 1.362***1.351**1.078**0.202*1.444*** (0.466)(0.542)(0.475)(0.107)(0.233)
Logrevenue 0.040*0.092***0.077**0.029***(0.023)(0.029)(0.027)(0.003)Estimation OLSOLSOLSOLSIV
18.17
YearFEs Y Y Y Y Y Industry-GeographyFEs Y Y Firmcontrols Y Y Y FirmFEs Y Y N 1847818478184781847818478
1st-stageKleibergen-
PaapF-statistic
45
Appendix
AppendixAAdditionalFiguresandTables
FigureA1:DataCoverageofEffectiveTaxRates
Notes: Thesepanelsshowthecoverageofoureffectivetaxratedatabetween1965and2018attheglobal level(topleftpanel),inhighincomecountries(bottomleftpanel),andinlow-andmiddle-income countries(bottomrightpanel).Low,middleandhigh-incomecountriesarebasedontheWorldBank incomeclassificationin2018.ThesolidlinesplotthepercentoftotalpopulationandGDPthatare coveredinourdata(leftaxis).Thedashedlinesshowthenumberofcountriesinthedata(right axis).Thedatasetiscomposedoftwoquasi-balancedpanels.Thefirstcoverstheyears1965-1993and excludescommunistregimes.Thesecondcovers1994-2018andintegratesformercommunistcountries, inparticularChinaandRussia.SeeSection 3.3 formoredetails.
0 50 100 150 # countries 0 25 50 75 100 coverage (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Global 0 10 20 30 40 # countries 0 25 50 75 100 coverage (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 High−Income Countries 0 25 50 75 100 125 # countries 0 25 50 75 100 coverage (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Low & Middle−Income Countries Population (% of total) GDP (% of total) # countries
1
FigureA2:Evolutionof ETRK Componentssince1989
Notes: Thesepanelsshowtheevolutionofthecomponentsof ETRK between1989and2018.Thisperiodis selectedtomatchtheperiodofrising ETRK inlowandmiddle-incomecountries(LMICs).Theleft-hand sidepanelscorrespondtothetaxesoncapital(numeratorof ETRK ):corporateincometaxes;taxeson property,wealthandinheritance;andtheshareofpersonalincometaxesallocatedtocapital(including capitalgainsanddividends).Theright-handsidepanelscorrespondtothenationalincomecomponents attributedtocapital(denominatorof ETRK ):corporateprofits;operatingsurplusofhouseholds(rents); andtheshareofmixed-incomeattributedtocapital.ThetoppanelsareforLMICs,whilethebottompanels areshown,ascomparison,forhigh-incomecountries(HICs).Seriesareweightedbycountries’national domesticproductin2010.Thetaxrevenuedatabetween1989-1993forformercommandeconomies(e.g. China,Russia)ismissing,andisimputedbyassigningthe1994values5yearsbackward.LMICsandHICs aredefinedaccordingtotheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.ThisfigureisdiscussedinSection 4.1
0 1 2 3 4 5 % of NDP 1990 2000 2010 2020 Corporate IncomePersonal Income (total) Property, WealthPersonal Income (capital) Taxes on (a) LMIC − Capital Tax Revenue 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 % of NDP 1990 2000 2010 2020 Corporate profitsMixed Income (total) Household SurplusMixed Income (capital) National Income component
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 % of NDP 1990 2000 2010 2020 (c) HIC − Capital Tax Revenue 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 % of NDP 1990 2000 2010 2020 (d) HIC − Capital Income
(b) LMIC − Capital Income
2
FigureA3:MechanismImpactsinTradeLiberalizationEventStudies
(a)Totaltaxes(%ofNDP)
Jointsignif.ofeventdummies: 1406 (.001)
(c)Corporateincome(%ofNDP)
Jointsignif.ofpost−eventdummies:
(b)Corp.incometaxrate(first-diff.)
Jointsignif.ofpost−eventdummies:
(d)Mixedincome(%ofNDP)
Jointsignif.ofpost−eventdummies:
(e)Corporate ETRK
(f)Capitalincome(%ofNDP)
Notes: Thesepanelsshowtheimpactsofthetradeliberalizationeventsontotaltaxescollectedandmechanism outcomes.ThepanelsareconstructedusingthemethodinSection 5.1,andsimilarlytoFigure 6.Across panels,theoutcomediffers:panela)istotaltaxrevenue,asapercentofnetdomesticproduct(NDP);panel b)isthefirst-differencedstatutorycorporateincometaxrate;panelc)isthecorporateincomeshareofnet domesticproduct,wherecorporateincomeisthesumofcorporateprofitsandemployeecompensation; paneld)isthemixedincomeshareofnetdomesticproduct;panele)istheaverageeffectivetaxrate oncorporateprofits;panelf)isthecapitalshareofnetdomesticproduct.Ineachpanel,thetop-left cornerreportstheF-statisticforthejointsignificanceofpost-eventdummies,withthep-valuereportedin parentheses.
−.1 −.05 0 .05
Coefficient on total taxes (% of NDP) −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent
.1
14.63 (.001) −.1 −.05 0 .05 .1 Coefficient on CIT rate −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent
20.03 (.001) −.1 −.05 0 .05 .1 Coefficient on corp. profits −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent
2.18 (.033) −.1 −.05 0 .05 .1 Coefficient on Mixed income −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent
14.30 (.001) −.2 −.1 0 .1 .2 Coefficient on Corp. ETR_K −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent
Jointsignif.ofpost−eventdummies:
Jointsignif.ofpost−eventdummies:: 35.01 (.001) −.08 −.04 0 .04 .08 .12 Coefficient on K−share −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent
3
TableA1:SyntheticDifference-in-DifferenceofTradeLiberalization
PanelA: Syntheticcontrolforeachoutcomeseparately
Post*Treat
Imputedtreatmenteffect
PanelB: Syntheticcontrolforalloutcomesjointly
Post*Treat
Imputedtreatmenteffect
PanelC: Donorpoolexcludingmajortradingpartners
Post*Treat
Imputedtreatmenteffect
PanelD: Donorpoolrestrictedtonot-yetliberalized Post*Treat
Imputedtreatmenteffect
PanelE: Donorpoolrestrictedtosameregion
Post*Treat
Imputedtreatmenteffect
PanelF: DonorpoolrestrictedtoLMICs
Post*Treat
Imputedtreatmenteffect
0.0640.045***0.020** (0.047)(0.015)(0.009)
0.070*0.047***0.020*** (0.039)(0.009)(0.005)
0.092*0.033*0.012 (0.044)(0.016)(0.008)
0.101***0.033***0.012*** (0.028)(0.006)(0.004)
0.0730.047***0.018** (0.055)(0.015)(0.008)
0.082**0.048***0.018*** (0.035)(0.009)(0.004)
0.0540.054***0.013 (0.058)(0.014)(0.008)
0.062*0.054***0.013*** (0.034)(0.009)(0.005)
0.0490.034*0.007 (0.060)(0.019)(0.008)
0.058*0.035***0.017*** (0.031)(0.012)(0.005)
0.0760.040**0.016* (0.052)(0.016)(0.009)
0.085**0.041***0.016*** (0.034)(0.008)(0.005) N 294294294
Notes: Thistableshowstheresultsfromestimatingthedifference-in-differenceeffectandthe imputedtreatmenteffect-seeAppendix C.2 fordetails.InPanelA,thesyntheticcontrolis createdseparatelyforeachoutcome(trade, ETRK , ETRL)andeachliberalizationcountryevent.InPanelB,thesyntheticcontroliscreatedforallthreeoutcomesjointlyforeachcountryevent.InPanelC,thedonorpoolforeachcountry-eventexcludesthe5majorimportand exporttradingpartnersofthecountry,measuredintermsoftotalvolumeoftradeintheyear immediatelyprecedingliberalization.InPanelD,thedonorpoolexcludesallcountriesthat havealreadyliberalizedbythetimeoftheevent (basedonWacziarg&Welch, 2008). InPanel E,thedonorpoolisrestrictedtocountriesinthesameregion.InPanelF,thedonorpoolisall lowandmiddle-incomecountries(LMICs),basedontheWorldBankincomeclassificationin 2018.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01. 4
Trade ETRK ETRL (1) (2) (3)
WeakInstrumentsF-statistic
TableA2:First-StageandReducedFormRegressions
Sample
Developing
Developingand countriesonly developedcountries
Notes: Thisregressiontableshowsthefirststageandthereducedformresults.Thesampleisdevelopingcountries(N =49160)incols.(1)-(3),and developinganddevelopedcountries(N =6489)incolumns(4)-(7).Tradeisexportsandimportsdividedbynetdomesticproduct.Column(1) correspondstothefirst-stageindevelopingcountries,usedinTables 1-2-3.Columns(4)-(5)correspondtothefirst-stageinthefullsample,which estimatesheterogeneouseffectsbydevelopmentlevel,andwhichisusedinTable A7.Wereportseveral 1st-stagestatistics:theF-statisticofexcluded instruments;theSanderson-WindmeijermultivariateF-testofexcludedinstruments;and,theKleibergen-PaapF-statistic.Whenthereisonlyone endogenousregressor(column1),thesethreeF-statisticsareequivalent.Noteincolumns(4)-(5)thatthereisonlyoneKleibergen-PaapF-statistic, whichevaluatestheoverallstrengthofthefirst-stage,eventhoughtherearetwofirst-stageregressions.Columns(2)-(3)and(6)-(7)reportthereduced formregressionsoftheinstrumentsontheeffectivetaxratesforcapital, ETRK ,andlabor, ETRL.Developing(developed)countriesarelowand middle-incomecountries(high-incomecountries)accordingtotheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01.Standard errorsinparenthesesareclusteredatthecountrylevel.
1st-stageReducedform 1st-stage Reducedform Trade ETRK ETRL TradeTrade∗1(High-inc.) ETRK ETRL (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Zgravity 0.069***0.010***0.003*** 0.014 0.040*** 0.014*0.002 (0.010)(0.002)(0.001) (0.019) (0.014) (0.008)(0.004) Zoil distance -0.116***-0.033***-0.020** -0.088*** -0.021 -0.022***-0.015*** (0.036)(0.009)(0.005) (0.015) (0.014) (0.007)(0.003)
st-stageF-statistic 24.59 22.82 11.75
st
41.93 26.60
1st-stageKleibergen-Paap 24.59 15.34
1
1
-stageSanderson-Windmeijer24.59
F-statistic
N 4916 49164916 6489 6489 64896489
TableA3:TradeImpactsonEffectiveTaxRatesinDifferentSamples
Samplechangesrelatedto
Samplechangesrelatedto Samplechangesrelatedto taxrevenuedata SystemNationalAccountsdata time-periodsandbalancedness
PanelA: ETR
PanelB: ETR
Modificationstobench-RemoveinterpolatedOnlyuseHAOnlyuseICTDOnlyuseOECDRemovecompositeOnlyuse Onlyuse Onlyuse OnlyuseFullybalanced marksampleinTable1
Notes: Thistablepresentsresultsfromestimatingtheeffectoftradeoneffectivetaxratesindifferentsamplesacrossdevelopingcountries.The estimationisidenticaltothebenchmarkIVmodelincolumn(2)ofTable 1;acrosscolumns,thesamplediffersfromthatbenchmarksample. Developingcountriesarelowandmiddle-incomecountriesaccordingtotheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.Theoutcomeistheeffective taxrateoncapital, ETRK ,inPanelAandtheeffectivetaxrateonlabor, ETRL,inPanelB.Tradeismeasuredasthesumofexportsandimports dividedbynetdomesticproduct(NDP).Inthefirstfourcolumns,sample-changesaremadetothetaxrevenuedata:interpolatedvaluesaredropped incolumn1;theonlydata-sourceishistoricalarchives(HA)incolumn2;theonlydata-sourceisICTDincolumn3;theonlydata-sourceisOECD incolumn4.Inthenextthreecolumns,sample-changesaremadetothesystemofnationalaccounts(SNA)data:incolumn(5),thecompositeSNA valuesareremoved;incolumn(6),onlydatafromSNA1968areused;incolumn(7),onlydatafromSNA2008areused.Inthefinalthreecolumns, sample-changesaremaderegardingbalancedness:incolumn(8),thequasi-panelbetween1965and1993isused;incolumn(9),thequasi-panel between1994and2018isused;incolumn(10),thefullybalancedpanelofcountriesbetween1965and2018isused.Formoredetailsonthe interpolations,imputationsanddata-sources,seeSection 3 andAppendix B.
(1)
(3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
(2)
Trade 0.157*** 0.133*** 0.215** 0.206*** 0.162** 0.138** 0.183*** 0.110* 0.205** 0.150*** (0.054) (0.049) (0.098) (0.068) (0.064) (0.062) (0.052) (0.060) (0.098) (0.052)
K
Trade 0.051*** 0.029*** 0.093* 0.028 0.039** 0.037* 0.041** 0.041** 0.056** 0.067*** (0.017) (0.011) (0.049) (0.022) (0.018) (0.018) (0.020) (0.015) (0.021) (0.020)
L
taxrevenue taxdata taxdata taxdata SNAdata SNA1968dataSNA2008datapre-1994yearspost-1994yearspanel1965-2018 N 4563 2268 1004 1644 2752 983 1769 2122 2794 2879
TableA4:RobustnessofResultsforTotalTaxesandMechanisms
PanelA:Totaltaxes(%ofNDP)
PanelB:CITrate(first-diff.)
1
PanelC: log(1+CITrate)
1
PanelD:Corp.income(%ofNDP)
PanelE:Mixedincome(%ofNDP)
PanelF:CapitalshareofNDP
PanelG:Corp. ETR
ModificationstoIV
NDPInclude IncludeWinsorizeOnlyuseOnlyuse inPanelBofTable 3 weightscountry-year 1(oil-rich)*yeartrade Zgravity ZOil Dist controlsfixedeffectsat5%-95%instrumentinstrument
Notes: Thistablepresentsrobustnesschecksfortrade’simpactsonseveraloutcomesindevelopingcountries.Developingcountriesarelowandmiddle-incomecountriesaccordingtotheWorldBankincome classificationin2018.Tradeisthesumofexportsandimportsdividedbynetdomesticproduct(NDP).The outcomediffersacrosspanels,andthespecificationdiffersacrosscolumns:eachcellisthecoefficientfroma separateIVregression.Wereportthe 1st-stageKleibergen-PaapF-statisticseparatelyforeachIVregression. PanelAistotaltaxesasa%ofNDP.PanelBisthefirst-differencedcorporateincometax(CIT)rate.PanelC isthepercentchangefromlogof (1+ CITrate).PanelDisthecorporateincomeshareofNDP.PanelEis themixedincomeshareofNDP.PanelFisthecapitalshareofNDP.PanelGistheaverageeffectivetaxrate oncorporateprofits.ThedifferentspecificationsacrosscolumnsarethesameasinTable 1 -pleasereferto thattableformoredetails.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01.Standarderrorsinparenthesesareclusteredatthe countrylevel.
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Trade 0.105*0.092** 0.097*** 0.106***0.099***0.170** (0.060)(0.039) (0.031) (0.032)(0.032)(0.073) 1st stageK-PF-stat 34.51 14.14 23.09 34.84 45.17 10.75 N 4916 3938 4916 4916 4916 4916
Trade 0.004 -0.007 -0.011* -0.013*-0.012*-0.030* (0.011)(0.009) (0.006) (0.007)(0.007)(0.016)
st stageK-PF-stat 34.51 14.14 23.24 34.84 45.13 10.75 N 4916 3938 4916 4916 4916 4916
Trade -0.009*-0.006 -0.009* -0.010*-0.009*-0.026* (0.005)(0.007) (0.005) (0.005)(0.005)(0.014)
st
34.51 14.14 23.24 34.84 45.13 10.75 N 4916 3938 4916 4916 4916 4916
stageK-PF-stat
Trade 0.188***0.197*** 0.173*** 0.189***0.179***0.211** (0.051)(0.047) (0.044) (0.046)(0.045)(0.104)
st stageK-PF-stat 34.51 14.14 23.24 34.84 45.13 10.75 N 4916 3938 4916 4916 4916 4916
1
Trade -0.203***-0.162*** -0.184***-0.194***-0.185***-0.137 (0.053)(0.040) (0.040) (0.038)(0.041)(0.112)
st stageK-PF-stat 34.51 14.14 23.24 34.84 45.13 10.75 N 4916 3938 4916 4916 4916 4916
1
Trade 0.102*0.112** 0.145*** 0.158***0.152***0.107** (0.052)(0.044) (0.032) (0.033)(0.035)(0.052)
34.51 14.14 23.24 34.84 45.13 10.75 N 4916 3938 4916 4916 4916 4916
1st stageK-PF-stat
Trade 0.238* 0.189* 0.148** 0.172**0.160**0.385** (0.156)(0.096) (0.074) (0.077)(0.076)(0.183)
st stageK-PF-stat 34.51 14.14 23.24 34.84 45.13 10.75 N 4916 3938 4916 4916 4916 4916
K
1
7
TableA5:ImpactsofTradeinLMICs,HeterogeneitybyEnforcementPolicy
PanelA:LargeTaxpayerUnit
Trade
Trade∗1(LTU)
0.116*0.0130.171*** 0.117* (0.066)(0.029)(0.057) (0.068)
0.0890.084** 0.019 0.113 (0.077)(0.040)(0.051) (0.131)
Impliedcoef.for 0.205***0.098***0.190*** 0.230** TradewithLTU (0.062)(0.029)(0.042) (0.097)
PanelB:Customs-TaxIntegration
Trade
Trade∗1(Customs-Tax)
0.121*0.0180.172*** 0.160* (0.064)(0.038)(0.052) (0.094)
0.2080.198* 0.046 0.183 (0.185)(0.109)(0.112) (0.249)
Impliedcoef.for 0.330**0.217**0.219** 0.344*
TradewithCustoms-Tax (0.153)(0.090)(0.089) (0.202)
PanelC:Value-AddedTax
Trade
Trade∗1(VAT)
0.116**0.0150.171*** 0.156* (0.058)(0.025)(0.054) (0.089)
0.1010.096** 0.022 0.085 (0.081)(0.043)(0.054) (0.115)
Impliedcoef.for 0.218***0.111***0.194*** 0.241*** TradewithVAT (0.064)(0.032)(0.045) (0.087)
PanelD:InternationalAccountingStandards
Trade
Trade∗1(IAS)
Impliedcoef.for
0.132**0.0230.160*** 0.183** (0.054)(0.022)(0.051) (0.088)
0.1220.111** 0.017 0.124 (0.087)(0.042)(0.055) (0.135)
0.255**0.134***0.177*** 0.307*** TradewithIAS (0.077)(0.036)(0.050) (0.110) N 49164916 4916 4916
Notes: ThistableestimatesheterogeneousIVeffectsoftradeindevelopingcountries(lowandmiddleincomecountriesaccordingtotheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018).Tradeisthesumofexports andimportsdividedbynetdomesticproduct(NDP).Outcomesdifferacrosscolumns:column(1)isthe effectivetaxrateoncapital, ETRK ;column(2)istheeffectivetaxrateonlabor, ETRL;column(3)isthe corporateincomeshareofNDP;column(4)istheaverageeffectivetaxrateoncorporateprofits.Weestimate
where 1(A)ct isanindicatorvariablewhichtakesavalueof1inallyearsaftertheadministrativereformhas beenimplemented.Weinstrumentfor tradect and tradect 1(A)ct usingthetwoinstruments(Section 5.2). Thecoefficienton 1(A)ct isalsoestimated,butisnotreportedinthetable.InPanelA,theadministrative reformistheexistenceofalargetaxpayerunit(LTU);thisvariableiscodedbasedontheUSAID’s’Collecting TaxesDatabase’ (websitelink) andcountry-sources.InPanelB,theadministrativereformistheintegration ofthecustomsauthorityandthedomestictaxauthorityinasinglerevenueagency;thisvariableiscoded basedonUSAID’s’CollectingTaxesDatabase’ (websitelink),theOECDTaxAdministrationComparative Series (websitelink),andcountry-sources.InPanelC,theadministrativereformistheimplementationofa value-addedtax(VAT);thisvariableiscodedbasedonKeenandLockwood(2010)andcountry-sources.In PanelD,theadministrativereformistheadoptionofinternationalaccountingstandards(IAS);thisvariable iscodedbasedontheIAScountry-profiles (websitelink).Atthebottomofeachcolumnandpanel,we reporttheimpliedcoefficientandestimatedstandarderrorbasedonthelinearcombinationofthe tradect and tradect 1(A)ct coefficients.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01.Standarderrorsinparenthesesareclustered atthecountrylevel.
ETR
ETRL Corp.incomeCorp. ETRK
K
(1) (2) (3) (4)
yct = µ tradect + κ tradect 1(A)ct + θ 1(A)ct + πc + πt + ϵct
8
PanelA:ExcludingTrade-InducedTariffRevenueLoss Periods(basedonCageandGadenne,2018)
PanelB:ExcludingPeriodsofIndirectTaxRevenueLoss
PanelC:ExcludingPeriodsofTotalTaxRevenueLoss
Notes: ThisIVspecificationisthesameascolumn(2)inTable 1,butmodificationsaremadetothesample ofdevelopingcountries.InPanelA,weexcludeallcountry-yearobservationswhichbelongtoanepisode oftraderevenueloss,basedon CagéandGadenne(2018). Inadatasetof130countriesbetween1792and 2006,theauthorsdefinesuchanepisodebyafallintradetaxrevenuesasapercentageofGDPofatleast 1percentagepointfromalocalyearlymaximumtothenextlocalyearlyminimumthatisaccompanied byanon-decreaseinthevolumeofimportsasashareofGDP.InPanelsBandC,weconsideralternative definitionsofrevenuelossperiods.InPanelB,wecalculatethewithin-countryyearlychangeinindirect taxescollectedasashareofnetdomesticproduct(NDP),andtakethethree-yearmovingaverage.Wethen createtercilesofthisvariable,separatelyforeachcountry.Wedefineperiodsofindirecttaxrevenueloss tobetheobservationswhichlieinthebottomtercileofthisdistribution,andexcludethesecountry-year observationsfromthesample.InPanelC,wecalculatethesamerevenue-lossvariable,butbasedonchanges intotaltaxescollectedratherthanindirecttaxescollected.Tradeisthesumofexportsandimportsdivided byNDP.Theoutcomediffersacrosscolumns:column(1)istheeffectivetaxrateoncapital, ETRK ;column (2)istheeffectivetaxrateonlabor, ETRL;column(3)isthecorporateincomeshareofNDP;column(4)isthe averageeffectivetaxrateoncorporateprofits.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01.Standarderrorsinparentheses areclusteredatthecountrylevel.
TableA6:ImpactsofTradeOutsideofPeriodsofTaxRevenueLoss ETRK ETRL Corp.incomeCorp. ETRK (1) (2) (3) (4)
Trade 0.151***0.047**0.183*** 0.203** (0.056)(0.020)(0.045) (0.089) N 39543954 3954 3954
Trade 0.189***0.053***0.197*** 0.225*** (0.051)(0.016)(0.044) (0.083) N 30113011 3011 3011
Trade 0.174***0.048***0.174*** 0.203** (0.050)(0.015)(0.042) (0.081) N 30163016 3016 3016
9
TableA7:HeterogeneousImpactsofTradebyDevelopmentLevel
Trade∗1(High-inc.)-0.2930.014-0.064*-0.502**0.340**-0.312***-0.214**-0.289-0.197**-0.239** (0.215)(0.110)(0.033)(0.218)(0.138)(0.099)(0.114)(0.320)(0.086)(0.110)
Impliedcoef.for -0.0400.130-0.084***-0.2230.160-0.135*-0.1580.156-0.066-0.081
TradeinHigh-inc.(0.127)(0.095)(0.020)(0.154)(0.135)(0.072)(0.117)(0.173)(0.056)(0.081)
1st-stageKleibergen-15.3415.3415.3415.3415.3415.3415.3415.3415.3415.34 PappF-statistic
Notes: ThistablepresentsIVresultsfromestimatingtheeffectsoftradeon ETR andmechanismoutcomesinthefullsampleofdevelopingand developedcountries.Tradeismeasuredasthesumofexportsandimportsdividedbynetdomesticproduct(NDP).WerunthefollowingIV regression: yct = µ · tradect + κ · tradect · 1(HighIncome
Thefirst-stageregressionisreportedinTable A2.Atthebottomof eachcolumn,wereporttheimpliedcoefficientandestimatedstandarderrorbasedonthelinearcombinationofthe Trade andthe Trade ∗ 1(Highinc.) coefficients.High-incomeisbasedontheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.Wealsoreportthe 1st-stageKleibergen-PaapF-statistic. Eachcolumnisadifferentoutcome:column(1)istheeffectivetaxrateoncapital;column(2)istheeffectivetaxrateonlabor;column(3)isthe first-differencedstatutorycorporateincometaxrate;column(4)isthecorporateincomeshareofnetdomesticproduct,wherecorporateincomeis thesumofcorporateprofitsandcorporateemployeecompensation;column(5)isthemixedincomeshareofnetdomesticproduct;column(6)isthe corporateprofitshareofnetdomesticproduct;column(7)istheemployeecompensationshareofnetdomesticproduct;column(8)istheaverage effectivetaxrateoncorporateprofits;column(9)isthecapitalshareofnetdomesticproduct;column(10)isthecapitalshareofcorporateincome. Formoredetailsonoutcomes,seeSection 3.1 andSection 6.2.Formoredetailsontheinstrumentalvariables,seeSection 5.2.*p<0.10**p<0.05*** p<0.01.Standarderrorsinparenthesesareclusteredatthecountrylevel.
ETRK ETRL Firstdiff. CITRate Corp. Totl. Income Mixed Income Corp. Profits Employee Comp. Corp. ETRK Natl. KShare Corp. KShare (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)(10)
(0.127)(0.051)(0.021)(0.119)(0.106)(0.049)(0.104)(0.193)(0.054)(0.064)
Trade 0.253**0.116**-0.0200.279**-0.183*0.176***0.0560.445**0.131**0.158**
N 648964896489 64896489 6489 6489 648964896489
c +Θ · Xct + πc + πt + ϵct
)
AppendixBData&ConstructionofEffectiveTaxRates
Thisappendixsectionprovidesanoverviewofthedatasourcesusedtocreateourtaxrevenueandnationalincomeseries(Section B.1).Additionally,wediscussthemethodology tomeasureeffectivetaxrates(Section B.2).
B.1Datasources
Taxrevenuedata Ourtaxrevenuedatadrawsfromthreekeysources:
(i) OECDGovernmentRevenueStatistics (websitelink):OECDrevenuestatisticstake precedenceinourdatahierarchyasitcontainsalltypesoftaxrevenuesalreadyarranged intheOECDtaxonomyoftaxes.WhileitcoversallOECDcountries,itonlycoversa subsetofdevelopingcountrieswhichtypicallystartintheearly2000s.
(ii) ICTDGovernmentRevenueDataset (websitelink):ICTDdatacoversmanydevelopingcountries,butonlybeginsinthe1980s.ICTDattimesdoesnotseparateincome taxesintopersonalvs.corporatetaxesandoftendoesnotcontainsocialsecuritycontributions.
(iii) Archivaldata:Themainarchivaldatacollectioncorrespondstothedigitizationofthe GovernmentDocumentssectionintheLamontLibraryatHarvardUniversity (website link).Foreachcountry,wescanned,tabulatedandharmonizedofficialdatafrom thepublicbudgetandnationalstatisticalyearbooks,toretrieveofficialtaxrevenue statistics.The supplementaryappendix liststhemainhistoricaldocumentsusedin eachcountry’stime-series.Inthecasewherethedocumentisastatisticalyearbook,the initiallistedsourceisalwaysareportproducedbythefinanceministryorthenational taxauthority.Tocomplementhard-copyarchivaldata,weretrievedcountries’online reports,usuallypublishedbytheirnationalstatisticalofficeorfinanceministry.Wealso usedcomplementarysources,includingofflinearchivalGovernmentFinanceStatistics datafromtheIMFwhichcoverstheperiod1972-1989.Forsocialsecuritycontributions, wereliedontwoadditionalsources:the‘D61’statisticonsocialcontributionsin thehouseholdsectorinSNA-1968andSNA-2008,anddatafrom Fisunoglu,Kang, Arbetman-Rabinowitz,andKugler(2011).
Toincreasethecredibilityofthetaxrevenueseriesbasedonnewlydigitizedhistorical documents,webaseourapproachonthefollowingfourguidingrules:
1. Weseektobuildlongtime-seriesfromthearchivalrecordsinordertooverlapwith pre-existingsources(OECD,ICTD,IMF).Weusetheoverlappingyearstoinspectthat thedifferentsourcesprovidesimilarestimatesoftheoveralllevelsoftaxescollectedand toverifythattheyreportthesamesetoftaxesinplace.Ifdiscrepanciesexistwhendata sourcesoverlap,weinspecttheaccuracyofeachsourcewithadditionalinformation. Forthisreason,switchesindata-sourcerarelyleadtoasignificantchangeintrend.
2. Inhistoricaltime-periodswherenooverlapexistswithpre-existingsources,wefind academicpublicationsandpolicyreportstocomparetheestimatedoveralllevelsof
11
tax/GDP.Whendiscrepanciesexist,weinvestigateitscauses(e.g.inclusionofnon-tax revenues,differencesinestimatedGDPnumbers).
3. Wetakenoteofinstanceswheretheoveralltaxtake,orindividualtaxtypes,seesudden andlargechanges.Weuseadditionalsourcestotrytodeterminetheproximatecauses astheyrelatetopolicychanges,politicaltransitionsoreconomicshocks.Weflagcases wherewecannotfindtheproximatecauseorwherethepoliticaloreconomicevents induceverysignificantvolatilityinthetime-series.
4. Weaimtobeconservativeinourinclusionofcountriesandtime-periods.Specifically, weexcludecountriesintime-periodswheredataexistsbutwheresignificantconcerns remainaboutitsreliability(andwhereitprovesdifficulttofindcorroboratingsources). Theseinstancesareofteninperiodsofsignificantpoliticaloreconomicchange.For example,weexcludeAfghanistaninthelate1970sandearly1980s;Cambodiainthe late1980sandearly1990s;DominicanRepublicintheearly1960s;and,Namibiain 1990.
The supplementaryappendix containsatablewhichsummarizesourdecisionsasthey relatetothesefourguidingrulesineachcountryinoursample.Thetableemphasizesthe uncertaintythatexistsforspecificcountriesinspecifictimeperiodsandweflaginstances whereweassessthedatatobeworthyofinclusionbutwhereitshouldstillbeinterpreted withcautionandadditionalinvestigationswouldbehelpful.Weconfirmthatnoneofour mainresultschangeifweexcludetheseflaggedinstances.Moreover,the supplementary appendix providescase-studieswithadditionaldetailsonourdecisionsanddirectlinks totheinitialhistoricaldocumentsforeachcountry.Thecasestudiesarecurrentlylimited to67countriesbutwillultimatelycovertheentiresample.63
Equippedwiththehistoricaltimeseries,wehavetoconstructlong-runpanelsacross sources.Below,weoutlinetheinstructionsusedtoharmonizeacrosssourcesandto improvedataqualityforthemeasurementofeachtypeoftax.Weflaginstanceswherewe considertheseriestobelegitimate,butwhereharmonizationprovedmorechallenging duetocoincidingeconomicorpoliticalchanges.Foreachcountry,themaindecisions relatedtoharmonizationanddata-qualityareprovidedinthe supplementaryappendix
1. WefirstrelyonOECDdatawheneveritexists.Archivaldataisinitiallysecondin priority,butwerevisethisbasedonwhetherICTDdataprovidesalongtimeseriesand separatespersonalfromcorporateincometaxes.WealsostudyifICTDhasthebetter matchinoverlappingtime-periodswithOECDdata.Whenpossible,weaimtouseno morethantwodatasourcespercountry.
2. Weexcludecountry-yearsforcommunist/commandeconomies.Thisimpliesthatour panelsizejumpsin1994,includingwhenChinaandRussiafirstappear.Theyear1994 isafewyearsremovedfromthedissolutionoftheSovietUnionbut,asdiscussedbelow, arguablycorrespondstoChina’sestablishmentofamoderntaxsystem (WorldBank, 2008).
63Weinvitecommentsfromresearcherstoimprovetheaccuracyoftheseriesaswebuildthecasestudies andexpandthedatatorecentyears.
12
3. WhennoneofthedatasourcesseparatePITfromCIT,weuseacademicsourcesand taxlegislationtoassignvalues.
4. Toguardagainstomittingsignificantvaluesofdecentralizedtaxrevenues,weuse theOECDdatabaseonsubnationalgovernmentfinance(link)tofindthecountries withsignificantstateandlocaltaxes,andweattempttocollectfurtherdataforthese countriesifnecessary.
5. Welinearlyinterpolatedatawhenagiventaxtypeismissing,butfornomorethan 4yearsinatime-seriesandwithoutextrapolation.Wecheckforsignificantsocioeconomicchangesthatcouldcastdoubtonthecontinuityofthetaxrevenueseriesand donotinterpolateinsuchyears.
6. Weonlyuseactualamountsoftaxescollected,anddonotrelyonestimatedvalues.
China’sestablishmentofamoderntaxsystemin1994 Inourbenchmarksetting,weonlyincludeformerlycommunisteconomiesinto ourdatastartingin1994.GivenChina’sweightintheglobaleconomy,itisworth reviewingthereasonforthatchoice.ThetaxrevenuedataforChinacoversmost ofoursampleperiodalthoughitsqualityimprovesmarkedlyinthe1980s.Official statisticsareavailableonline: linkhere
Priortothe1980s,Chinahadacommandeconomymodelof‘profitdelivery,’in whichthestatedirectlyreceivedtherevenuesofprofitableSOEs,andsubsidized unprofitableones.AcorporateincometaxfirstappearsinChinain1983-84,butthe majorityofthebasecontinuestobestate-ownedenterprises.In1985,thetaxsystem wasfurtherreformedintoa‘fiscalcontracting’systemwherebyfirmsnegotiateda fixedlump-sumpayment(regardlessofeconomicoutcomes),whichcannotbesplit intolaborversuscapitaltaxes(norintoconsumptiontaxes).Wethereforeexclude the‘pseudo’-CITrevenuedatingfrom1985through1993.
Rather,weconsiderthatChina’smoderntaxsystembeganin1994.The World Bank(2008) showsthat,in1994,Chinaestablishedforthefirsttimeacentraltax administration;reformedthe‘fiscalcontracting’system;unifiedthePIT;createda VAT;andreduced‘extrabudgetary’(non-tax)revenues.Thusfrom1994onward wecancategorizetaxrevenuepreciselybytype,assignthemtocapitalorlabor, andestimateour ETRs.
Nationalaccountsdata Tocomputefactorincomesofnetdomesticproduct,wecombine twomaindatasetsfromtheUnitedNationsStatisticsDivision.Thefirstisthe2008System ofNationalAccounts(SNA)onlinedatarepository.Thesecondisthe1968SNAarchival material.The2008and1968SNAsinitiallyhavedifferentreportingclassifications;tothe bestofourknowledge,ourprojectisthefirsttoharmonizenationalaccountsacrossthese twosources.
Toestimatecapitalandlaborfactorincomesrequiresinformationonthe4mainsubcomponentsthatmakeupnetdomesticproduct(seeequation 3).However,insome
13
country-yearswherewehaveinformationondomesticproductfromanSNAdataset,there maynotbedataonallfoursub-componentsatthesametime.Thisismorefrequently thecaseforthe1968SNAthanforthe2008SNAanditismostfrequentformixed income(OSPUE ).Inthesecases,wefirstattempttorecoverthevalueofthemissing componentusingdatafromtheotherSNAdatasetandnationalaccountingidentities withnon-missingvaluesforothercomponentswithinthesamecountry-year.Forthe remainingcasesafterapplyingthisprocess,weimputevaluesforthecomponent.Allof theregressionsinSections 5-6 includedummyvariablesforthesecompositecases;our mainresultsalsoholdwithouttheimputedvalues(Table A3).Fortheimputation,we followtheprocedurefrom Blanchetetal.(2021). TheWorldInequalityDatabaseuses thisproceduretoimputeconsumptionoffixedcapital(depreciation)whenitismissing incountries’series.Forexample,applyingthisprocedureinoursettingmeansthatwe model OSPUE asafunctionoflognationalincomepercapita,afixedcountrycharacteristic, andanAR(1)persistenceterm.
Table B1 summarizesthenationalaccountscoverageinourdataset.The’Complete SNA2008’rowreferstocountry-yearswhereallcomponentsofnetdomesticproductare extractedfromthe2008SNA;similarlyforthe’CompleteSNA1968’row.The’Composite’ rowcountsinstanceswhereonecomponent(ormore)ofnetdomesticproductisinitially missingfromanSNAdatasetandisretrievedfromtheotherSNAdataset,iscalculated viaaccountingidentities,orisimputed.
PanelA:Taxrevenuedata
PanelB:Factorincomedata
Notes: SeeSection B.1 formoredetailsonthedata-sourcesfortaxrevenueandfactorincome.
Country-yearobs.%
TableB1:MainDataSources
OECD 287542.3% Archives 267839.4% ICTD 124618.3% N 6799100%
CompleteSNA2008245536.1% CompleteSNA1968136020.0% Composite 298443.9% N 6799100%
14
B.2Constructionof ETR
Bycombiningdataondisaggregatedtaxrevenuesandnationalincomecomponents,we constructeffectivetaxratesoncapitalandlabor(equations 1 and 2 inSection 3.1).Herewe providefurtherdetailsonthedefinitionsof ETR.Computing ETRL and ETRK requires thefollowinginformationforcountry c inyear t:
Foreachtypeoftax j,thereisa λj,ct allocationofthetaxtolaborwhichmayvaryby country-year(and 1 λj,ct istheallocationtocapital).Theallocationforeachtypeoftax isdescribedinTable B2,wherethetypesoftaxesfollowtheOECDclassification.Inour benchmarkassignment,theseallocationsaretime-andcountry-invariantforalltypesof taxes,exceptforpersonalincometaxes(λPIT,ct)whichwediscussindetailbelow.Further, inourbenchmarkassumption,weassumethatthelaborshareofmixedincome, ϕct,is fixedat75%inallcountry-years(ϕct =0 75).Inrobustnesschecks,welet ϕct varyatthe country-level,basedon ILO(2019), oratthecountry-yearlevelbyusingthelaborshare inthecorporatesector.Inourbenchmarkassignment,replacingtheinvariantparameters withtheirfixednumericalvalues,wethereforehave:
ETRL,ct = TL,ct YL,ct = λPIT,ct T1100,ct + T2000,ct CEct +0.75 · OSPUE,ct
ETRK,ct = TK,ct YK,ct = (1 λPIT,ct) ·
TheparametervaluesaredescribedinTable B2,bothforthetaxrevenuenumerator andthenationalincomedenominator.Wenowprovidemoredetailson λPIT and ϕ Laborshareofpersonalincometaxes: λPIT AsdiscussedinSection 3.1,thelevelof personalincometax(PIT)thatderivesfromcapitalversuslaborincomeisrarelydirectly observed.64 Thus,withinPIT,animportantparameteristheshareofrevenueassigned tolabor,denoted λPIT .IntheUnitedStates, Pikettyetal.(2018) findthatapproximately 85%ofPITrevenueisfromlaborand15%fromcapital.Toconstructcountry-yearspecific λPIT,ct,westartfromtheUSbenchmark(λPIT =85%)andmaketwoadjustments:
(a) First,thelocationofthePITexemptionthresholdintheincomedistributionimpacts λPIT ,sincethecapitalincomeshareishigherforricherindividuals.WeretrievePIT exemptionthresholdsfrom Jensen(2022). WeassumecountrieswithahigherPIT exemptionthresholdhaveahigher λPIT .SincetheUShasalowexemptionthreshold
64PITrevenuefromcapitalincomeincludestaxesondividendsandcapitalgainsandonthecapitalshareof self-employmentincome.OECDrevenuedataoccasionallyreportstaxrevenuefromcapitalgains,which wasonaverage4%ofPITintheperiod2010-2018(7.5%intheUS).
ETRL,ct
TL,ct YL,ct
λPIT,ct · T1100,ct + λsocsec,ct · T2000,ct CEct + ϕct OSPUE,ct ETR
TK,ct
K,ct
(1 λPIT,ct) T1100,ct +(1 λCIT,ct) T1200,ct +(1 λassets,ct) T4000,ct (1 ϕct) · OSPUE,ct + OSCORP,ct + OSHH,ct
=
=
K,ct =
Y
=
T1100,ct + T1200,ct + T4000,ct 0 25 OSPUE,ct + OSCORP,ct + OSHH,ct
15
with λPIT =85%,weassign85%ofPITtolaborincountrieswherethePITatleast halfoftheworkforce(mainlyhigh-incomecountries).ForcountrieswherethePIT covers1%orlessoftheworkforce(lowest-incomecountries),weassignamaximum PITcapitalshareof30%.ForPITthresholdswithacoveragebetween1%to50%of theworkforce,welinearlyassign λPIT between70%and85%.
(b) Second,weassumethatcountrieswhereadualPITsystemisinplacehavealarger λPIT .DualPITsystemssetcapitalincometaxationtoalower—oftenflat—rate,while laborincomeistaxedwithprogressivemarginaltaxrates.Wecomputethemeasure ofthepercentdifferencebetweenthetaxrateondividendsandthetopmarginaltax rateonlaborincome.Dataondividendvswageincometaxratesaretakenfrom OECDRevenueStatisticsandcountry-specifictaxcodedocuments.Sinceweonly havedividendrates,weassumethat50%ofcapitalincomeinPITbenefitsfromthe lowerrate(e.g.,capitalgainsmightnotbenefit).Forthis50%,wemultiply λPIT by thepercentdifferenceindividendversustopmarginaltaxrates.
Laborshareofmixedincome: ϕ Section 3.1 notedthedifficultyofestimatingthelabor shareofmixedincome(unincorporatedenterprises).Weassumeabenchmarkmeasureof ϕ =75%.Theimpliedcapitalshareislowerthanthe30%usedinDistributionalNational Accountsguidelines (Blanchetetal., 2021). However,sincetheglobalaveragecorporate capitalshareis27%,assumingthatthecapitalshareofunincorporatedenterprisesis slightlylowerappearsreasonable (seeGuerriero, 2019).
Weimplementtworobustnesschecks.First,wesetthelaborshareofmixedincomeequaltothatofthecorporatesectoratthecountry-yearlevel;specifically, ϕct = CEct CEct+OSCORP,ct .Thisprocedurefollows Gollin(2002).
Second,weimplementthe ILO(2019) methodwhichreliesonharmonizedhousehold surveysandlaborforcesurveysindevelopingcountriesbetween2004and2017.Estimationoftherelativelaborincomeofself-employedisbasedontheobservablecharacteristics ofthoseworkersandtheircomparisonwithemployees.Relevantvariables,includingindustry,occupation,educationlevelandage,areusedinaregressiontouncoverthe determinantsoflaborincomeofemployees.Giventheestimatedrelationshipbetween employeelaborincomeandtheexplanatoryvariables,laborincomeisextrapolatedto self-employed,generatingacoefficientofrelativeearningstoemployees,denoted γq.The methodestimatesaseparate γq fordifferentgroups q ofself-employed:self-employed workers;own-accountworkers;and,contributingfamilymembers.Acorrectionprocedureisimplementedtoreducethebiasfromselectionintoself-employment.Totallabor incomeinagivencountry-yearisthendeterminedas Y ILO L = CE + q wemp · γq · bq,where CE isthetotalcompensationofemployeesinSNA, wemp istheaverageemployeewage (whichrelates CE tothetotalemployeeworkforce), bq isself-employedgroup q’scountin theworkforce,and γq isthe q-specificearningscoefficientrelativetotheaverageemployee wage.Equippedwiththe Y ILO L estimate,wecalculatethe‘implicit’labormixedincome (OSPUEL)asthedifferencebetween Y ILO L andthevalueofcompensationforemployees CE observedinthenationalaccounts.Then,wecomputethemixedincomeshare allocatedtolabor.Specifically, ϕILO iscomputedasfollows: ϕILO = (Y ILO L CE) OSPUE = OSPUEILO L OSPUE
16
Finally,wecomputetheaverage ϕILO foreachcountryduring2004-2017andassignthis valuetoallyears.Weassignacountry-specificbuttime-invariantvaluefortworeasons. First,priorto2004,theILOlackstherequireddatatocompute Y ILO L onacountry-year basis.Second,whenmeasuredatthecountry-yearlevelduringthe2004-2017period, ϕILO varieslittlewithincountryacrossyears.Assigningacountry-specificbuttime-invariant mixedincomefactorsharemaythereforebereasonable.
Themainchallengeisthattheestimationframeworkfor γq isnotdisciplinedbythe country’sactualvaluesinSNA.Inparticular,nothingprevents q wemp γq bq >OSPUE -suchthatestimatedlabormixedincomeislargerthantheSNAactuallyobservedentire mixedincome.Thiswould,implausibly,implythat ϕILO > 100%.Toremedythisconcern, wewinsorize ϕILO at100%.Incaseswhere γq and bq arenotfrom ILO(2019), wealso winsorize ϕILO frombelowwiththelowestobservedcountryvaluein ILO(2019), whichis 36%.Whilethe ILO(2019) methodgeneratesimportantcountry-levelvariation,theglobal averagevaluefor ϕILO,at80%,doesnotdiffermuchfromourbenchmarkvalue ϕ =75%.
MixedincomeinChinaandtheUS Wemakemixed-incomeadjustmenttothebenchmarkseriesforChinaandtheUnitedStates.ForChina, Piketty,Yang,andZucman(2019) (PYZ)showthatChinesenationalaccountssystematicallyunderestimatemixedincome andoverestimateotherfactorincomes:forexample,theincomeofself-employedagriculturalworkersisattributedtoemployeecompensationintheSNA2008dataandnotto mixedincome(asinothercountries).WebaseourmixedincomeseriesonPYZ.
FollowingPYZ,wedefinemixedincomeasthesumoftheincomeattributedtoselfemployedworkersfromagricultureandindividualbusinesses.PYZcoverstheperiod 1992-2014.Foryearsbeforeandafter,weextendtheseriesasfollows:
(a) Foragriculture,relevantdataisavailabledatingbackto1952.Weextendtheseries backto1965relyingonthepricedeflatoravailableatWorldInequalityDatabase. Formorerecentyears(2014-2018),wepredictthetrendbasedonsourcesusedin PYZ(NationalBureauofStatistics, link).
(b) Forindividualbusinesses,PYZcomputestheincomeofthissectorbycombining severaldatasources.Unfortunately,acrucialpartofitisnotavailablepriorto1992, namelythe’flowoffunds’data.Instead,ourassumptionisthat,priorto1980, Chineseindividualbusinessesaccountedforanegligibleshareoftheeconomy.This observationisconsistentwithfactsonself-employmentstructureinChinaatthe microandmacrolevels,andthetrendspresentedinPYZforthe1990s.65 Forrecent years(2014-2018),wepredictthetrendbasedonsourcesusedinPYZ(National BureauofStatistics, link).
TheestimatedseriesofmixedincomeinChinafollowsthesametrendasfortherestof LMICs,althoughitstartsfromaslightlyhigherinitiallevel.
FortheUS,weusethefactorsharesfrom Pikettyetal.(2018), which(i)assumesa highercapitalshareofincomeforpartnershipsvs.othernon-corporatebusinesses;and (ii)accountsfortherisingcapitalintensityofpartnershipssincethe1980s.
65Atthemicrolevel,self-employedworkersrepresentlessthan2%ofworkforceinthe1980s,buthadsimilar incomepercapitaaswageearners(Gustafsson&Zhang,2022).Atthemacrolevel,verysmall-scale industriesrepresented0.4%ofindustryoutputinthe1970s,reaching7%onlyin1989(Yusuf,1994).
17
PanelA:TaxRevenue
TableB2:MainTaxRevenueandNationalAccountsConcepts
6000 othertaxes excluded
Taxesonindividuals(wages,capitalincome,capitalgains). λPIT,ct variesbycountryand year:seeSectionB.2fordetails
Taxesoncorporateprofits.Unallocableincometaxes(OECDcategory1300)aresplitbetween PITandCITbasedoninformationfromadditionalsources(seesupplementaryappendix)
Includesallsocialsecuritycontributionsaswellaspayrolltaxes
Includesproperty,wealthandfinancialtransactiontaxes
Includestradetaxes,value-addedtaxesandothersalestaxesandexcisetaxes.Weconsider thesetaxesaspriortofactorincomereturns,suchthattheycanbeexcludedfromfactor incometaxation(Browning,1978;SaezandZucman,2019).
Rareinoccurrenceandoftenquantitativelysmall
7000 non-taxrevenue excluded Doesnotmeetdefinitionoftaxation,canbequantitativelysignificant
PanelB:NationalAccounts
Natl.accounts
OSHH imputedrent capital
OSCORP corporateprofits capital
OSGOV governmentoperatingsurplus
Includeswagesandsalaries,employerandemployeesocialcontributions,andallpayments fromemployerstotheiremployees
‘Operatingsurplusofprivateunincorporatedenterprises’includesincomefromselfemployment,householdbusinessowners,andinformalorunincorporatedenterprises
‘Operatingsurplusofhouseholds’isimputedrentalincomeaccruingtohomeownerswho liveintheirownhome
‘Operatingsurplusofcorporations’includesallcorporateincomeafterpayingemployees andexpenses,andcanbethoughtofascorporate-sectorcapitalincome
OSGOV =0,byconstructioninnationalaccounts
NIT netindirecttaxes excluded ‘indirecttaxes,netofsubsidies’usuallycomprise8-15%ofnationalincome.
NFI netforeignincome
Wetreatdomesticincomewithoutbalancingtheaccountstoforeignearnedincome:many countriestaxincomeearneddomestically,regardlessofcitizenship,whereasnetforeign incomeistaxedonlywithdifficulty
CFC depreciation excluded Factorincomeandour ETR areexpressednetof‘consumptionoffixedcapital’
OECDrevenue classification typeoftax j incidence λj onlabor notes 1100 personalincometax(PIT) 68% ≤ λPIT ≤ 93%
1200 corporateincometax(CIT) λCIT =0%
2000/3000 socialsecurity&payroll λsoc.sec. =100%
4000 property&wealthtaxes λassets =0%
excluded
5000 indirecttaxes
acronym nationalincomecomponent benchmarkallocation notes CE compensationofemployees labor
OSPUE mixedincome ϕ =75% labor
Notes: Thesegraphsprovideacomparisonofour ETR estimationswiththerecentliterature. Theleft-handgraphcomparesourestimationswith KostarakosandVarthalitis(2020), based onEU-27membersfrom1995to2019.Theright-handgraphcomparesourestimationswith theupdateddatasetinMcDaniel(2020)thatincludes30OECDcountriesfrom1995to2018. Thisextensionisbasedon McDaniel(2007) (Table B3),andcoversthelargestOECDcountries, includingtheUS,aswellasMexicoandTurkey.Thesolidlinerepresentstheresultsusing our ETR measuresandweights,butbasedontheexactcountrysamplesintherespective studies.Thelong-dashlinereplicatesthe ETR measuresfromthetwostudies.Theshort-dash lineextendstheir ETR seriesbutusingourcountry-yearweights.Foradiscussionofthe differencesbetweenseries,seeSection 4.2,Table B3 andthe supplementaryappendix.
TableB3:EffectiveTaxRates:ExistingDatabases
Mendozaetal(1994) 1965-1988 G7membersOECD
CareyandRabesona(2004) 1975-2000 25OECDbiggest members OECD
McDaniel(2007) (McDaniel2020) 1950-2003 (updated:1995-2018) 15OECD biggestmembers (updated30OECD biggestmembers) OECD
Difference:Allmixedincomeisallocatedtocapitalincome. Difference:LaborandcapitalinthePITaretaxedatthesamerate
Difference:Mixedincomeallocationwhereself-employedpay themselvestheannualsalaryearnedbytheaverageemployee.
Similarity:LaborandcapitalinPITarenottaxedatsamerate,measure preferentialtaxtreatmentofpensionfundsanddividends.
Difference:Socialsecuritycontributionsdeductedfromhouseholdincome.
Difference:Mixedincomeimputedtocapitalbasedonrest-of-economyshare. Difference:LaborandcapitalinPITaretaxedatthesamerate
KostarakosandVarthalitis (2020) 1995-2019 EU-27membersEurostat FollowsCareyandRabesona(2004)
FigureB1:Comparing ETR EvolutioninOurDataandExistingStudies (a)KostarakosandVarthalitis(2020) 27EUcountries 0 10 20 30 40 Effective Tax Rate (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 onLabor(ownestimation) onCapital(ownestimation) onLabor(Kostarakos)onCapital(Kostarakos)
30OECDcountries 0 10 20 30 40 Effective Tax Rate (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 onLabor(ownestimation)onCapital(ownestimation) onLabor(McDaniel)onCapital(McDaniel)
onLabor(Kostarakos,weight)onCapital(Kostarakos,weight) (b)McDaniel(2020)
onLabor(McDaniel,weight)onCapital(McDaniel,weight)
Source
Paper Time Countries
Notesonmethodologicaldifferenceswithourapproach
19
AppendixCTradeLiberalizationEventStudies
C.1Descriptionofliberalizationevents
Ourselectionoftradeeventsisdeterminedbythreecriteria.First,theeventisrelated tomeasurablepolicyreforms;thisimprovesthetransparencyoftheevent-studydesign whichisbasedonawell-definedpolicyevent.Second,thepolicyreformsinduced largechangesintradebarriers;thisincreasesthelikelihoodofobservingsharpbreaksin macroeconomicoutcomesaroundtheevent-time.Third,theeventhasbeenstudiedin academicpublications;thisallowsustorelyoneventsforwhichthepositiveeffectson opennesshavepreviouslybeenestablished.
Thesecriterialedustofocusonthesixtradeliberalizationeventsreferencedinreview articlesby GoldbergandPavcnik(2007, 2016) towhichweaddChina’sWTOaccession event (studiedinBrandtetal., 2017). Mostoftheseselectedeventsfeaturereductionsin tariffrates:manyofthecountriesdidnotparticipateintheearlyGATT/WTOnegotiation rounds,makingreductionsintariffsanavailablepolicylever.Thetariffreductionswere large:Brazilcuttariffratesfrom59%to15%,Indiafrom80%to39%percent,andChina from48%to20%.Mexicoreducedtariffratesfrom24%to12%andimportlicense requirementswentfromcovering93%ofnationalproductionto25%;Colombia’stariffs werereducedfrom27%to10%andimportrequirementsdroppedfrom72%ofnational productioncoverageto1%.Intheselectedcountries,“tariffreductionsconstituteabig partoftheglobalizationprocess” (Goldberg&Pavcnik, 2016). Thetimingoftheevents andacademicreferencesareprovidedinthe supplementaryappendix. Belowarenarrativeanalysesforsomeoftheevents:
• Brazil Theliberalizationeventof1988isdetailedinDix-CarneiroandKovak(2017). Theauthorsnote:“Inanefforttoincreasetransparencyintradepolicy,thegovernment reducedtariffredundancybycuttingnominaltariffs...Liberalizationeffectivelybegan whenthenewlyelectedadministrationsuddenlyandunexpectedlyabolishedthelist ofsuspendedimportlicensesandremovednearlyallspecialcustomsregimes.”
• Colombia SimilarlytoBrazil,tariffreductionsinColombiain1985weredrivenby thecountry’sdecisiontoimposeuniformratesacrossproductsandindustriesunder thenegotiationcommitmentstotheWTO. GoldbergandPavcnik(2007) notethatthis reformobjectivemakes“theendogeneityoftradepolicychangeslesspronouncedhere [inColombia]thaninotherstudies.”
• China Brandtetal.(2017) notethattradeopennessreformshadgraduallybeenimplementedinChinapriortothecountry’sWTOaccessionin2001,butthatthetariff reductionsimplementeduponaccessionwerelarge,“lessvoluntary”andlargelycompliedwiththepre-specifiedWTOaccessionagreements.Importantly,thepotential accessiontoWTOcontributedtothetimingofprivatizationinitiatives,inwhichthe Chinesegovernmentrestructuredandreduceditsownershipinstate-ownedenterprises.Whiletheprivatizationeffortsbeganin1995andwereincremental,itispossible thatadditionalsell-offsinthepost-WTOyearscontributetotheobservedmedium-run trendsinouroutcomes.
20
• India The1991eventinIndiaoccurredasaresultofanIMFinterventionthatdictated thepaceandscopeoftheliberalizationreforms.UndertheIMFprogram,tariffrates hadtobeharmonizedacrossindustries,which,likeinBrazilandColombia,ledtoa largeaveragereductionintariffs.TopalovaandKhandelwal(2011)arguetheIndian reform“cameasasurprise”and“wasunanticipatedbyfirmsinIndia.”Thereforms wereimplementedquickly“asasortofshocktherapywithlittledebateoranalysis.” TheIMFprogramwasinresponsetoasetofeventsincluding“thedropinremittances fromIndianworkersintheMiddleEast,theincreaseinoilpricesduetotheGulfWar, andpoliticaluncertaintyfollowingtheassassinationofRajivGandhi”.
• Vietnam The2001reformwasimplementedasabroadtradeagreementthatdidnot involvenegotiationsoverspecifictariffs (McCaig&Pavcnik, 2018). Thereformwas drivenbytheAmericangovernment’sdecisiontoreclassifyVietnamfrom’Column2’ oftheUStariffscheduleto’NormalTradeRelations’.Column2wasdesignedinthe early1950sforthe21communistcountries,includingVietnam,withwhomtheUSdid nothavenormaltradingrelations.
Thesedescriptionsofreformtimingdonotsuggestthattheliberalizationeventswere directlytriggeredbychangesindomestictaxationorfactorincomes.
GoldbergandPavcnik(2007) noteothercross-borderreformsthatoccurredduring post-yearsoftheliberalizationevents.Argentina’s1989eventandBrazil’s1988event werefollowedbyaccessiontoMercosurin1991;India’s1991eventwasfollowedby foreigndirectinvestmentliberalizationin1993;andMexico’s1985WTOaccessionwas followedbyaremovalofcapitalinflowrestrictionsin1989.Thesereformsoccurredwith somelagtothetradeliberalizationevents.
C.2Eventstudymethodology
Oursampleisconstructedbyapplyingasyntheticmatchingproceduretoeverytreated countryforeachoutcomeofinterest.Thedonorpoolhastobefullybalancedinallpreeventperiods.Toestimatetheeventstudyinequation(4)foragivenoutcome,thesample poolstheseventreatedcountriesandtheirsyntheticcontrolcountriesfor10yearsbefore andaftertheevents(yielding294observations).Weestimatetheevent-studyinequation 4 andtheDiDmodel: yct = βDiD ·1(e ≥ 0)t ·Dc + θt + κc + πYear(t) + ϵct.TheDiDmodeluses thesamenotationasequation(4).Moreover,weusetheimputationmethodby Borusyak etal.(2021) toreportaveragetreatmenteffectscomparableto βDiD withatechniquethat dealswithissueswithtwo-wayfixedeffectsandheterogeneouseventtiming.Details areprovidedinthe supplementaryappendix.AlltheDiDaveragetreatmenteffectsare reportedinTable A1.Wetestifourresultsholdwithamorerestrictivesyntheticcontrol, byusingourthreemainoutcomes—trade, ETRK and ETRL—toconstructonesynthetic controlgrouppertreatedcountry.TheresultsarereportedinPanelBofTable A1.
C.3Alternativetradeliberalizationeventstudy
Wepresentresultsbasedonanalternativemeasureoftradeliberalizationevents.We usetheeventsfrom WacziargandWelch(2008), whichcover141countriesatalllevelsof developmentbetweenthe1950sand1998.Whenmergedwithourdata,thesamplecovers
21
68liberalizationeventsthatoccurredbetween1965and1998indevelopingcountries.A tradeliberalizationeventisdefinedtooccurwhenallfiveofthefollowingconditionsno longerhold:(i)averagetariffratesareabove40%;(ii)non-tariffbarrierscoveratleast40% oftrade;(iii)theblackmarketexchangerateisatleast20%lowerthantheofficialexchange rate;(iv)thereisastatemonopolyonmajorexports;(v)thereisasocialisticsystemin place.Theseconditionsarebroaderthanourmainliberalizationeventcriteria(Section 5.1 and C.1).Atthesametime,ourmaineventsarecoveredinthisexpandedeventsample (withtheexceptionofChinaandVietnam,whoseeventsareaftertheendofthesample period);thisoccursbecausethereductionintariffrates,oneofourmaineventcriteria,was theremainingevent-conditiontobesatisfiedin WacziargandWelch(2008). Weestimate theeffectsoftheliberalizationeventsusingtheDiDmodel: yct = βDiD · Ect + θ
yct istheoutcomeofinterestincountry c inyear t, Ect istheeventindicatorwhichtakes onavalueof1inallperiodsafteracountryhasaliberalizationevent(and0otherwise), and θt and θc areyearandcountryfixedeffects,respectively. ϵct isclusteredatthecountry level.Estimationissuesarisingfromheterogeneoustreatment-timingmaybeimportant; forthisreason,wefocusontheimputedtreatmenteffectsbasedon Borusyaketal.(2021). Werestrictthesampletodevelopingcountriesbetween1965and2008.
PanelAofTableC1reportsthe βDiD impactsontrade, ETRK and ETRL.Despitebeing basedonbroadercriteria,thetradeliberalizationeventsproducequalitativelysimilar resultstothemainevent-study(Section 5.1),withpositiveimpactsonopennessandboth ETRs,andalargermagnitude-impacton ETRK than ETRL.Figure C1 estimatesthe dynamicevent-study.Liberalizedandcontrolcountriesareonparalleltrendsuntilthe eventonset;both ETRsstarttoincreaseintheimmediatepost-eventyears.PanelBshows thattheresultsarerobusttoestimatingtheeffectsinafullybalancedpanel10-years post-reform.InPanelC,theresultsholdwhenthecontrolgroupisformedwithin-region. PanelDshowstheresultsarerobusttoexcludingcountrieswhichhavecross-border capitalliberalizationeventsatanypointduringthesample-period(Bekaert,Harveyand Lundblad,2000).Finally,PanelEshowstheresultsholdwhenweexcludecountrieswith concurrentdomesticreforms (Wacziarg&Wallack, 2004).
FigureC1:Event-StudyofTradeLiberalizationBasedonWacziarg&Welch(2008)
(a)Effectivetaxrateoncapital
(b)Effectivetaxrateonlabor
Notes: Thesegraphsshowevent-studyimpactsofthetradeliberalizationeventsfrom Wacziarg andWelch(2008) on ETRK (leftpanel)and ETRL (rightpanel).
t + θc + ϵct
.
22
TableC1:TradeLiberalizationEvent-StudyBasedonWacziarg&Welch(2008)
Trade ETRK ETRL (1)(2) (3)
PanelA: Benchmark
Post*Treat
Imputedtreatmenteffect
0.0300.0210.006 (0.048)(0.017)(0.006)
0.090*0.043**0.021*** (0.049)(0.016)(0.005)
N 403240324032
PanelB: Fullybalancedpanel,10-yearpost-reform
Imputedtreatmenteffect
0.110**0.031**0.018*** (0.054)(0.014)(0.005)
N 308230823082
PanelC: Withregion-yearfixedeffects
Imputedtreatmenteffect
0.084**0.042**0.021*** (0.041)(0.016)(0.005)
N 403240324032
PanelD: Excludingcountrieswithcapitalliberalization
Imputedtreatmenteffect
0.101*0.028*0.014** (0.057)(0.017)(0.006)
N 265126512651
PanelE: Excludingcountrieswithdomesticreforms
Imputedtreatmenteffect
0.0560.040**0.015*** (0.051)(0.016)(0.005)
N 355135513551
Notes: Thistableshowstheresultsfromestimatingthedifference-in-differenceregressionand theimputedtreatmenteffectofthe68tradeliberalizationeventsfrom WacziargandWelch (2008), between1965and2008.Thesampleislowandmiddle-incomecountries,basedonthe WorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.InPanelA,thepost*treatcoefficientcorrespondsto the βDiD basedonestimatingtheequationinSectionC.3.Theimputedtreatmenteffectisbased onthemethodin Borusyak,Jaravel,andSpiess(2021). InPanelB,thesampleisrestrictedto thefullybalancedsetofcountriesinthe10yearsaftertheliberalizationevent.InPanelC,the estimationisaugmentedwithregion-by-yearinteractivefixedeffects.InPanelD,thesample excludesallcountriesthathaveacapitalliberalizationreformatanypointduringthesampleperiod,basedonBekaert,HarveyandLundblad(2000).InPanelE,thesampleexcludesall countrieswithdomesticreformswhichcoincideintimingwiththeirtradeliberalizationevent, basedon WacziargandWallack(2004). Standarderrorsareclusteredatthecountrylevel.For moredetailsontheliberalizationevents,seeAppendix C.3.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01.
23
AppendixDResultsonTaxCapacityMechanism
D.1Firm-levelanalysisinRwanda
Data-sourcesandsample Ouranalysisdrawsonthreeadministrativedatasetsfromthe RwandaRevenueAuthority(RRA),fortheyears2015-2017.Thesedatasourcescanbe linkedthroughuniquetaxidentifiersforeachfirm,assignedbytheRRAforthepurpose ofcollectingcustoms,corporateincomeandvalue-addedtaxes.Thefirstdatasourceis thecustomsrecords,whichcontaininformationoninternationaltradetransactionsmade ineachyearbyeachfirm.Weusethisdatatomeasureeachfirm’sdirectimports.The seconddataisthefirms’corporateincometax(CIT)declarationsmergedwiththefirm registry.Thesedatacontaindetailedannualinformationonfirms’profits,revenueand costs.Weusethesedatatomeasureeachfirm’seffectivetaxrate.Thethirddatasource isthebusiness-to-businesstransactionsdatabase.Thesedataareretrievedthroughthe electronicbillingmachines(EBM)thatallfirmsregisteredforVATarelegallyrequiredto use(EissaandZeitlin,2014).Foragivenseller,EBMsrecordthetransactionstoeachbuyer identifiedbythetaxfirm-ID.Weusethisdatatomeasurebuyer-sellerrelationships.
Whencombined,thesedataallowustoconstructthebuyer-supplierrelationshipsof theRwandanformaleconomyanddocumentfirms’totaltradeexposure.Importantly, sincethenetworkdataisbasedontax-IDs,wecannotobservetransactionlinkageswith informal,non-registeredfirms.Thissampleselectiononformalfirmsalsofeaturesin mostrecentnetworkstudies,byvirtueofrelyingonadministrativedata,includingin Chile(Huneeus,2020);CostaRica(Alfaro-Ureñaetal.);Ecuador(Adaoetal.,2022);India (Gadenneetal.,2022);Turkey(Demiretal.,2021);andUganda(Almuniaetal.,2023).
OursampleisthesetoffirmsthatareregisteredforCITandthatreportpositive incomeduringtheyears2015-2017.Notethatonlyasmallnumberoffirmsareregistered forCITorVATbutnotboth,meaningthattheoverlapwiththeEBMtransactionsdatais strong.However,restrictingthesampletopositiveincomeisconsequential,asasignificant numberofregisteredCITfirmsare’nilfilers’thatreportzeroincome(’nilfilers’are commonindevelopingcountries:Keen,2012).Wemeasureeachfirm i’syearlyeffective taxrateoncorporateprofits,correspondingtocorporate ETRK i inequation(6),asthe ratioofcorporatetaxespaiddividedbynetprofit.Netprofitisrevenueminusmaterial, labor,operational,depreciationandfinancialcosts.
TheEBMdataismeanttoimprovetheenforcementofcorporatetaxesandVAT,and thereportingoflinkagesismorecomprehensivefortherelativelylargerfirmsthatare registeredforthesetaxbases.Forsmallerincorporatedfirmsthatareinsteadregistered tosimplifiedtaxbases(flat-amountorturnover),onlyafewofthemareregisteredfor VAT.Consequently,thesefirmsaremostlikelytoberecordedintheEBMdataasclients inaparticulartransaction,makingthecoverageoftheirlinkageslesscomprehensive. Itisinprinciplealsopossibletomeasure ETRK i amongstthesesmaller,incorporated firms.However,theinformationontheirtaxreturnsregardingcostitemsislessdetailed andadditionalassumptionsontherelationshipbetweenturnoverandprofitarerequired, whichmakestheprofitmeasureinthedenominatorof ETRK i lessprecise.Withthesedatachallengesinmind,wecanincludetheseadditionaltax-registeredfirmsintheanalysis; wefindqualitativelysimilarresults(availableuponrequest).
24
Exposuretotrade Tomeasureafirm’stotalexposuretotrade,wefollow Dhyneetal. (2021) whousesimilaradministrativedatasetsasourstomeasuretradeexposureof Belgianfirms.Wedefinefirm i’stotalforeigninputshareastheshareofinputsthatit directlyimports(sFi),plustheshareofinputsthatitbuysfromitsdomesticsuppliers l (sli),multipliedbythetotalimportsharesofthosefirms:
where Vi isthesetofdomesticsuppliersoffirm i,and Vl isthesetofdomesticsuppliers offirm l.Thedenominatoroftheinputsharesisthesumofpurchasesfromotherfirms andimports.Notethat sTotal i isrecursive:afirm’stotalforeigninputshareisthesumof itsdirectforeigninputshareandtheshareofitsinputsfromotherfirms,multipliedby thosefirms’totalforeigninputshares.Welimitthecalculationtotheinputsfromafirm’s immediatesuppliers l aswellasthesupplierstotheirsuppliers r (addingmorenetworklevelsonlymarginallyincreases sTotal i ). sTotal i reflectsthedirectimportshareoffirm i’s suppliersandthesuppliers’suppliers,eachweightedbytheshareofinputsthateachfirm buysfromotherdomesticfirms.Wefocusonfirms’exposuretoimportsthroughtheir suppliernetwork;inanextension,wefindqualitativelysimilarresultswhenstudying firms’exposuretoexportsthroughtheirclientnetwork(resultsavailable).
Figure D1 displaysahistogramof sTotal i and sFi forallformalRwandanfirms.While justunder30%offirmsimportdirectly,93%relyontradeeitherdirectlyorindirectly throughtheirsuppliers.Inthemedianfirm,thetotalforeigninputshareis48%(itis39% forthemedianBelgianfirmin Dhyneetal., 2021).
Impactsoftradeexposureon ETRK andsize Tovisualizetheassociationbetweentrade exposure(sTotal i )and ETRK i ,weplotbinnedscattersofthevariablesagainsteachother, afterresidualizingbothagainstyearfixedeffects.InFigure D2,thedotscorrespondto equal-sizedbinsoftheresidualizedtradevariable.Thelinecorrespondstothebestlinear fitregressionontheunderlyingfirm-leveldata(N =18478).Figure D2 revealsapositive andstronglysignificantassociation:firmsthataremoreexposedtointernationaltrade, boththroughdirectimportsandthroughlinkstoimportersinthesupplynetwork,have highereffectivetaxratesoncorporateprofits.
WeinvestigatethisassociationinaregressionforminTable 4,deployingbothOLSand IV.TheIVappliesthedesignin Dhyneetal.(2021) thatextendstheshift-shareapproach of Hummelsetal.(2014) toasettingwithshockpass-throughvianetworklinkages.The empiricalstrategiesandthemainresultsaredescribedinSection 6.3.
Inadditionalregressions(notshownbutavailable),wefindthattheresultsarerobust tocontrollingfortradeshockstofirm i’spotentialsuppliers(firmsthatoperateinthesame industryandgeographicalareaas i’scurrentsuppliersbutarenotcurrentlysupplyingto i)andfirm i’shorizontalsuppliers(firmsthataresupplierstofirm i’scurrentclients).
Wefocusonfirms’exposuretoimportsthroughtheirsupplynetwork,butfirms mayalsobeimpactedbyimportsthroughtheirclients.Inanextension,wefindthat increasedoutputexposuretoimportsthroughtheclientnetworkhaspositiveeffectson ETRK (resultsavailable),thoughthisaverageeffectcouldmaskheterogeneityacrossfirms dependingonthecomplementaritybetweenimportsanddomesticinputs.
s Total i = sFi + l∈Vi sli · [sFl + r∈Vl srl · (sFr + ...)]
25
Becausetheestimationiswithinthecorporatesector,thisexercisecannotspeakto themagnitudeoftrade’snetimpactonsector-level ETRK C .Thesefirm-levelresultson corporate ETRK i arethereforecomplementarytothecountry-levelresultson ETRK C .An additionallimitationisthatthenetworklinkagemeasuresarederivedfromadministrative datawhich,byconstruction,onlyexistfortaxregisteredfirms(Atkin&Khandelwal, 2020). Thissamplerestrictionimpliesthatthisfirm-levelregressionisnotsuitedtostudythe impactsoftradeonthesizeofinformalfirms.
D.2Typeoftradeanalysis
Weinvestigatewhethertradehasdifferentialimpactson ETR andmechanismoutcomes dependingonthenatureofthetradevariation(Section 6.4).Weuseourtwoinstruments toinvestigatetheimpactsof:(i)importsversusexports(oftradeinbothintermediateG-S andfinalG-S);(ii)tradeinintermediateG-SversusfinalG-S(summedacrossimportsand exports).WeuseUN’sBroadEconomicCategories(Rev.5)toclassifyfinalversusintermediategoods-services(G-S),combiningcapitalgoodswiththelatter.Fortheimports versusexportsIV,thetwo 1st-stageregressionsare
where log(impct) and log(expct) arethelogsoftotalimportstoNDPandtotalexportsto NDP,respectively,incountry c inyear t.Thelog-transformationimprovesthe 1st-stage (resultswithoutlogsarequalitativelysimilar).The 2nd-stageis
Theset-upissimilarforthesecondIV(intermediateG-SvsfinalG-S)wherewereplace log(impct) and log(expct) withthelogoftotaltradeinintermediateG-StoNDPandthe logoftotaltradeinfinalG-StoNDP.IVresultsfordevelopingcountriesareinPanelA ofTable D1,with 1st-stageregressionsinPanelB.Notethatitisexanteunclearifthe twoinstrumentsgenerateastrongoverallfirst-stage.Wegaugethisbyinspectingthe Kleibergen-PaapF-statistics,whicharenotwellaboveconventionalthresholdlevels(13.56 and8.21).Giventhischallenge,welimitourscopetostudyingwhetherthecoefficient signsforthedifferenttypesoftradeareconsistentwithoursimplifiedpredictions(and whethertheystatisticallydifferfromeachother).Theexclusionrestrictionrequiresthat theregressorsadduptototaltradeopenness.Forthisreason,wecannotimplementan IVwhichfocusesontheimpactsoffinalversusintermediateG-Sfor,say,importsonly. Thisalsoimpliesthat,foragivenoutcome,thehypothesesinourtwoIVs(finalversus intermediateG-S;importsversusexports)willbecorrelated.Weaccordinglyadjustthe p-valuesformultiplehypothesestestingusingtheRomano-Wolfmethod.
TheresultsaredescribedinSection 6.4.Sinceweonlyhave2instruments,wecannot decisivelyconcludeontheimpactsforthe4typesoftrade(importsofintermediateG-S, exportsofintermediateG-S,importsoffinalG-S,exportsoffinalG-S).Notwithstanding, theestimatedIVcoefficientsareconsistentwithimportsoffinalG-Sdecreasing ETRK andmechanismoutcomes(µC ,ETRK C ),andimportsofintermediateG-Sincreasingthem.
log(impct)= β1 Zgravity ct + β2 Zoil dist ct + µc + µt + ϵct log(expct)= π1 · Zgravity ct + π2 · Zoil dist ct + ηc + ηt + ιct
yct = θ1 · log(impct)+ θ2 · log(expct)+ κc + κt + ϕct
26
FigureD1:RwandanFirms’DirectandTotalExposuretoTradeinImports
Notes: Thisfigureshowsthedistributionofdirectforeigninputshare, sFi,andtotalforeigninputshare, sTotal i ,forallcorporatefirmsinRwandabetween2015and2017.Themeasuresarecalculatedannually,and thefigurepoolsallfirm-yearobservations.Thehorizontallinerepresentsascalebreakintheverticalaxis. MoredetailsareinSection D.1
FigureD2:RwandanFirms’TradeExposureandCorporateEffectiveTaxRate
Notes: Thisfigureshowsthefirm-levelassociationbetweentotalforeigninputshare, sTotal i ,andthecorporate effectivetaxrateforallcorporatefirmsinRwandabetween2015and2017.Thegraphplotsbinnedscatters ofthevariablesagainsteachother,afterresidualizingbothvariablesagainstyear-fixedeffects.Thedots correspondtoequal-sizedbinsoftheresidualizedtradeexposurevariable.Thelinecorrespondstothebest linearfitregressionontheunderlyingfirm-leveldata(N =18478),whichisalsoreportedincolumn(1)of Table 4.
0 .01 .02 .03 .04 .05 .06 .07 .70 Fraction of sample (%) 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1 Trade input share DirectTotal
0.100 se: (0.021) −.045 −.025 −.005 .015 .035 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (resid.) −.5 −.4 −.3 −.2 −.1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 Total trade input share (resid.)
b:
27
WeakInstrumentF-statistic 1
Notes: Thesampleisdevelopingcountries,whicharelowandmiddle-incomecountriesaccordingto theWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.PanelApresentsIVresults,whilePanelBpresents 1st-stage results.InPanelA’sodd-numberedcolumns,importsandexportsaretheregressorswhileineven-numbered columnsitistradeinintermediategoodsandservices(G-S)andtradeinfinalG-S.Outcomesdifferacross columnsinPanelA:incols.(1)-(2),effectivetaxrateoncapital, ETRK ;incols.(3)-(4),effectivetaxrateon labor, ETRL;incols.(5)-(6),corporateincomeshareofnetdomesticproduct;incols.(7)-(8),mixedincome shareofnetdomesticproduct;incols.(9)-(10),averageeffectivetaxrateoncorporateprofits.Fordetailson theoutcomesandtheinstruments,seeTable 1 and 3.Relativetothosetables,thedropinsamplesizeinthis tableisduetoavailabilityofthetypeoftradeclassification.Foreachcoefficient,wereportinbracketsthepvalueswhichcorrectformultiplehypothesestesting,usingtheRomano-Wolfmethod.Multiplehypothesis testingisaccountedforwithineachoutcomebetweenthetwoIVestimations(exportsandimports;final G-SandintermediateG-S).AtthebottomofeachcolumninPanelA,wereporttheF-testfortheequalityof coefficients.InPanelB,cols.(1)-(2)correspondtothefirst-stageregressionthatinstrumentssimultaneously forimportsandexports;cols.(3)-(4)isthefirst-stageregressionwhichinstrumentssimultaneouslyfor intermediateG-SandfinalG-S.InPanelB,wereporttheF-statisticofexcludedinstruments;theSandersonWindmeermultivariateF-testofexcludedinstruments;and,theKleibergen-PaapF-statistic.*p<0.10** p<0.05***p<0.01.Standarderrorsinparenthesesareclusteredatthecountrylevel.Formoredetails,see Section D.2.
TableD1:TypeofTradeAnalysisinDevelopingCountries Corporate Mixed Corporate PanelA:IV ETRK ETRL Income Income ETRK (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) ExportofG-S 0.487* 0.225** 0.214* -0.159* 0.611* (0.263) (0.096) (0.123) (0.091) (0.339) [0.066] [0.019] [0.039] [0.119] [0.076] ImportofG-S -0.358*** -0.184*** -0.126* 0.069 -0.442*** (0.126) (0.044) (0.074) (0.049) (0.158) [0.059] [0.013] [0.045] [0.145] [0.033] IntermediateG-S 0.303*** 0.133*** 0.147** -0.119*** 0.385*** (0.095) (0.038) (0.070) (0.045) (0.122) [0.053] [0.012] [0.033] [0.048] [0.031] FinalG-S -0.245*** -0.125*** -0.089** 0.050** -0.302*** (0.051) (0.023) (0.044) (0.024) (0.056) [0.013] [0.006] [0.019] [0.119] [0.006] F-test:Equalityof 4.82 14.78 8.55 19.06 2.734.33 2.555.98 4.6015.35 coefficients[p-value] [0.030] [0.004] [0.004] [0.001] [0.096][0.039] [0.113][0.016] [0.034][0.000] N 4572 4572 4572 4572 45724572 45724572 45724572
ImportofG-SExportofG-S IntermediateG-SFinalG-S (1) (2) (3) (4) Zgravity 0.287*** 0.252*** 0.282*** 0.268*** (0.034) (0.060) (0.034) (0.052) Zoil distance -0.077*** 0.003 0.008 -0.116*** (0.011) (0.018) (0.013) (0.019) 1st-stageF-statistic 134.47 15.75 54.76 75.85
34.02 65.33 70.59
st-stageKleibergen- 8.21 13.56
N 4572 4572 4572 4572
PanelB:1st-stage
1st-stageSanderson-Windmeijer36.49
PappFstatistic
28
AppendixECapitalLiberalizationEvents
Toattempttoinvestigatetheimpactofcapitalliberalizationoneffectivetaxrates,we drawon Charietal.(2012). Theauthorsmeasurecapitalliberalizationeventsin25 developingcountriesasthedatewhenforeigninvestmentinthedomesticstockmarketwas firstallowed.Theyshowthattheseeventssignificantlyincreaseforeigncapitalinflows, includingforeigndirectinvestment(FDI)andimportofcapitalgoods.66 Comparedto otherpoliciesaimedatliftingFDIrestrictions,liberalizingthedomesticstockmarket occursataprecisepointintime,isnotmarkedbypolicy-reversalornetcapitaloutflow, andisunambiguouslyrelatedtocapitalliberalization(Eichengreen,2001).Weemploy theempiricaldesignofSection 5.1 andcreateasyntheticcontrolcountryforeachofthe 25treatedcountriesandforeachoutcome.Wemeasurecapitalopennessasthetotalsum ofthestocksofforeignassetsandliabilities(Gyglietal.,2019).Wefindsimilarresults whenusingalternativemeasuresofcapitalopenness,includingportfolioequityassets andliabilitiesandtheKOFfinancialglobalizationindex(Gyglietal.,2019).
Figure E1 reportstheevent-studyresults.Relativetoastablepre-trend,weobservea sustainedriseincapitalopennesspreciselyatthetimeoftheevent. ETRK alsoincreases, withasmalllagtothetimingofthecapitalliberalizationevent;inthemedium-run, thepositiveeffecton ETRK issignificantatthe5%level.Thereisnodiscernibleeffect on ETRL.Similartothereasoningforthetradetax-capacitymechanism,theinflowof foreigncapital,aswellasanysubsequentincreaseincapitalgoodsimportsandaggregate investment,maypositivelyimpact ETRK bycontributingtogeneralgrowthoffirmsorby causinganexpansionofinitiallylargerfirms.Consistentwiththisinterpretation,wefind thatthecapitalliberalizationeventsledtoincreasesinthecorporateoutputshareandthe averagecorporateeffectivetaxrate(resultsnotshownbutavailable).
Oneimportantlimitationisthattheeventsconsideredhereremoverestrictionson capital inflows andarenotinformativeoftheimpactsofincreasedcapital outflows.In general,moreworkisneededtounderstandthedeterminantsofpoliciesthatimpact cross-bordercapitalflowsindevelopingcountriesandtheireffectson ETRs.
66FDIincludesgreenfieldinvestments(buildingplantsfromscratch)andcross-bordermergersandacquisitions(M&A). Charietal.(2012) notethatM&Aisimpactedbystockmarketliberalization,makesupto 40-60%ofFDIindevelopingcountries,andcantriggersubsequentgreenfieldinvestments.
29
FigureE1:EventStudyofCapitalLiberalizationReforms
Notes: Thesepanelsshowevent-studiesforcapitalliberalizationreformsinthe25developingcountries of Chari,Henry,andSasson(2012). Thepanelscorrespondtodifferentoutcomes:capitalopenness(top panels);effectivetaxrateoncapital(middlepanels);effectivetaxrateonlabor(bottompanels).Capital opennessisthetotalsumofthestocksofforeignassetsandliabilities,inconstantUSD.Weusethelog transformationforthisoutcome;resultswherethetotalsumisexpressedasapercentofGDParesimilar. Theleft-handgraphsshowtheaverageleveloftheoutcomeineveryyearto/sincetheevent,fortreated countriesandforsyntheticcontrolcountries.Theright-handgraphsshowtheestimated βe coefficientson theto/sincedummies,basedonequation(4)butwherethetradeliberalizationeventsarereplacedwith capitalliberalizationevents.Thebarsrepresentthe95%confidenceintervals.Standarderrorsareclustered atthecountrylevelandestimatedwiththewildbootstrapmethod.Thetop-leftcornersreporttheF-statistic onjointsignificanceofthepost-eventdummies,withthep-valueinparentheses.DetailsareinAppendix E
10 11 12 13 Log of capital openness −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent TreatedCountries SyntheticControl Jointsignif.ofpost−eventdummies: 2.27 (.026) −.2 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 Coefficient on Log capital openness −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent .08 .12 .16 .2 Effective tax rate on capital (in %) −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent TreatedCountries SyntheticControl Jointsignificanceofyear−sinceeventdummies: 1.37 (.222) −.12 −.08 −.04 0 .04 .08 .12 Coefficient on ETR_K −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent .08 .12 .16 .2 Effective tax rate on labor (in %) −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent TreatedCountries SyntheticControl Jointsignificanceofyear−sinceeventdummies: 1.63 (.122) −.12 −.08 −.04 0 .04 .08 .12 Coefficient on ETR_L −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent
30
Appendix
OnlineSupplementaryAppendix,NotforPublication "CapitalTaxation,DevelopmentandGlobalization: EvidencefromaMacro-HistoricalDatabase"
(Pleasenote:Thisappendixcontainsthesamematerialasthe108-page onlinesupplementaryappendix,includingthecase-studiesreport, circulatedunderthetitle"GlobalizationandFactorIncomeTaxation")
byPierreBachas,Matthew-FisherPost,AndersJensenandGabrielZucman
1
Notes: Thisfigureshowstheevolutionofeffectivetaxratesonlaborandcapitalforthe17largestlowand middle-incomecountries.Countriesaredisplayedwhentheyrankinthetop20bothintermsofpopulation andNetDomesticProduct(NDP)in2018.Lowandmiddle-incomecountriesarebasedontheWorldBank incomeclassificationin2018.
FigureO1:EffectiveTaxRatesinLargeDevelopingCountries 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 China 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 India 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Brazil 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Indonesia 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Russian Federation 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Mexico 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Nigeria 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Turkey 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Philippines 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Pakistan 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Bangladesh 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Thailand 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Egypt 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 South Africa 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Viet Nam 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Argentina 0 10 20 30 40 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Colombia Effective Tax Rate on Labor on Capital
2
Notes: Thisfigureplotsthetimeseriesoftaxrevenueasashareofnetdomesticproduct(NDP),separated intofiverevenuesources.Thetopleftpanelcorrespondstotheglobalaverage,weightingcountry-year observationsbytheirshareinthatyear’stotalNDP,inconstant2019USD(N=154).Thebottom-left panelshowstheresultsforhigh-incomecountries,andthebottomrightforlow-andmiddle-income countries.Low,middleandhigh-incomecountriesarebasedontheWorldBankincomeclassificationin 2018.Taxrevenuesareseparatedintofivemaincategories:indirecttaxes(domesticconsumptiontaxesand internationaltradetaxes),payrollandsocialsecuritytaxes,taxesonpersonalincome,taxesonpropertyand wealth,andtaxesoncorporateincome.Thedatasetiscomposedoftwo(quasi)balancedpanels:thefirst coverstheyears1965-1993andexcludescommunistregimes.Thesecondcovers1994-2018andintegrates formercommunistcountries,inparticularChinaandRussia.
FigureO2:TaxRevenueasaShareofNetDomesticProduct 0 10 20 30 40 Tax Revenue (% NDP) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 0 10 20 30 40 Tax Revenue (% NDP) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 0 10 20 30 40 Tax Revenue (% NDP) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Indirect Tax Payroll Tax Personal Income Tax Property Tax Corporate Income Tax
3
FigureO3:Robustnessof
K and ETRL TrendsbyDevelopmentLevels
Notes: Thesepanelsshowtrendsintheeffectivetaxationofcapitalandlaborforhigh-incomecountries (HICs,toppanels)andlowandmiddle-incomecountries(LMICs,bottompanels).Low,middleandhighincomecountriesarebasedontheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.Thebenchmarkseriesare denotedbythethickcoloredlinesandthegreylinesdenoteall54possiblepermutationsoftheserieswhen varyingthefourkeymethodologicalchoices(detailedinSection4.2):theallocationofpersonalincome taxrevenuetocapitalvslabor;theallocationofmixedincometocapitalvslabor;presentingresultsforan unbalancedpanelofcountriesvsabalancedpanelviaimputations;and,howtoweightindividualcountries’ serieswhenaggregatingthem.Panel(c)correspondingtothe ETRK forlowandmiddle-incomecountries isfurtherdecomposedinFigure3.
(a) ETRK inHICs 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Effective Tax Rate on Capital (%) 196519751985199520052015 Benchmark Allpermutations (b) ETRL inHICs 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Effective Tax Rate on Labor (%) 196519751985199520052015 Benchmark Allpermutations
ETRK inLMICs 0 5 10 15 20 Effective Tax Rate on Labor (%) 196519751985199520052015 Benchmark Allpermutations (d) ETRL inLMICs 0 5 10 15 20 Effective Tax Rate on Labor (%) 196519751985199520052015 Benchmark Allpermutations
ETR
(c)
4
b:0.063 se:(0.026)
Notes: Thesepanelsshowtheassociationbetweentradeandeffectivetaxrates,conditionalonGDPper capita,indevelopingcountries.ThepanelsarecreatedexactlyinthesamewayasinFigure5,exceptthe variablesareadditionallyresidualizedagainstthegrowthrateinGDPpercapita.Developingcountries includelow-incomeandmiddle-incomecountries,wherecategoriesarebasedontheWorldBankincome classificationin2018.Theoutcomeistheeffectivetaxrateoncapital, ETRK ,andonlabor, ETRL,inthe left-sideandright-sidepanels,respectively.Tradeismeasuredasthesumofimportandexportsasashare ofnetdomesticproduct.Boththex-axisandy-axisaremeasuredaswithin-countrypercentchangesover5 years.Eachgraphshowsbinnedscatterplotsofeachoutcomeagainsttrade,afterresidualizingallvariables againstyearfixedeffectsandthe5-yeargrowthrateinGDPpercapita.Eachdotcorrespondstoaventile (20equal-sizedbins)oftheresidualizedtradevariable,withaveragevaluesoftradeand ETR calculatedby ventile.Ineachgraph,thelinerepresentsthebestlinearfitbasedontheunderlyingcountry-yeardata,with thecorrespondingslope-coefficientandstandarderrorreportedinthetop-leftcorner.Formoredetails,see Section4.4.
FigureO4:Associationsbetween ETR andTrade,ConditionalonGDPperCapita (a) ETRK :Low&middle-income
5−year Change in ETR
b:0.202 se:(0.030) 0.000.050.100.150.20
K −0.40−0.200.000.200.400.60 5−yearChangeinTrade (b) ETRL:Low&middle-income
0.000.050.100.150.20 5−year Change in ETR L −0.40−0.200.000.200.400.60 5−yearChangeinTrade
5
Notes: Thesepanelsplotthetimeseriesoftradeopenness(top-leftpanel),effectivetaxrateon capital(bottom-leftpanel)andeffectivetaxrateonlabor(bottom-rightpanel).Thesampleis limitedtolow-andmiddle-incomecountries,accordingtotheWorldBankincomeclassification in2018.Withineachpanel,theorangeline(greenline)tracestheevolutionofthegroupwhich hadrelativelyhigh(low)tradeopennesspriorto1995.Specifically,high(low)tradeopennessis definedashavingaveragetradeopennesswhichliesabove(below)theglobalaveragebetween 1965and1995.Tradeopennessismeasuredastheshareofimportsandexportsinnational domesticproduct;notethatthissharecanexceedavalueof1.Eachlineplotstheyearfixed effectsfromanOLSregressionintherelevantsub-sampleoftheoutcomeoncountryandyear fixedeffects.Theinclusionofcountryfixedeffectslimitstheinfluenceofcountriesenteringand leavingthesample.Thefixedeffectsarenormalizedtoequaltheleveloftheoutcomevariable intherelevantsub-samplein1965.Theshadedareahighlightsthenotable1990-1995period, whichmarksthebeginningofthe‘secondwave’ofglobalizationthatfeaturedaproliferation ofbilateralandmultilateraltradeagreements (Egger,Nigai,&Strecker, 2019).
FigureO5:TrendsbyInitialTradeOpennessinDevelopingCountries
6
FigureO6:StrengthofIndividualInstrumentsAcrossSubsamples
(a)Sub-samplesofNDPpercapita
(b)Sub-samplesoftime-periods
Notes: Thesefiguresshowthestatisticalstrengthoftheinstruments Zoil distance and Zgravity in developingcountries(lowandmiddle-incomecountriesbasedonWorldBankclassificationin 2018, N =4916).Theoutcomeisthefirst-stageF-statisticfromaregressionoftradeopenness oneachindividualinstrument,insubsamplesoflogNDPpercapita(panela)andyears(panel b).Thex-axisvariableispartitionedintotendeciles,andtheestimationisdoneinincrements ofonedecilewithabandwidthofoneadditionaldecileofoneitherside.Tomaintainequal samplesizes,estimationcenteredonthefirstandthetenthdecilearedropped.Thisfigureis discussedinSection5.2.
FigureO7:RobustnessofTradeLiberalizationtoChangingEvents-Sample (a)Effectivetaxrateoncapital
(b)Effectivetaxrateonlabor
Notes: Thesefiguresshoweventstudyimpactsoftradeliberalizationontheeffectivetaxrate oncapital(panela)andtheeffectivetaxrateonlabor(panelb).Thesolidgreenlinedisplays thedynamicevent-studycoefficients βe estimatedinthefullsampleof7liberalizationeventcountries(Figure6);thegraylinespresenttheevent-studycoefficientsestimatedinsamples thatremoveoneevent-countryoneatatime.MoredetailsinSection5.1.1.
−.01 .01 .03 .05 .07 Effective Tax Rate on Capital −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent
−.01 .01 .03 .05 .07 Effective Tax Rate on Labor −10 −8 −6 −4 −2 0 2 4 6 8 10 Yearsto/fromEvent
7
High income countriesLow and middle income countries
Notes: Thisfigureplotsthetimeseriesofthestatutorycorporateincometax(CIT)rate,separatelyforhighincomecountriesandformiddleandlow-incomecountries.Low,middleandhigh-incomecountriesare basedontheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.Eachlineplotstheyear-fixedeffectsfromanOLS regressionoftheCITrateoncountryandyear-fixedeffectsintherelevantsub-sample.Theinclusionof country-fixedeffectshelpsalleviatetheinfluenceofcountriesenteringandleavingthesample.Thefixed effectsarenormalizedtoequaltheleveloftheCITrateintherelevantsub-samplein1965.Country-year observationsareweightedbytheirshareintheyear’stotalnetdomesticproductinconstant2019USD.
FigureO8:TrendsinCorporateIncomeTaxRates 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 CIT rate (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 year
8
Notes: Thisfigureplotsthetimeseriesofthecapitalshareasapercentageofnetdomesticproduct(NDP). Thesolidlinecorrespondstotheoverallcapitalshare,andthedottedlinetothecapitalsharewithinthe corporatesector.Thetopleftpanelcorrespondstotheglobalaverage,weightingcountry-yearobservations bytheirshareinthatyear’stotalNDP,inconstant2019USD(N=154).Thebottom-leftpanelshowstheresults forhigh-incomecountries,andthebottomrightforlow-andmiddle-incomecountries.Low,middleand high-incomecountriesarebasedontheWorldBankincomeclassificationin2018.Thedatasetiscomposed oftwo(quasi)balancedpanels.Thefirstcoverstheyears1965-1993andexcludescommunistregimes.The secondcovers1994-2018andintegratesformercommunistcountries,inparticularChinaandRussia.
FigureO9:CapitalShareofNetDomesticProduct
9
TableO1:NotesonTaxRevenueDataSeries
Country Years MaindatasourcesHistoricalarchive(HA)datasources
Afghanistan 2003-2018ICTD(2003-2018)
Albania 1994-2018 ICTD(1994-2018)
Algeria 1965-2017HA(1965-2017) AnnuaireStatistiquedel’Algerie
Argentina 1965-2018 HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
Armenia 1994-2018HA(1994-2018)
Australia 1965-2018 OECD(1965-2018)
Austria 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
Azerbaijan 1994-2018 ICTD(1994);HA (1995-2018)
Bahamas 1973-2018 HA(1973-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
Bahrain 1974-2018
Bangladesh 1976-2018
Barbados 1972-2018
HA(1974-1987); ICTD(1988-2018)
HA(1976-2000); ICTD(2001-2018)
HA(1972-1990); OECD(1991-2018)
Belarus 1992-2018ICTD(1993-2018)
Belgium 1965-2018
OECD(1965-2018)
Belize 1982-2018 HA(1982-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
SintesisEstadisticaMensual,Boletin MensualdeEstadistica
DataprovidedbyStatisticalCommitteeoftheRepublicuponrequest
DataretrievedfromStateStatistical Committeeonlinedatawebsite
IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics, IMFArticleIVReport
IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics, IMFArticleIVReport
BudgetBook,StatisticalDigestof Bangladesh
IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics, IMFArticleIVReport
IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics, IMFArticleIVReport
Commentsonseries
ExistsHAseries(1973-1978),butseriesisshortandtax/GDPfiguresappeartoovolatile(could notfindcorroboratingevidence);historicalICTDdataexists(1982-1989),butnodisaggregation bytaxtype
Databeginsinpost-communistperiod;existingHAdatanestedincoverageinICTD,soprefer ICTDsource(andlevelsoftaxrevenuesarecomparablebetweensources)
Taxesurchiffred’affairesclassifiedasunallocablebetweenPITandCITinHA,butitisataxon firms;’Contributionsdiverses’leftasanexcisetaxin1960s;interpolate1967,1970-1971,1974.
Historicallystabletax/GDPseries,despitemultiplepoliticalchanges,untilgrowthintaxtake in1990swhenindirecttaxexpands;interpolatedirecttaxsplit(PITvsCIT)between1961-1969 and1984-89,basedonratiosonadjacentyears;socialsecuritydatafromAlvaredo(2010)is comparabletoOECDinoverlappingyears,soispreferredhistoricalsource.
Independencein1991,butofficialpublishedrevenuedatabeginsin1994;notabledipinsocial securityinmid-2010sisgenuine,resultsfromseveralreforms(IMF,2019;Asatryan,2014).
ICTDdataismoreaccuratein1994,from1995matchesintrendsandlevelswithHAdata; independencein1991,butunrestensueduntil1994andlimitedgovernmentrecords(HArecords unreliable,GDPnumbershardtocorroborate);non-taxrevenuesaresignificant,especiallysince early2000s;spikeinCITrevenueinlate2000sreflectsgenuineeconomicshock(Aliyevand Gasimov,2016)
HistoricalHAdataisbasedonIMFsources;socialInitialdifferencebetweenHAandOECDin overlappingyearsisduetosocialsecuritycontributions(missinginHA).
HistoricalHAdataisbasedonIMFsources;changeinCITrevenuesin1970scorrespondsto nationalizationandexpropriationevents(Kobrin,1984)andtherewasnomajorchangetooil productionduringthisperiod(RossandMahdavi,2015)
Independencein1971,butreliablegovernmentdatabeginsin1976.Interpolate1980-1981;very lowdirecttaxescollectedonfirmspriorto1986reform,andsignificantCITdropin2003.
HAdataisbasedonIMFhistoricalreports;usesocialsecurityasreportedininitialsources, corroboratedwithdatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)
ICTDdataexistsin1991butitisnotdisaggregated;decreaseinCITandincreaseinindirect taxesinearly2000s,maybeduebothtoRussianfinancialcrisisandtoICTDswitchingitssource fromIMFArticleIVtoIMFGFS[flagged]
HAdataisbasedonhistoricalIMFdata;interpolate1986-1987;socialsecuritycontributions missinginHA,wetakeitfromFisunogluetal.(2011);socialsecuritystartedin1979(SSA,2015)
Benin 1965-2018 HA(1965-2018) ComptesdelaNation,StatistiquesFinancesPubliques Socialsecurityfirstimplementedin1970(SSA,2017);interpolatebetween1988and1990.
Bolivia 1965-2018 HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018) AnuarioEstadistico,BoliviaenCifras
BosniaandHerzegovina 1999-2018 ICTD(1999-2018)
1967-2018 HA(1967-1989); ICTD(1990-2003); OECD(2004-2018)
AnnualStatementsofAccounts,StatisticalAbstract,StatisticalBulletin,FinancialStatistics
UsehistoricaldatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecurity,whichstartedpriortoour time-coverage(SSA,2017);unclearwhat’complementaria’tax(1960-1970)refersto,weassignit equallytoPITandCIT;largedeclineinmid-1980sappearsgenuine(Kehoeetal.,2019)
Warendsin1995butreliabledataonlystartsin1999;importantroleoflocaltaxation(Foxand Wallich,1997;Kandeva,2001),comparedatafromICTDwithIMFGFSandZornetal.(1999) whichsuggestlocaltaxsourcesareadequatelycovered.
OECDdataismissingtradetaxes,whichwebringinfromICTDinoverlappingyears;GDP estimatesdifferinthepre-1990periodbetweenIMF,WorldBankandUN-SNAsources[flagged], weuseWorldBanksource;CITvalueinICTDin1990appearstoolarge,interpolatebasedon surroundingyears[flagged];’mineraltax’inHAdataappearstopartlyincludeCIT,predict CIT-sharebasedonprecisesplitbetweenCITandresourcetaxinothersources[flagged];social securityprogramstartsin1996accordingtoSSA(2017),howeverweobservecontributions priortothatdate(Fisunogluetal.,2011)whichmaycorrespondtoanon-contributorypension benefit(ArzaandJohnson,2006)[flagged];largeeconomicshocksin1980swhichaffectedpublic finances(O’Connell,1988).
Comparisonwithotherstudies
Polackova(1996)tax/GDPestimatein1993-1994isslightlyhigher thanours,butlikelyincludesnon-taxrevenues;WorldBank(2020) tax/GDPmatchesourestimatesfrom1995to1998.
Tax/GDPnumberscomparabletohistoricaltime-seriesfromAlvaredo(2010).
Polackova(1996)tax/GDPestimatein1993-1994isslightlyhigher thanours,butlikelyincludesnon-taxrevenues
Comparabletax/GDPnumbersinrecentperiodsbasedonWorld Bank(2020),thoughthedatainlattersourcestopsin2004.
Comparabletax/GDPnumberswithICTDinoverlappingperiods.
Consistenttax/GDPwhencomparingtoWorldBank(2013),after adjustingICTDforexistenceofsocialsecuritycontributions
Historicalsourcesarehardtofind.HAseriescomparabletohistorical IMFseriesinearlyperiods(1960-1970),anddipinlate1980sexists acrosssources.
Historicaltax/GDPnumberscomparabletoKehoeetal.(2019)and Sachs(1990),thoughlargerthannumbersreportedinThirsk(1997) in1970s[flagged].
Comparabletax/GDPnumberswithWorldBank(2020)after2005, buthighertax/GDPreportedinDingandSherif(1999)forhistorical period[flagged].
Comparablehistoricaltax/GDPbasedonTakirambudde(1995), O’Connell(1988),Bonu(1995).
Botswana
10
TableO1:NotesonTaxRevenueDataSeries
Country Years MaindatasourcesHistoricalarchive(HA)datasources
Brazil 1965-2018 HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018) AnuarioEstatisticodoBrasil
Bulgaria 1993-2018HA(1993-2018)
BurkinaFaso 1965-2018 HA(1965-1999); OECD(2000-2018)
Burundi 1965-2018HA(1965-2018)
Cambodia 1994-2018 ICTD(1994-2018)
Cameroon 1965-2018 HA(1965-1992); OECD(1993-2018).
Canada 1965-2018
CentralAfricanRepublic1965-2018
Chad 1965-2018
Chile 1965-2018
StatisticalYearbook,MonthlyStatistical Reviews
ComptesEcononomiquesdelaHauteVolta,ComptesNationauxdelaHauteVolta,LesComptesEconomiquesdela Nation
AnnuaireStatistique,BulletinStatistique
NoteTrimestriellesurlaSituation Economique,NoteAnnuelledeStatistique
OECD(1965-2018)
HA(1965-2007); ICTD(2008-2018)
HA(1965-1982); ICTD(1983-2009); OECD(2010-2018)
HA(1965-1979); ICTD(1980-2018)
BulletindeStatistique,BulletinMensueldeStatistique,AnnuaireStatistique
BulletinMensueldeStatistique,Budget Generaldel’Etat
InformeEconomicoAnual,Statistical ProfileofChile,
China 1994-2018 HA(1994-2007); OECD(2008-2018) StatisticalYearbook,onlinedata fromNationalBureauofStatistics
Colombia 1965-2018
Congo 1972-2018
HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
HA(1972-1981); ICTD(1982-1998); OECD(1999-2018)
Commentsonseries
ChallengingtofindreliableGDPdatainhistoricalperiods,usereportednationalpriceindex fromAyres(2019)priorto1990whichinturnsisbasedonBrazilianInstituteofGeography andStatistics;OECDdataappearstobehighquality,includingwithrespecttosub-nationaltax collection;corroboratesub-nationaltaxesinHAdatausingdetailedinformationfromAfonso andAraujo(2004),whichdiscusseslocalpublicfinancesince1960s,andVarsano(1999);use Fisunogluetal.(2011)priorto1980forsocialsecuritycontributions.Interpolateincometax between1968and1971and1973and1975.
Excesstaxrevenue’categoryin1995-96iscontributionfrompreviousyeartaxescollected,we checkthatithasnotbeendouble-counted[flagged];somedifferenceinsocialsecuritycontributionsbetweenUN-SNAdataandFisunogluetal.(2011),preferlattersourceasitcomparesto ICTDinoverlappingyears
Severalperiodsofpoliticalinstability(1974,1980-1983,1987)whereinterpolatedata;largetax frompropertyrightsregistrationtaxinlate1970s,appearsgenuine.
Datainterpolated1970-1973butconcernsremainaboutdataquality(violence)[flagged];IMF (1973)datasuggestslittlechangeincompositionoftaxes,thoughchangeinoveralltaxtake; historicalIMFsourcelistsataxonproperty,whichcannotbefoundinHA(whichinstead recordsatransactiontax)
HAdataexistsfrom1987to1993,butthedatahasqualityconcerns(givenpoliticaltransition), soprefernottousethatdata;socialsecuritycontributionsbeginin1997(SSA,2018),wedraw ondatafromFisunogluetal.(2011).
Interpolate1969-1970,1989;classifythe’taxeunique’asanindirecttax,ratherthandirectfirm tax,basedoninformationfromGauthieretal.(2002);dropinoverallrevenuein1980sconfirmed tobemainlyrelatedtodwindlingtradetaxes(GauthierandGersovitz,1997);declineinwealth taxesbetween1968and1993isnotaccountedforviaadditionalsources[flagged];socialsecurity contributionsstartin1968(SSA,2017),wedrawdatafromFisunogluetal.(2011);significant generalvolatilityofrevenueslikelydrivenbyrelianceonvolatilecommodities(deHerdt,2002).
VaillancourtandKerkhoff(2019)foradditionalinformationonthecapitalshareofPIT
Politicalunrestinearlyhistoricalperiodscreateuncertaintyarounddata[flagged];the’tax additionnelle’inthe1960swasadirecttaxonfirmsratherthanindividuals(Mbounou-Ngopo, 2019);dipsintaxcollectioninmid-1990scoincidewithpoliticaltransitions.HAdatafeatures changeinterminology1994-1997,whichcoulderroneouslybeinterpretedasasubstitutionfrom directtoindirecttaxes;socialsecuritystartedin1963(SSA,2019),wedrawonFisunogluetal. (2011)forentireHAperiod.
Militaryrulefrom1975-1978andcivilwarfrom1979-1982,interpretdatawithcautionduring theseperiods[flagged];socialsecurityprogrambeganin1977(SSA,2017),drawondatafrom Fisunogluetal.(2011)priortoOECDcoverage;volatilityinrecentyearsisnotablebutappears tobegenuine(foundinbothOECDandICTDdata).
Themorerecentdata(1990-2018)isfromInter-AmericanDevelopmentBank;interpolate197879;dataqualityischallengedduring1970-1973period,thetransitionyearsforAllende[flagged]; useinformationfromMamalakis(1978)andCorbo(1989)toconfirmHAdatasplitbetweenCIT andPIT,theextentofsub-nationaltaxes,andtheexistenceofsocialsecuritycontributions.
SeeAppendixBformoredetailsonsourcesandtaxsystem;dataexistspriorto1994,butwestart theseriesafterthetransitionawayfromcentralplanning(conceptualdifficultieswithdefining certainrevenuesourcesastaxesinthepre-transitionperiod);HAandOECDmatchwellin overlappingyears.
Comparisonwithotherstudies
Historicaltax/GDPnumberscomparabletoAfonsoandAraujo (2004),Chelliah(1971)-bothofwhichcovernationalandsub-national revenues.
Comparabletax/GDPnumbersinearlyperiodsbasedonBogeticand Hassan(1997),matchWorldBank(2020)inlateryears.
Comparabletax/GDPnumberswithICTDinoverlappingperiods.
Tax/GDPnumberscomparabletoGauthier,SoloagaandTybout (2002).
Observeddecreaseintax/GDPinrecentperiodsalsoconfirmedin IMFreports(IMF,2016).Difficulttofindhistoricalsourcestocorroborate.
Tax/GDPestimateinearlyhistoricalperiod(1965)approximately1.5 percentagepointslowerthanreportedinLotzandMorss(1967).
SocialsecuritydatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)inagreementwith historicaldatafromCerda(2005).Historicaltax/GDPratiocomparabletovaluesreportedinWorldBank(1980).
Tax/GDPcomparabletovaluesreportedinLouandWang(2008) andICTD.
EstadisticasFiscales,CifrasFiscales,InformeFinanciero
AnnuaireStatistique,BulletinMensuel deStatistique,EconomicSurvey
CostaRica 1965-2018 HA(1965-1987); OECD(1988-2018) AnuarioEstadistico,MemoriaAnnual
Goodmatchinlevelswhensourcesoverlap;special’proequityincometax’,initiallyclassifiedas unallocablebetweenPITandCITinOECDdata,isinfactataxoncorporateincome(WorldBank, 2014);concernifwearecapturingallsub-nationaltaxesintheHAperiod(basedonArroyo-Abad andLindert,2016)[flagged];socialsecuritydatamissinginHAperiod[flagged].
Interpolatebetween1977and1979;yearofoverlapbetweenICTDandOECDcoincideswith periodofgenuinedropinrevenues,duetoviolence.
UseIMFhistoricaldatabetween1974and1987,matcheswillinoverlappingyearswithbothHA andOECD;lowCITrevenuecollectedinthe1980sisconfirmedinShome(1992);socialsecurity contributionsarefromFisunogluetal.(2011).
McClurecitesatax/GDPin1980whichis3percentagepointshigher thanourHAestimate,thoughourestimatesagreewithMitchell (2003)intheperiod1965-1989.
Historicaltax/GDPvaluesarebroadlyinlinewithTaitetal.(1979) forthe1970s.
Comparablehistoricaltax/GDPcomparedtoTaitetal.(1979).
11
TableO1:NotesonTaxRevenueDataSeries
Country Years MaindatasourcesHistoricalarchive(HA)datasources
Coted’Ivoire 1965-2018 HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
Croatia 1996-2018ICTD(1996-2018)
Cuba 1990-2018 OECD(1990-2018)
BulletinMensueldeStatistique,Les ComptesdelaNation,BudgetGeneral deFonctionnement,
Cyprus 1972-2018HA(1972-2018) AnnualBudget
CzechRepublic 1993-2018 OECD(1993-2018)
DemocraticRepublicofthe Congo 1968-2018 HA(1968-1990); ICTD(1991-2018) ConjonctureEconomique
Denmark 1965-2018
DominicanRepublic 1968-2018
Ecuador 1973-2018
Egypt 1965-2018
OECD(1965-2018)
HA(1968-1989); OECD(1990-2018) EjecucionPresupuesto
HA(1973-1989); OECD(1990-2018) CuentasNacionalesdelEcuador
HA(1965-1989); ICTD(1990-2001); OECD(2002-2018) AnnuaireStatistique
ElSalvador 1965-2018
HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
EquatorialGuinea 1981-2018 ICTD(1981-2004); OECD(2005-2018)
Estonia 1993-2018 ICTD(1993-1994); OECD(1995-2018)
Ethiopia 1965-2018
Fiji 1972-2018
AnuarioEstadistico,IndicadoresEconomicosySociales
HA(1965-1992); OECD(1993-2018). StatisticalAbstract
HA(1972-1989); ICTD(1990-2007); OECD(2008-2018)
Finland 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
France 1965-2018 OECD(1965-2018)
Gabon 1965-2018
Gambia 1972-2018
IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics, IMFArticleIVReport
HA(1965-1985); ICTD(1986-2018)
AnnuaireStatistiqueduGabon,Tableau deBorddel’Economie
HA(1972-1987); ICTD(1988-2018)
EstimatesofRecurrentRevenueandExpenditure,GambiaStatisticalYearbook
Commentsonseries
Interpolate1977-1979,1987-1989;inHAyearswhereindividualversusfirmsplitexistsfor’tax onbenefices’,assumesameratioinallotheryearswheresametaxdoesnothavebreakdown; OECDdataappearstounder-estimatePITinrecentyears,useinformationfromIMFandICTD toadjustlevel[flagged].
HAdataexistsbuthaslesscompletecoveragethanICTDbytypeoftax;ICTDalsoappearsto havecapturedwellsub-nationaltaxes(IMF,2020).
HAdataexistsinsomeofthehistoricalOECDperiods,butprefertodrawalldatafromasingle source
HistoricalIMFdatabetween1972and1989,thenHAforremainingperiods;supplementHA withFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecuritycontributions;Lent(1977)confirmsexistenceof corporateincometaxin1970s.
Somedifferencebetweensourcesinoverlappingyears,coincideswithperiodofhighinflation andsignificantseignioragetax(DeHerdt,2002;Nachega,2005)[flagged];between1977and 1990,taxtypecalled’divers’whichisinitiallyunallocablebetweenPITandCIT[flagged];likely thatwecapturelocaltaxrevenuesinhistoricalperiods.Interpolate1973,1992-1995.
Specificityinhowsocialsecuritycontributionsarelevied(throughthePIT,unlikeinmanyother countries)
OmissionofindirecttaxcategoriesinHAinlate1970sandlate1980s-interpolatebasedon surroundingyears[flagged];givenunrestinearly1960s,webeginourseriesin1968.
MinistryofFinance(2016)dataincludesbreakdownbetweenresourceandnon-resourcerevenuesinhistoricalperiods,whichsuggestthatourHAdatasometimesincludesresourcerevenues[flagged]-usehistoricalIMFdatainlimitedsetsofyearstocorrectthedirectfirmincome taxnumbersinHA.
HAandICTDdatamatchverywellinoverlappingyear;forperiodspriortoOECD,useFisunoglu etal.(2011)tomeasuresocialsecuritycontributions;interpolate1965-67,1970-1971,and19731974;sharpdropinrevenuein1980sisgenuine;difficulttoensureCITdoesnotinpartcapture resourcerevenues,astheygrewinimportancein1970s[flagged];inyears2002-2008,’taxon movablecapitalrevenuesfromCentralBank’appearstobeunallocablebetweenCITandPIT, weassignsharesbasedoninformationinWaterbury(2014).
Significantcurrencyreformin2001,interprettax/GDPnumberwithcautioninthatyear [flagged],andweadjustthecurrencyinprioryearstobecomparable;socialsecuritycontributionsbeganin1959(SSA,2017),weusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)inyearspriorto OECDcoverage,whichwassubstantial(Grosh,1990).
Verylimiteddirecttaxescollectedpriortoearly2000s,corroboratedinSame(2008);historically strongrelianceonrevenuesfromcommodityexports(HumanRightsWatch,2017);socialsecurity firstimplementedin1947(SSA,2017),weusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011).
Russianpresenceonlyphasedoutby1993;goodmatchbetweensourcesinoverlappingyears
Incometaxonlyseparatespersonalfrombusinessincomestartingin1975;perSchwab(1970), incometaxschedulespriortothenincludedbothindividualandfirmincome-sowekeepthe initiallyunallocablecategory;ourHArecordoflandusefeessuggestswearecapturingsubnationaltaxes;Chloe(1984)notestherelianceoncommodityexports,whichinducesvolatilityin taxrevenues;verylimitedquantityofsocialsecuritycontributionsincomparisonwithMengistu etal.(2017)[flagged].Interpolate1989,2005.
HAdataderivesfromhistoricalIMFdata;useFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecuritycontributions,whichbeganin1966(SSA,2016);disappearanceofpropertytaxesbetween1992and 2010,thoughconsistentlymissinginbothICTDandOECDsources[flagged]
ConfidentthatHAsourcesexcludesresourcerevenues,comparisonwithhistoricalIMFdata; interpolate1977-1980;severalhistoricaltaxesunallocablebetweenCITandPIT,including’impot generalsurlerevenue’,forwhichhistoricalsourcesarenotinformative(Abdel-Rahman,1965); socialsecuritycontributionsbeganin1963(SSA,2019),wedrawondatafromFisunogluetal. (2011).
Startdatain1972,ascurrencychangein1971introducesmeasurementchallenges;atsame time,continuedmacro-economicvolatilitymeansdatapriorto1990shouldbeinterpretedwith caution[flagged]
Comparisonwithotherstudies
Comparablelevelsoftax/GDPinWorldBank(2020).
Comparabletax/GDPlevelstoLent(1977).
TrendsintaxationbysourceinhistoricalHAperiodsisconsistent withEmziet(1997).
HistoricalIMFdataagreeswithHAestimatesin1970s.
CEPAL(1991)corroboratestaxrevenuelevelsin1979-1987,including thespikein1985.GarciaandUquilles(1992)confirmlevelsin19891992period.
Smith(1970)andNyrop(1976)corroboratelowlevelofPITin1960s andearly1970s.Mitchell(2003)differsonaverageby10%fromour tax/GDPestimates.
Estimatesoftax/GDPin1980sand1990sveryclosetonumbers reportedinCardemiletal.(2000).
Ourtax/GDPnumbersinearlytransitionperiodmatcheswellwith Polackova(1996).
CompareswellwithMascagni(2016)forhistoricaltax/GDPin1960s1980s,seriesarewithinonepercentagepointofeachother.
Limitedhistoricalsources,thoughdropinrevenuein1980siscorroboratedinGaulme(1991)andYates(1996).
Tax/GDPestimatesinHAarecomparabletoAnsari(1982),about 18%loweronaverage.Jallow(2016)provideshistoricalaccountof taxsystem,butnodataontax/GDP.
12
TableO1:NotesonTaxRevenueDataSeries
Country Years MaindatasourcesHistoricalarchive(HA)datasources
Georgia 1994-2018ICTD(1994-2018)
Germany 1965-2018 OECD(1965-2018)
Ghana 1967-2018 HA(1967-1999); OECD(2000-2018) QuarterlyDigestofStatistics
Greece 1965-2018 OECD(1965-2018)
Guatemala 1965-2018 HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
Guinea 1980-2018 ICTD(1980-2018)
Guyana 1972-2018
Haiti 1975-2018
Honduras 1973-2018
HA(1972-1986); ICTD(1987-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
HA(1975-1989); ICTD(1990-2018)
EstadisticasdeFinanzasPublicasde Guatemala
Commentsonseries
Socialsecuritycontributions,intheircurrentform,beganin1990(SSA,2010),wedrawondata fromFisunogluetal.(2011);interpolatesocialsecuritybetween1995and1997.
Verygoodmatchbetweensourcesinoverlappingyears,onceaccountforsocialsecuritycontributions;removerevenuefromgovernmentpropertiesinHAhistoricalperiods(initiallycounted within’taxoninterestandprofits);volatilepatternsin1980sconfirmedinDarko-Oseiand Telli(2017),coincidingwitheconomicturbulenceandIMFrecoveryandstructuraladjustment agreements.
OECDclassifiessolidaritytaxasunallocable,since1995,butitisataxoncorporations(PriceWaterhouseCooper,2020);historicaldataonsocialsecuritycontributionsfromFisunogluetal. (2011)seemunreliableinthiscase,sowereportsuchtaxesfrom1978onward[flagged].
Revenuemovementsin1980scoincidewithpoliticaltransitionandnewfiscalregimeunder Conte(Yansane,1990);Topouzis(1989)notestherisingimportanceofresourcerevenue,which maybecapturedinsideourCITcategorybetween1985and1992[flagged].
IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics, IMFArticleIVReport
TableaudesOperationsFinancieresde l’Etat
HA(1973-1989); OECD(1990-2018) AnuarioEstadistico
Hungary 1994-2018 OECD(1994-2018)
Iceland 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
India 1965-2018 HA(1965-2019)
Indonesia 1965-2018
MonthlyAbstractofStatistics,Indian PublicFinanceStatistics
HA(1965-1996); OECD(1997-2018) StatistikIndonesia
Iran 1969-2018 HA(1969-2018) AnnualBudget,IranStatisticalYearbook
Ireland 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
Israel 1972-2018 HA(1972-1992); OECD(1993-2018) AccountantGeneral’sReport,IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics
Italy 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
Jamaica 1965-2018 HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
Japan 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
Jordan 1973-2018 HA(1973-1989); ICTD(1990-2018)
StatisticalYearbookofJamaica,Abstract ofStatistics
AnnualReport,YearlyStatisticalSeries, MonthlyStatisticalBulletin
HAisdrawnfromIMFsources;dropinrevenueatendof1980sisgenuine,likelyreflects economicturbulenttimes(consistentnumbersacrosssources);initialdifferenceacrosssources inoverlappingyearsisduetoICTDdatanotaccountingforsocialsecuritycontributions.
HAdatadrawsonhistoricalIMFreports;interpolate1988-1989,thoughshouldbeinterpreted withcautiongivenviolenceattime[flagged];spikein1987isdrivenbycollapseinunderlying valueofGDP;socialsecuritybeginsin1965(SSA,2017),wedrawonFisunogluetal.(2011); propertyandtransactiontaxesexistinHA,smallinmagnitude,butaremissingfromICTDdata [flagged].
1974isacomplicatedyearduetomissingtypesoftaxes,soweinterpolateit;jumpinrevenues aroundyearofoverlapbetweenOECDandHA,butHerrera(1994)corroboratessignificant changesintaxperformanceatthattime;usesocialsecuritydatafromFisunogluinallyearsprior toOECDcoverage.
WorldBank(2020)corroboratesspikeinnon-recurrentpropertytaxesobservedin2016;infer, basedonHerdandThorgeirsson(2001)andKarlsson(2014),assignportionofinitiallyunallocableOECDrevenuetoindividuals.
InHA,’incometaxotherthanCIT’isnotexclusivelyataxonindividuals,weuseadditional informationtoassignthiscategorytofirmsversusindividuals(includingRao,2005);HAdata carefullyrecordsacomprehensivesetofwealthandpropertytaxes,includingforland;reasonablyconfidentHAcapturessub-nationaltaxes;socialsecuritycontributions,verysmallin magnitude,appeartobereportedinsideindividualincometaxcategory[flagged].
Strongmatchfordatainoverlappingyearsbetweensources;1983reformcollapsedmultiple taxes(CIT,PIT,otherdirectincome)intoasingleschedule,soweusesharesofcapitalversus labordirectincometaxesin1983andassignsuchsharesuntil1997[flagged];reasonableability toexcluderesourcerevenuesinHAdata.Interpolate1968-1971,1994.
Reasonableabilitytoexcluderesourcerevenues;socialsecuritydatainHAandinICTDare unreliable,weinsteaddrawdatafromUN-SNA,startingin1996[flagged];datastrictlybased oncentralgovernment,butnodocumentationsuggestssub-nationaltaxesarequantitatively important.
HAdrawsinpartfromhistoricalIMFdata;interpolate1992-1994;someIMFdatareportedin 1970sseemsapproximate[flagged];historicalIMFmissespropertytaxinsomeyears,supplement withICTDdata.
Propertytaxesdipin1997,butthisappearsgenuine(intheOECDdata,basedonlocalpublic financerecords);unallocablepartofdirectincometaxesissignificantinthe1980s,comprising amixoftaxesondividends,interestandan’educationtax’since1983(GovernmentofJamaica, 1988),andweuseadditionalinformationfromInter-AmericanCenterofTaxAdministratorsto assignittofirmsversusworkers;
Comparisonwithotherstudies
BarboneandPolackova(1996)havecomparabletax/GDPestimates for1995,onceourseriesareadjustedforsocialsecuritycontributions.
Reasonablecomparisonfortax/GDPnumbersinhistoricalperiods, asreportedinChelliah(1971),LotzandMorss(1967),Killick(1978) andDarko-OseiandTelli(2017).
Tax/GDPestimatesinearlyhistoricalyears(1965-1967)liewithin onepercentagepointofnumbersfromLotzandMorss(1967).
Dioda(2012)estimatessimilartax/GDPin1990,Tanzi(2000)estimatesslightlyhighertax/GDPbetween1993and1999.
HistoricalIMFdataarecomparabletoHAnumbersfortax/GDPin the1980s.
Verycomparabletax/GDPestimateinearliestperiodswithRao (2005);alsoconsistentwithrecentestimatesinWorldBank(2019).
Multiplesourcesestimateverylowhistoricaltax/GDPratios(1960s and1990s),between2and8percentagepoints(Prasetyo,2018;Gillis, 1985;Amiretal.,2013),generallyconsistentwithourestimates
Inoverlappingperiod(1979-1989),ourtax/GDPestimatesandtrend matchverycloselywithMazarei(1996).Generallylimitedstudiesin Englishonhistoricaltaxsystemincountry.
Historicaltrendsin1980sand1990sarecorroboratedinBrender (2007),thoughtheleveloftax/GDPisapproximately15%higher thanourestimates.
Historicalestimatesoftax/GDPin1960sand1970sare10-18%larger thanours(Chelliah,1971;Shome,1992).
HAuseshistoricalIMFdata;atyearofmergebetweensources,Abu-Hammour(1997)confirms alargeincreaseintax/GDP;non-taxrevenuesaresignificantinthecountry,butoursourcescan reasonablyexcludethem. HAdatamatchesverycloselythenumbersinAbu-Hammour(1997).
13
TableO1:NotesonTaxRevenueDataSeries
Country Years MaindatasourcesHistoricalarchive(HA)datasources
Kazakhstan 1993-2018 ICTD(1993-1998); OECD(1999-2018)
Kenya 1965-2018 HA(1965-2000); OECD(2001-2018) StatisticalAbstract
Korea 1965-2018 HA(1965-1971); OECD(1972-2018) KoreaStatisticalYearbook
Kosovo 2008-2018
Kuwait 1972-2018
HA(2008-2015); OECD(2016-2018)
DataretrievedfromDepartmentof FinanceandGeneralServices
HA(1972-1989); ICTD(1990-2018) GovernmentFinanceStatistics
Kyrgyzstan 1994-2018 ICTD(1994-2018)
Laos 1982-2018 ICTD(1982-2009); OECD(2009-2018)
Latvia 1994-2018 OECD(1994-2018)
Lebanon 1965-2018
HA(1965-2018); ICTD(1988-2001)
RecueildeStatististiquesLibanaises, StatisticalYearbook
Lesotho 1965-2018 HA(1966-1981); ICTD(1982-2018) StatisticalBulletin
Liberia 1970-2018 HA(1970-1988); ICTD(2000-2018)
EconomicSurvey,QuarterlyStatistical BulletinofLiberia,StatisticalBulletinof Liberia
Lithuania 1991-2018 HA(1991-1994); OECD(1995-2018) LithuaniaStatisticsYearbook
Luxembourg 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
Macedonia 1993-2018 ICTD(1993-2018)
Madagascar 1965-2018 HA(1965-1989); ICTD(1990-2018)
Malawi 1965-2018 HA(1965-2004); OECD(2005-2018)
Malaysia 1965-2018
Mali 1965-2018
InventaireSocio-Economique,Malagasy Budget,BudgetGeneraldel’Etat
MalawiStatisticalYearbook,CompendiumofStatistics,EconomicReport
HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018) EconomicReport
HA(1965-1979); ICTD(1980-1999); OECD(2000-2018) ComptesEconomiquesduMali,AnnuaireStatistique
Commentsonseries
Independencein1991,butICTDcoveragebeginsin1993;socialsecuritycontributionsbeganin 1991,weusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011);volatilityinindirecttaxrevenuesissignificant butplausible(WorldBank,2017).
Toassigninitiallyunallocabledirecttaxbetweenfirmsandindividuals,weuseinformationfrom Jetha(1966)andWanjala(2006)ontheincometaxschedules;gradualincreaseintax/GDPover thelongrunobservedinMachaetal.(2018)andOmondietal.(2014);possiblethatwearenot capturingsub-nationaltaxesinHAdata[flagged]
Goodmatchinlevelsforyearsofoverlap;interpolatefrom1968to1971;overalllowlevelsof revenueinthe1960saregenuineandreflectgovernmentpolicy;onlyaftermajortaxreformin 1967didtaxcollectionstarttosignificantlygrow(Yoo,2000);observedchangesincapitaltaxes collectedin1970saregenuine(KwackandLee,1992)
Governmentdatapriorto2008isscarce;accordingtoKoshutova(2004)andKritzer(2005), pensionsystemisfundedthroughgeneraltaxation;levelofCITasashareofGDPisconfirmed inHernandezetal.(2019)
Interpolate1975-1976;donotobservesocialsecuritycontributionsinHA,butitisplaceinhistoricalyears(SSA,2016),soweusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011);largeresourcenationalization in1975,firms’incometaxdatafrom1972to1975shouldbeinterpretedwithcaution[flagged]
Datacoverageofpropertyandwealthtaxesonlybeginsin1995,butwecouldnotfindahistorical sourcetoconfirmifthisreflectsapolicyimplementation[flagged]
Whilesocialsecuritycontributionshaveexistedsince2001(SSA,2016),thereisnodatacovering thesecontributions[flagged];significantnon-taxsourcesofrevenueinthe1980s(Saignasith, 1997)
ICTDdataexistspriortoOECDcoverage,butitisnotdisaggregatedanddifficulttoreconcile withOECDnumbersinoverlappingyears.
SeriesusesHAdata,withICTDdatabetween1988and2001;turbulenttaxcollectionduringcivil warperiod(1975-1990),whereinformationinDimashkieh(1993)andHoury(1997)confirmthe levelsoftaxesbytype;socialsecuritycontributionsbeganin1963,weusedatafromFisunoglu etal.(2011);useinformationfromEkenetal.(1995)toconfirmlevelofCITcollectedpriorto 1993.
Datamissingin1978-1981,butduetounrestweleavedataempty(ratherthaninterpolate);spike inrevenuein1977iscorroboratedacrossdata-sets;licensingfeesconstituteslargesourceof revenueinearliestperiods(Cobbe,1981).
Importantgapincoveragebetween1988and2000-aturbulentperiodduringwhichrevenues werecollectedbutdivertedfromofficialuseandGDPdecreasedby90%(Atkinson,1997);drop inrevenuein1973-1974isgenuine.
Socialsecuritybeginsin1991,weusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011).
Interpolateincometaxesfrom2003to2005;SSA(2005)confirmsthatsocialsecuritycontributions aresignificantinthecountry.
Interpolate1969-1971,notingthepoliticalinstabilityin1972,1974-1976,and1981-1983;usesocial securitydatafromFisunogluetal.(2011),startingin1965(SSA,2018)thoughdatafrom1965to 1969maybeestimatedinoriginalsource[flagged].
SocialsecuritycontributionsmissinginOECD,soweusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)for entireperiod,whichweresignificantinmorehistoricalperiods;spikeinPITrevenuein2001is genuine,likelyreflectstaxenforcementreforms;ShaliziandThirsk(1990)emphasizethatdirect incometaxeswereasignificantshareoftotaltaxesinthe1960s.
Interpolate1979-1980and1988,duetomissingHAdata;usesocialsecuritycontributionsdata fromFisunogluetal.(2011),butunreliableinperiodfrom1972to1980[flagged];totallevels matchwellinoverlappingyearsbetweenOECDandHA,highlightsthatthestampduty,which OECDclassifiesinas’othertax’,isclassifiedasunallocableincometaxinHA;dropinindirect taxesinlate1980sisgenuine.
LevelsmatchwellinoverlappingyearsbetweenHAandICTD,lendsconfidencetoHAsources eventhoughwecannotfindmultiplehistoricalsourcestocorroborate(Founou-Tchuigoua,1989); socialsecuritycontributionsbeginin1961(SSA,2019),weusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011); OECDlistsnocorporatetaxin2000,thoughICTDdoes[flagged].
Comparisonwithotherstudies
Ourtax/GDPestimatesaresystematicallysmallerby2percentage pointsinthe1960sand1970scomparedtootherestimates(Wanyagathi,2015;KanjiandWanjala,2005),butthismayalsobedueto differencesintheunderlyingestimateofGDP(ourGDPestimates basedonWIDarelargerthanWorldBankestimates).
Tax/GDPestimatereportedinmid-1960sisapproximately1percentagepointhigherthanourdata.
Goodhistoricalmatchintax/GDPandsourcesfor1972-1976when comparedtoNyrop(1977).
Estimatesoftax/GDPinthe1990sareveryclosetodatareportedin BokrosandDethier(1998)andBarboneandPolackova(1996).
HistoricalestimatesinSaignasith(1997)arelargerthanourdata,but thosefiguresalsoreportfortotalrevenues(ratherthantotaltaxes).
Highlevelsoftax/GDPin1994-1995arecorroboratedinPolackova (1996).
HistoricalestimatesinSaleh(2004)arecomparabletoourseriesduringturbulentperiod(1975-1990).
Tax/GDPestimatesfromourdataare2percentagepointslowerin the1970sthanthenumbersreportedinCobbe(1981).
Levelsoftax/GDP,bothbeforeandafterthedata-gap,arecomparabletoestimatesinDaviesandDessy(2016).
Highlevelsoftax/GDPin1993-1994iscorroboratedinPolackova (1996).
Excludingsocialsecurity,tax/GDPlevelsarecomparabletoestimates since2005inWorldBank(2020).
Historicalestimatesoftax/GDPareslightlylowerthaninChipeta (1998)andShaliziandThirsk(1990),thoughthismayalsobedueto differencesinGDPvalues.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Limitedhistoricalsources;ourestimatesarecomparabletoFounouTchuigoua(1989)forperiod1981-1989.
14
TableO1:NotesonTaxRevenueDataSeries
Country Years MaindatasourcesHistoricalarchive(HA)datasources
Mauritania 1986-2018
HA(1986-2006); OECD(2007-2018)
AnnuaireStatistique,BulletindelaDirectiondelaStatistiqueetdesEtudes Economiques
Mauritius 1973-2018 HA(1973-1989); OECD(1990-2018) DigestofStatistics
Mexico 1965-2018 HA(1965-1979); OECD(1980-2018)
Moldova 1992-2018 ICTD(1992-2018)
Mongolia 1994-2018ICTD(1994-2018)
AnuarioEstadisticodelosEstados UnidosMexicanos
Morocco 1965-2018 HA(1965-1999); OECD(2000-2018) AnnuaireStatististiqueduMaroc
Mozambique 1975-2018 HA(1975-2014); ICTD(2015-2018) InformacaoEstatistica
1991-2018 HA(1991-2018)
EstimateofRevenueandExpenditurefor theFinancialYear
Nepal 1976-2018 HA(1976-2005); ICTD(2006-2018) StatisticalYearbookofNepal
Netherlands 1965-2018
OECD(1965-2018)
NewZealand 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
Nicaragua 1965-2018
Niger 1965-2018
Nigeria 1965-2018
HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018) CompendioEstadistico
HA(1965-1999); OECD(2000-2018) AnnuaireStatistique,BudgetAnnuel,
HA(1965-1991); ICTD(1992-2009); OECD(2010-2018) AnnualAbstractofStatistics
Norway 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
Commentsonseries
LevelsmatchwellinoverlappingyearsbetweenHAandOECD;’autresdroits’inHAislisted asincometaxinOECD,sowefollowthatassignmentinHA;interpolatemissingindirecttaxes in2000and2007-2008;limitedhistoricalsources,1986appearstobefirstyearthegovernment preparedacomprehensivebudgetstatement(Handloff,1990).
HAdrawsonhistoricalIMFdata;historicalgovernmentpublicationsmatchonlevelstoIMF data,butislesscompleteinyearsofcoverage;usedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocial securitycontributionspriortoOECDcoverage.
Interpolatesocialsecuritycontributions1973-1976;largeincreaseinindirecttaxesinearly1980s isgenuine(drivenbypolicyreforms),asisthedropinincometaxesin1980;initiallyunallocableincometax’impuestosobrelarenta’pre-1970(Aguilar,2003),assignsharestofirmsand individualsbasedondatapost-1970;unclearifwecapturesub-nationaltaxespre-1970[flagged].
ICTDmissesrevenuefromproperty-transactiontaxes,whichweretrievewithHAsources;use socialsecuritydatafromFisunogluetal.(2011),startingin1992.
ICTDdatagoesbackto1986,butdoesnotdisaggregateincometax;accordingtoIMFsources, capitalgainstaxisataxoncorporations;incorporateadditionaldataonproperty-wealthtaxes fromHAsources,initiallymissinginICTD;significant’othertax’categorybetween1993and 2011(includingstampduties,royalties,landtransactions),andimportantnon-taxrevenues.
SpikesinCITin1975and2009appeargenuine;’droitsd’enregistrement’inHAareclassifiedas propertytaxes;socialsecuritycontributionsbeganin1959,yetarenotobservableinHA,sowe drawdatafromFisunogluetal.(2011);interpolate1966,1971-1973,1995.
Interpolate1991and2001;useinformationfromFjeldstadandHeggstad(2010)toassignincome taxestofirmsversusindividualsinperiod2003-2009,andCastroetal.(2009)for1993-2007 period;HAsourcesforsocialsecurityraiseconcerns,sousedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011); dropinrevenuein2014-2015appearsgenuine,basedonoverlapofdatabetweenHAandICTD.
Startdatain1991,givenpoliticalinstabilityinprioryears(fullindependenceachieved),though ICTDdataexistsinmorehistoricalyears;perfectmatchinoverlappingyearswithICTDdata forindirecttaxes,thoughHAestimatesofincometaxesare1percentagepointofGDPhigher [flagged].
Matchinoveralltax/GDPlevelbetweenHAandICTDinoverlappingyears,butdiscrepancy inlevelbytypeoftax-thisisbecauseICTDclassifies’exciseonindustrialproduct’asindirect taxwhileHAclassifiesascorporateincometax[flagged];socialsecurityprogrambeganin1962 (SSA,2017),weusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011);dropinPITandCITin2005aresignificant, havenotfoundadditionalsourcestocorroborate;property-wealthtaxesareaminusculefraction oftaxesin2005(HA),anddisappearentirelyinICTD(2006)[flagged].
Existsinitiallyunallocableincometaxes(category1300inOECDclassification),butastheyare taxesoninterest,dividendsandwithholding(onnon-residents’passiveinvestmentincome),we attributethemtocapitalratherthanlabor,minusculeinmagnitude.
HAuseshistoricalIMFdatainperiod1972-1989;multiplecurrencyre-denominationsandrevaluationsthataffecttax/GDPestimatesinlate1980sandearly1990s[flagged],butwecorroborate withhistoricalsources-includingthespectacularspikein1980s(Machado,2010;Irvinand Croes,1987;Gibson,1996);socialsecuritypolicybeganin1956(SSA,2017),weusedatafrom Fisunogluetal.(2011).
Interpolate1969-1972;usedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecuritycontributionsprior toOECDcoverage,firstpolicyimplementedin1967(SSA,2017);HAandOECDmatchinyear ofoverlap,whichcouldsuggestlowlevelsinHAin1999aregenuine;tax’surunrole’between 1975and1998isassignedtoPIT;useinformationfromOECDinoverlappingyearswithHAto assign’autresrecettesfiscales’inHAin1999.
Interpolatepersonalincometaxesbetween1987and1990,interpolateoveralltaxes2008-2009; importantconcernsaboutextenttowhichresourcerevenuesaretrulyexcludedinHAseries, butmatchinlevelsisreasonablewithICTDinoverlappingyears[flagged];personalincometax representsminusculeshareoftotaltaxesin1980s,corroboratedinIBFD(2016);dropinindirect taxesbetween1965and1969appearsgenuine,relatedtopolicyreforms.
Corroboratesignificantcomponentofcorporateincometaxwhichreflectsvariationinproduction ofoilandgas.
Comparisonwithotherstudies
Limitedhistoricalsources;OualalouandJaidi(1986)discusslow overalllevelsoftaxcollectionhistorically,andWorldBank(2020) providesnodataonthecountry.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
OveralllevelsoftaxesmatchthehistoricalestimatesinMartinezVasquez(2001)forperiod1980-1999.
Tax/GDPlevelcomparablein1993toestimatesreportedinBarbone andPolackova(1996).
Comparabletax/GDPestimatesinWorldBank(2020),thoughthisis notsurprisinggivensimilarinitialdata-sources.
CITlevelsin1980sand1990sarecomparabletothosereportedby MinistryofFinance(2011).
Limitedhistoricalsources;ourhistoricalestimatesfor1993-2007are comparabletoLemgruberetal.(2010)andCastroetal.(2009).
Comparabletax/GDPestimatesfromWorldBank(2020).
Overallgoodmatchintax/GDPlevelswithWorldBank(2020), thoughlimitedcomparisonsavailableinearliesthistoricalperiods.
Mostimportantly,comparabletax/GDPestimatesineconomicturbulentperiodof1980s(Ocampo,1990;Machado,2010).
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Estimatesoftax/GDPinearly1990sareapproximately1percentage pointlowerthaninExpoandNdebbio(1996)andBaunsgaardetal. (2012).
Namibia
15
TableO1:NotesonTaxRevenueDataSeries
Country Years MaindatasourcesHistoricalarchive(HA)datasources
Oman 1972-2014 HA(1972-1989); ICTD(1990-2014) StatisticalYearbook
Pakistan 1965-2018HA(1965-2018)
Panama 1973-2018
PapuaNewGuinea 1976-2018
Paraguay 1965-2018
HA(1973-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
HA(1976-1999); OECD(2000-2018)
HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
DetailedStatementofRevenueReceipts, StateBankofPakistanAnnualReport StatisticalSupplement
IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics, IMFArticleIVReport
CompendiumofStatistics,Summaryof Statistics,EstimatesofRevenueandExpenditurefortheYear
AnuarioEstadistico
Peru 1965-2018
Philippines 1965-2018
HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018)
HA(1965-1993); OECD(1994-2018)
Poland 1991-2018OECD(1991-2018)
Portugal 1965-2018 OECD(1965-2018)
Qatar 2000-2018ICTD(2000-2018)
Romania 1991-2018 ICTD(1991-2018)
Russia 1994-2018 HA(1994-1999); ICTD(2000-2018)
Rwanda 1967-2018 HA(1967-1995); OECD(1996-2018)
Samoa 1983-2018 ICTD(1983-2004); OECD(2005-2018)
SaudiArabia 1994-2018 ICTD(1994-2018)
AnuarioEstadistico
PhilippineStatisticalYearbook,Annual Budget,AnnualReportoftheCommissionerofInternalRevenue
HAuseshistoricalIMFdata,generalagreementwithotherhistoricalHAsourcesbutIMFdata carefullyandconsistentlyexcludesresourcerevenues;missingproperty-wealthtaxesinICTD [flagged],thoughHAseriessuggestsverysmallinmagnitude;additionalinformationusedto corroborateabsenceofpersonalincometaxrevenues(KPMG,2013);sharpdipin1990-2000 appearsgenuine;significantnationalizationreformsin1972,makingdatapriortothoseevents hardtoharmonize.
Combineseveralgovernmentpublicationstoensurewecapturenationalandsub-nationaltaxes inallperiods,withthelatteranimportantsourceoftotaltaxes(Hasan,1997);’incometax otherthancorporationtax’isnotentirelyPIT(similarchallengeinclassificationinIndia),use additionalinformationfromspecificyearstoassignshareswithinthiscategorytofirmsversus individuals.
HAuseshistoricalIMFdata;initiallyunallocablerevenuebetweenPITandCITinIMF,use additionalinformationfromGomezandSabaini(2005)andShome(1994)toallocate;declinein revenueinmid-1980sisgenuine,likelyreflectspoliticaltransitionandviolence.
Socialsecuritycontributionsstartedin1980(SSA,2016),usedatafroFisunogluetal.(2011)prior toOECDcoverage,thoughsmallinmagnitude;volatiletaxcollectioninmid-1970s,confirmed inDucThacandLim(1984).
Declineintaxesin1980sanduptickinearly1990sappeargenuine,likelyreflectpoliticaltransition period;jumpinsocialsecuritycontributionsin1998-1999isgenuine,reflectspolicyreforms(SSA, 2015);initialjumpintax/GDPin2016-2017wasduetoerroneousGDPvalueprovidedtoWID, hasbeencorrected.
Historicalvalues(1968-1978)shouldbetreatedwithcaution,givenstrongchangesincurrency andmacro-economicconditions[flagged];usedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecurity contributionspre-OECD;jumpintotalrevenuesinyearoftransitionfromHAtoOECDisgenuine (HAmatcheswellthelevelofOECDinpost-1989years);OECDliststwotypesofwealthtaxes leviedatnationallevel,whileHAlistsonlyone[flagged],thoughsmallinmagnitudecompared tolocaltaxeswhicharecapturedinbothHAandOECD;interpolate1965-1967.
PossiblethatHAfailstocapturesub-nationaltaxes,whileOECDdoes[flagged],thoughsuch taxesareestimatedtorepresentlessthan5%oftotaltaxes;uptickintaxcollectionstartingin mid-1980sreflectsimportantpolicyreforms(ResideandBurn,2016).
Assigninitiallyunallocableincometax(OECDcategory1300)toindividualsversusfirmsonthe basisofinformationprovidedinOECDdataandcomparisonwithhistoricalIMFreports.
Socialsecuritycontributionsdoexist(Deloitte,2019),weusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011); IMFreportslist’otherrevenues’whichareasignificantsourceoftotalrevenues,butthislikely correspondstoresourcerevenues[flagged];excisetaxwasintroducedin2019,corroborates indirecttaxeslistedinyearsofcoverage.
ICTDestimatesforsocialsecuritycontributionsarecomparabletoFisunogluetal.(2011),sowe donotdrawonadditionaldata-sources.
HAdrawsonIMFsources.IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics,IMFArticle IVReport.
SituationEconomiqueetConjoncturelle,BulletindeStatistique,Rapportsurl’EvolutionEconomiqueetFinanciere,StatisticalYearbook
GovernmentstatisticspublishedduringHAcoverageshouldbeinterpretedwithcaution(Gale, 2005)[flagged];complexpropertytaxsysteminHA,butestimatesoflevelsarecorroboratedin Martinez-VasquezandWallace(1999)andChua(2003),andcomparisonwithTreisman(2000) suggestsHAseriesmeaningfullycapturessub-nationaltaxes.
Socialsecuritycontributionsbeginin1956(SSA,2017),weusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011) priortoOECDcoverage;interpolate1990-1993,thoughconcernsexistsaboutdataqualitygiven unrestincountry[flagged].
Interpolate1984;observepropertytaxinearlyICTDyearsaswellasinallOECDyears,butsmall inmagnitude.
Non-taxrevenuescontributesignificantlytooverallrevenues;socialsecuritycontributionsdrawn fromFisunogluetal.(2011).Interpolate2006-2008.
Comparisonwithotherstudies
Tax/GDPlevelsfrom2000onwardarecomparabletoestimatesin BesleyandPersson(2014).
Historicaltax/GDPestimatesin1970sand1980saresystematically larger,by1-1.5percentagepoints,thanHasan(1997,2015)though thissourceonlycapturesnationaltaxes.
Historicaltax/GDPestimatecomparabletoestimatesinCEPAL (1978)priorto1975.
Historicallevelsandtrendsintax/GDParecomparabletoestimates reportedinDucThacandLim(1984)forperiod1965-1997.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Historicaltax/GDPestimatesaresystematicallywithin1percentage pointofestimatesinResideandBurns(2016),thoughonaverage15% smallerthanMitchell(2003).
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
HistoricalestimatesarecomparabletonumbersinvariousIMFreports.
Tax/GDPestimatesinearlyhistoricalperiod(1966-1968)arevery closetothosereportedinCheliah(1971).
Tax/GDPestimatesapproximately2percentagepointslower(10%) thanestimatesinIMF(2006)forlate1990s.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Senegal 1965-2018
HA(1965-1984); ICTD(1985-1998); OECD(1999-2018)
Serbia 2000-2018 ICTD(2000-2018)
BulletinStatistiqueetEconomique Mensuel,SituationEconomiqueetSocialeduSenegal
DropinrevenueinHAin1970swhichishardtoaccountfor,soreplacewithhistoricalIMFdata inthatperiod[flagged];Boye(1990)describesthetaxsystemasgenerallystableandsteadily growingin1960sand1970s,alsoconfirmsthatPIToutweighsCITintheseperiodsandoverall levelofincometaxesrelativetoGDP.
HAdataexistsinprioryears,butseriesbeginsin2000givenpoliticaltransition.
Estimatesofhistoricaltax/GDPsignificantlylowerthanestimatesin Cheliah(1971)forperiod1966-1968[flagged].
Estimatesoftax/GDPinmid-2000sisconsistentwithnumbersreportedinWorldBank(2007).
Commentsonseries
16
TableO1:NotesonTaxRevenueDataSeries
Country Years MaindatasourcesHistoricalarchive(HA)datasources
Seychelles 1980-2018 ICTD(1980-2007); OECD(2008-2018)
SierraLeone 1965-2018 HA(1965-1989); ICTD(1990-2018) EstimatesofRevenueandExpenditure
Singapore 1965-2018 HA(1965-1999); OECD(2000-2018) YearbookofStatistics
Slovakia 1994-2018 ICTD(1994);OECD (1995-2018)
Slovenia 1995-2018OECD(1995-2018)
SolomonIslands 1993-2018 ICTD(1993-2007); OECD(2008-2018)
SouthAfrica 1965-2018 HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018) StatisticalYearbook
Spain 1965-2018 OECD(1965-2018)
SriLanka 1965-2018HA(1965-2018)
Sudan 1972-2018 HA(1972-1980); ICTD(1981-2018)
StatisticalAbstractofCeylon,Statistical Pocketbook
TheNationalAccountsandSupporting Tables
Swaziland 1969-2018 HA(1969-1998); OECD(1999-2018) EstimatesofRevenueandExpenditure, IMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics
Sweden
1965-2018
OECD(1965-2018)
Switzerland 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
Syria 1965-2007 HA(1967-2007) StatisticalAbstractofSyria
Taiwan 1965-2018HA(1965-2018) StatisticalYearbook
Tanzania 1965-2018 HA(1965-2018) StatisticalAbstract,FinancialStatement andRevenueEstimates
Commentsonseries
Socialsecurityprogrambeginsin1971(SSA,2017),usedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)priorto OECDcoverage;PITcollectionsarepracticallyzeroinsomeyearsbetweenlate1990sandearly 2000s,whichappearsgenuine.
UsehistoricalIMFdatawithinHAseries,between1974and1989,andHAandIMFperfectly matchonlevelsandtypeoftaxin1974;socialsecuritycontributionsbeginin2001(SSA,2017), priortothatobservepayrolltaxreportedinICTDandHA;interpolatesplitbetweenPITand CITin1994-1997.
InHAseries,useadditionalinformation(AsherandTayabji,1980;TanziandShome,1992)to assigninitiallyunallocableincometaxesbetweenPITandCIT;usedatafromFisunogluetal. (2011)forsocialsecuritycontributionspriortoOECDcoverage;sharpdipin1980sreflectgenuine taxpolicyreforms(JoonChien,1996);basedonoverlappingyears,suggeststhatHAismissing ataxonfinancialandcapitaltransactionswhichiscoveredinOECD[flagged],butHAcovers other,moresignificant,wealth-propertytaxes(Haqetal.,1996;Bird,1991).
ICTDandOECDdatamatchperfectlyin1995.
ICTDandOECDdatamatchperfectlyin1995,butICTDdatapre-1995doesnotprovidesufficient disaggregationbytaxtype;SSA(2016)confirmssignificanceofsocialsecuritycontributions;drop inCITrevenueinmid-late2000sappearsgenuine(WorldBank,2020).
ICTDdataexistsin1980sbuthasnoconsistentdis-aggregationbetweenPITandCIT;interpolate in1996;ICTDlikelyonlycoversnationaltaxes[flagged].
HigherlevelinOECDdatathanHAatyearoftransitioningdata-source,whichcoincideswith importantindirecttaxreform,whichisalsotaxcategorywherediscrepancylies,butnoyearsof data-overlaptofurtherinvestigate[flagged];reasonableconfidenceindata’sabilitytoexclude resourcerevenues,corroboratedinadditionalsources(SouthAfricaRevenueServices,2015); Ndlovu(2017)referstoapay-as-you-earnsocialsecurityschemedatingbackto1963,whichwe donotseparatelyobserveinHAbutwhichcouldbeincludedunderPITcategory[flagged].
Socialsecurityfrom1958,weusedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011);transactionandpropertytaxes prominentfrom1982onward,unabletoconfirmifabsencepre-1982isduetopolicy[flagged].
ChallengingtoassigninitiallyunallocableincometaxestofirmsversusindividualsinHAdata; usesomeIMFdatainHAcoverage,butgenerallydifficulttofindreliableinformationinhistorical periods[flagged];usedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecuritycontributions.
HAdrawsonhistoricalIMFdatabetween1972and1989;spikeinrevenuesin1970sappears genuineandrelatedtoeconomicchanges;usedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecurity contributionspriortoOECD;taxesoninternationaltradesubstantialin2000s,corroboratedin Ayoki(2018).
WithholdingtaxoninterestincomeinfinancialinstitutionsisunallocablebetweenPITandCIT withoutfurtherinformation.
HAdataextendsfurtherback,butseriesstartsin1967givenpoliticaltransition;dropinPITin 2004appearsgenuine,confirmedinICTDdata;largeincreaseinCITfrom1980to1985reflects changesinresourceenvironment,butunclearifourseriesentirelyexcludesresourcerevenues [flagged];socialsecurityprogrambeganin1959(SSA,2018),weusedatafromFisunogluetal. (2011)forentireseries.
Spikeintaxesin2000appearsgenuine,reflectseconomicchanges;nodatafromanyofmain sourcesonsocialsecuritycontributions,andofficialgovernmentrecordsleavethereporting entryforsuchcontributionsblank;eithersocialsecurityisfundedthroughother,generaltax sourcesorsocialinsuranceschemesaredecentralizedandnocentralizedstatisticsexist(Chow, 2001)[flagged].
Interpolate1972,1977,1993-1995;PITandCITbundledinonereportedcategorybetween1965 and1974,assumesamesplitasreportedindisaggregateddatain1975;uptickinrevenue collectioninearly1990sattributedtomultiplereforms(IMF,2009).
Comparisonwithotherstudies
Limitedhistoricalcomparisonstootherstudies,butadditionalIMF dataprovidescomparableestimatesin1980s.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Thailand 1965-2018 HA(1965-1999); OECD(2000-2018) StatisticalYearbook
Goodmatchonleveloftax/GDPbetween1960sandearly2000swithJansenKhannabha(2009), approximately1percentagepointloweronaverageinourseries;goodmatchinlevelsbytax-type withMatsumoto(2018).Interpolate1972,1980,1985,1987,1994,1996-moresothaninanyother country[flagged]
Comparablelong-runseriesoftax/GDPasreportedinWorldBank (2020).
Estimatesoftax/GDPin1990sarecomparablewithWorldBank (2020).
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Comparabletax/GDPestimatesin1970swithNdlovu(2017)and Kochetal.(2003),in1990swithCentralReserveBank,thoughlower estimatesthaninGlendlay(2008).
Ravinthirakumaran(2011)reportscomparabletax/GDPnumbersfor theperiod1977-2009.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Estimatesoftax/GDPare1-2percentagepointslowerthanreported inFjeldstad(1995)during1986-1990period,andlowerthaninOsoro (1993)forlate1980speriod,thoughgoodmatchonlevelsandtrends withIMF(2009)between1986and2008;differenceinestimatemay partlybedrivenbydifferencesinestimatesofGDPvalue(WIDand WorldBankestimatesdifferbyalmost25%)[flagged].
17
TableO1:NotesonTaxRevenueDataSeries
Country Years MaindatasourcesHistoricalarchive(HA)datasources Commentsonseries
Timor-Leste 2006-2018 HA(2006-2018)
DataretrievedfromonlineannualbudgetspublishedbyMinistryofFinance
Togo 1966-2018 HA(1966-1999); OECD(2000-2018) AnnuaireStatistique
TrinidadandTobago 1965-2018
Tunisia 1965-2018
Turkey 1965-2018
Uganda 1965-2018
HA(1965-1989); OECD(1990-2018) AnnualStatisticalDigest
HA(1965-1999); OECD(2000-2018) AnnuaireStatistique
OECD(1965-2018)
HA(1965-1991); OECD(1992-2018)
FinancialSummaryandRevenueEstimates
Ukraine 1993-2018 ICTD(1993-2018)
UnitedKingdom 1965-2018OECD(1965-2018)
UnitedStatesofAmerica 1965-2018 OECD(1965-2018)
Uruguay 1972-2018 HA(1972-1989); OECD(1990-2018) AnuarioEstadistico
Uzbekistan 1993-2018 ICTD(1993-2018)
Vietnam 1994-2018 HA(1994-2002); OECD(2003-2018)
Yemen 1990-2012
AnnuaireStatistique,MonthlyBulletin ofStatistics,VietnamStatisticalDatain the20thCentury,StatisticalYearbook
HA(1990-1997); ICTD(1998-2012) StatisticalYearbook
Zambia 1965-2018HA(1965-2018) FinancialReport,FinancialStatisticsof GovernmentSector
Databeginsafterindependence;socialsecuritycontributionsbeganin2016(ILO,2017);initially unallocableincometaxisawithholdingtaxonpersonalincomeandhenceclassifiedunderPIT; countrystronglydependentonresourcerevenues(Doraisami,2009;Scheiner,2015).
Interpolate1981-1982;’transactiontax’inHAisclassifiedasindirecttax,ratherthanpropertywealthtax(Ghura,1998);mid-1960stolate-1960swereweremarkedbypoliticaltransition andcoupsd’etat,cautionreliabilityofdataandabsenceofhistoricalestimatestocorroborate [flagged];socialsecuritybeganin1968(SSA,2017),usedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)prior toOECDcoverage.
Largeincreaseinearly1970sseemstobedrivenbyeconomicvolatilityandincreasedinflation withstrongincreaseinCITcollection;dipinCITcollectioninlate1990smaybegenuine(appears inbothOECDandofficialgovernmentrecords),butunclearnatureofshock;historicalIMFdata corroborateslevelsofPITandCITin1970s.
UsedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecuritycontributionspriortoOECDcoverage, whichisotherwisemissinginHA;initiallyunallocableincometaxreportedinHAincertain years,limitedhistoricalsourcestospecifyallocation[flagged].
OECDdataincludeslocaltaxessincelate1970s.
UsehistoricalIMFreportstoassignincometaxbetweenindividualsandfirmsinHAperiods; interpolate1984,1991;usedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecuritycontributions priortoOECDcoverage;largeandsustaineddropintaxcollectioninlate1970slikelydrivenby politicaltransition.
HAisavailablefromearly2000sonward,butcomparableinlevelswithICTDandweprefer tominimizetotalnumberofsources;ICTDnumbersforsocialsecuritycontributionsarecorroboratedingovernmentdocuments,anddipinlate1990sisobservedinadditionalsources (UN-SNAandFisunogluetal.,2011).
EarlierHAseriesexist,butimpliedlevelsoftax/GDParenotcomparabletohistoricalestimates (LotzandMorss,1967),webeginseriesin1972whenthereisstrongerconsistencywithother studies;verylimitedcollectionofPITinhistoricalperiodsisconfirmedinIMF(1992);CIAT corroboratesincometaxsplitbetweenPITandCITin1990s.
ICTDincludessocialsecuritycontributionsandwhichmatchwellinlevelswithFisunogluetal. (2011),includingtheriseincollectionin2000s;interpolate2013-2014.
HAsourcesrelyonIMFdata;priortoDoiMoireformsinlate1980s,revenueswerelargely generatedfromnon-taxsources;socialsecuritycontributionslikelyinplaceduringHAcoverage, butnodatainHAseries[flagged];Bhattarai,NguyenandNguyen(2018)corroboratesplit betweenPITandCITbetween1994and2010.
Nodatapast2012,givenpoliticalunrestandviolence;goodmatchonlevelsbetweenHAand ICTDinoverlappingyears;usedatafromFisunogluetal.(2011)forsocialsecuritycontributions.
UsesocialsecuritycontributionsfromFisunogluetal.(2011)asitexistsduringfullperiod, corroboratedwithHAestimatesinspecificyears;limitedcomparisonwithICTDdataasit appearstoincluderesourcerevenuesinCITnumbersincertainyears[flagged].Interpolate 1986,1990-1991.
Comparisonwithotherstudies
Comparabletax/GDPwithseriesreportedinIMF(2019),though muchsmallerthanestimatesinWorldBank(2020),thelattermay includeresourcerevenues.
Overalltax/GDPlevelsarecomparabletoGhura(1998)andStotsky andWoldemariam(1997)during1980sand1990s.
Closematchinlevelsoftax/GDPduring1960sand1970swithLotz andMorss(1967)andChelliah(1971).
Tax/GDPlevelscomparableinlate1960sandearly1970swithhistoricalIMFreports.
Limitedexistenceofstudiesforhistoricalcomparison.
Polackova(1996)tax/GDPestimatein1993-1994iscomparable.
Zimbabwe 1980-2018 ICTD(1980-2018)
Datacoveragebeginsafterindependence;interpolate1998;socialsecuritycontributionsbegan in1989(SSA,2017),datamatcheswellbetweenICTDandFisunogluetal.(2011);increasein unallocableincometaxesbetween2010and2018,butlimitedadditionalinformationtoclarify allocationbetweenindividualsandfirms;collapseintaxcollectioninlate2000sdrivenby economicconditions.
Historicalestimatesoftax/GDP,centeredonyearofoverlapbetween OECDandHA,matchwithdatareportedinIMF(1989)andOECD (1990).
Ourtax/GDPestimatesareslightlyhigherthanGrigorianand Davoodi(2007)for1998-2004period,andslightlylowerthan MokhtariandAshtari(2012)for2005-2010period.
Closetax/GDPestimatesreportedinCottarelli(2011)fortheperiod between2001and2008.
Tax/GDPestimatesarecomparabletothosereportedinIMF(2002) forlate1990speriod,generallylimitedhistoricalcomparisons.
Comparabletax/GDPestimatesin1990-2004withDiJohn(2010)and Weeksetal.(2006),lowertax/GDPestimatethaninColclough(1988) for1975-1985periodthoughthismaybeduetoouromissionof category’miscellaneouscapitalreceipts’inHAwhichwedonot countastaxrevenue.
18
GoldbergandPavcnik(2006)
GoldbergandPavcnik(2006), Dix-CarneiroandKovak(2017)
Brandtetal.(2017)
FeenstraandHanson(1997); GoldbergandPavcnik(2006,2016)
GoldbergandPavcnik(2016), McCaigandPavcnik(2018)
Notes: Thistableshowstheseventreatedcountriesandthethreecountrieswiththelargestweightinthesyntheticcontrolgroupforeachtreated countryandoutcome(tradeopenness, ETRK , ETRL).Foreachoutcome,thepoolofpossibledonorcountriesconsistsofallnon-treatedcountries withabalancedpaneloverallthepre-eventperiodsthatareusedinthematchingprocedure.ThistableisdiscussedinSection5.1.
TableO2:WeightsinSyntheticControlforTradeLiberalizationEvents TreatedCountryEventYear TradeOpennessWeight ETRK Weight ETRL Weight Reference
1989 Bangladesh97.3 Bangladesh41.6% Chile 35.9%
Argentina
UnitedStates2.7% Haiti 14.1% Togo 31.6% . . Bolivia 13.4% Jordan 16.8%
1988 Bangladesh59.8% Jordan 35.7% Panama25.7%
Brazil
UnitedStates32.2 Sudan 21.2% Guyana21.7% Japan 6.1% Zimbabwe 12.7% Chile 14.5% ... ... ... ... ... ...
2001 UnitedStates36.2% Congo 41.8% Kuwait31.1%
Bangladesh36.0% Nicaragua 26.3% Pakistan22.9% DominicanRep.12.2% Gabon 14.2% Uganda20.2% ... ... ... ... ... ... Colombia 1985 Bangladesh50.7% Kuwait 67.9% Paraguay45.5%
Iran 22.6% Gabon 14.6% Sudan 15.0% Guatemala 12.5% SierraLeone12.6% Cameroon11.5% ... ... ... ... ... ... India 1991 UnitedStates76.4% Uganda 41.4% Lebanon37.9% GoldbergandPavcnik(2006,2016);
Bangladesh23.6% Bolivia 14.0% Oman 17.6% Haiti 4.6% Jordan 16.2% . . ... ... ... ... Mexico 1985 Bangladesh72.0% SierraLeone33.2% Tunisia31.1
Uruguay 9.6% Bahrain 23.6% Zimbabwe25.8% Spain 8.0% Bolivia 14.7% Uruguay15.9% ... ... ... ... ... ... Vietnam 2001 Thailand 42.4% Korea 45.8% Bangladesh72.8%
Ghana 22.6% Luxembourg19.2% Myanmar22.6% Venezuela 21.7% Trinidad&Tob.17.3% Haiti 4.6%
China
GoldbergandPavcnik(2006;2016)
Topalovaetal.(2009)
TableO3:HeterogeneityImpactsofTradeonTaxationbyCountryCharacteristics
Hc :
PanelA:CITrate(first-diff).
Trade
-0.003 (0.016) (0.038)
Trade∗Hc -0.022 -0.110** (0.065) (0.051)
Impliedcoef.for
Tradein Hc (0.057) (0.027) 1st-stageKleibergen- 7.30
PappF-statistic
PanelB: ETRK Trade
0.511** (0.210) (0.248) Trade∗Hc
-0.374 (0.540) (0.340)
Impliedcoef.for -0.367 0.137 Tradein Hc (0.401) (0.123)
1st-stageKleibergen- 7.01 11.41 PappF-statistic
PanelC: ETRL
0.190*** 0.127 (0.065) (0.129)
Trade∗Hc 0.067 0.187 (0.242) (0.209)
Impliedcoef.for 0.258 0.315*** Tradein Hc (0.216) (0.109)
1st-stageKleibergen- 7.01 11.41 PappF-statistic
Notes: Thistablepresentsresultsfromestimatingheterogeneouseffectsoftradeonoutcomesinthefull sampleofdevelopedanddevelopingcountries.Tradeisthesumofexportsandimportsdividedbynet domesticproduct.WeestimateanIVsimilartothatinTableA7butwheretheinteractiontermisan indicatorforsmallpopulation(column1),oranindicatorforcapitalopenness(column2).Smallpopulation takesavalueof1ifthecountry’spopulationin2018wasbelow40million.Capitalopennesstakesavalue of1ifthecountry’saveragevalueoftheChinn-Itoindex(Chinn&Ito,2006)liesabovethemedianvalueof allcountry-years.Bothoftheseheterogeneitydimensionsarethereforecountry-specificbuttime-invariant. Thesamplesizeissmallerincolumn(2)duetodata-availabilityoftheChinn-Itovariable.Thepanelsdiffer byoutcome:panela)isthefirst-differencedcorporateincometax(CIT)rate;panelb)istheeffectivetax rateoncapital, ETRK ;panelc)istheeffectivetaxrateonlabor, ETRL.Atthebottomofeachcolumnand panel,wereporttheimpliedcoefficientandestimatedstandarderrorbasedonthelinearcombinationof the Trade andthe Trade*Hc coefficients.Wealsoreportthe 1st-stageKleibergen-PaapF-statistic.Formore detailsontheIV,seeSection5.2.*p<0.10**p<0.05***p<0.01.Standarderrorsinparenthesesareclustered atthecountrylevel.
Heterogeneity
Small population Capital openness (1) (2)
-0.067***
N 6489
-0.089 -0.114***
11.41
5969
0.374*
-0.742
N
6489 5969
Trade
N 6489
5969
20
O.1EventStudy:FurtherDetails
Sampleconstruction Oursampleisconstructedbyapplyingasyntheticmatchingproceduretoeverytreatedcountry,foreachoutcomeofinterest.Thedonorpool(theset ofallcontrolcountriesfromwhichtochoosethesyntheticcontrolgroup)hastobefully balancedinallpre-eventperiods.Wethenpooltogetherallseventreatedcountriesand theirsyntheticcontrolunits.Usingthispanel,weestimatetheDiD:
Here, βDiD canbeinterpretedasanaveragetreatmenteffectoverthefirst10eventperiods(e)aftertreatment.Werunbothregressions—theeventstudyandtheDiD regression—onthesetofmainoutcomes,andclusterstandarderrorsatthecountry level.Statisticalinferencebasedonsmallsamplesizeshouldbeapproachedwithcaution (Abadie,DiamondandHainmueller,2010):wealsoreportstandarderrorsfromthewild bootstrap(Cameron,Gelbach,andMiller,2008)inTableA1. Moreover,weusetheimputationmethodby Borusyaketal.(2021) toreportaverage treatmenteffectscomparableto βDiD withatechniquethatdealswithissuesfortwowayfixedeffectsandheterogeneouseventtiming.Theapproachprovidesatransparent alternativemethodtothedifference-in-differenceequationspecifiedabove.Theaverage treatmenteffect(TE)iscalculatedinthreesteps:
1. Weuseuntreatedcountriesaswellastreatedcountriesintheyearsbeforetreatment, toestimateunitand(relative)yearfixedeffects:
if e< 0 or Dc =0.Tobringusclosertotheapproachdevelopedby Borusyaketal. (2021), weincludeyearandrelativetimefixedeffects.
2. Withthefittedvalues ˆ θt and ˆ κc,wenowimputeunitspecifictreatmenteffects:
3. Thefinalstepistoaverageoverthosecoefficientstoproduceatreatmenteffect.We reportunweightedaverages,butheterogeneityintreatmenteffectscouldbeaccounted forbyspecifyingweights.
Yct = βDiD 1(e ≥ 0)t Dc + θt + κc + πYear(t) + ϵct
Yct = θt + κc + πYear(t) + ϵct
ˆ TEct = Yct ˆ θt ˆ κc ˆ πYear(t)
21
O.2InstrumentalVariablesforTrade
Inthisappendix,weoutlinetheconstructionofthetwoinstrumentalvariables.Both instrumentsaredrawnfrom Eggeretal.(2019), whoprovidefurtherdetails.
Instrumentbasedonquantitativetrademodels Thefirstinstrumentleveragesthestructureofgravitymodelsingeneralequilibrium.Thesemodelspermitcalibrationofcountry pair-year-specifictradecostsfromtradedata,relyingonthreekeyassumptions:(i)producersareperfectlycompetitiveandmakezeroprofitsorchargeaconstantmarkup;(ii) tradecoststaketheicebergform;and(iii)aggregateexpenditureanditsallocationacross productsareseparable.Theseassumptionsimplythatbilateralconsumptionsharestowardscountry o byconsumersincountry c inyear t,denoted πcot,havemultiplicative componentsthatareexporter-year-specific(ψot),importer-year-specific(ιct)andpair-yearspecific(βcot):
Thecomponent ψot isproportionaltocountry o’ssupplypotentialandcapturesproductioncostsandgross-of-taxfactorincome—andmightbeinfluencedbybothcapital andlabortaxation.Thecomponent ιct dependsontheconsumerpriceindex,whichvaries acrossyearsandcountries.67 βcot capturestradefrictionsacrosscountry-pairsandtime.68 Theproductofthenormalizedsharesgivesthebilateralfrictionsofimporting-exporting country-pairsatapointintime:
Finally,weuse βcot · βoct tocomputetheaverage ct-specificcostsofexportingand importing,whichconstitutestheinstrument:
Notethatallexporter-yearandimporter-yearfactorsareremovedfromtheinstrument. Thisinstrumentisvalidsolongasthe distribution oftradecostsamongcountry-pairs(not itslevel)isnotinfluencedbytheleveloffactorincomesoreffectivetaxburdens.Constructingthisinstrumentrequiresdataoncountry-pairtradeflows:weuseUNCOMTRADE datatoconstructalargesampleofbilateralconsumptionshares.69 First-stageregressions with Zgravity ct areshowninTableA2.
67Both ψot and ιct maycapturecountry-year-specifictradecosts,butthepair-specificcomponent βcot isfree ofsuchcountry-yearspecificinfluence.
68Eggeretal.(2019) exploitthemultiplicativemodelstructureabout πcot torecovermeasuresof βcot.They assumethattransactioncostsbetweendomesticsellersandcustomersarezero,suchthat βcct =1.Both theimporter-yearcomponentandexporter-yearcomponentcanthenbeeliminatedbynormalizingimport andexporttradesharesbytheimporterandexporters’consumptionfromdomesticsellers.
69WeaugmentourrawdatafromCOMTRADEwithdatafromHarvardGrowthLab,whoharmonized importer-andexporter-reportedtradeflowstoexpandthecoverageandimprovetheprecisionofcountrypartner-yeartradeflowestimates.
πcot = ψot × ιct × βcot
πcot πcct · πoct πoot = βcot · βoct
Zgravity ct = o=c [βcot · βoct]
22
Instrumentbasedonglobaloilprices&transportdistances Thesecondinstrument exploitsspatialheterogeneityacrosscountriesinawaythatinteractswithoilpriceshocks. Thisinstrumentisbasedonglobaloilpricechangesovertimeandwithin-countrytransportationdistancesfromcitiestothenearestport.70 Theinstrumentisthevarianceofthe productoilprice
where dc istheaveragecity-portdistanceincountry c.Thisvarianceincreasesincountries whosemaincitiesarefarfromthenearestportandfarfromeachother,whichimplies alargerchangetotransportationcostsfollowingaglobaloilpriceshockinspread-out countriesthanincountrieswithconcentratedpopulations.Itisthistransportation-cost shockthattheinstrumentcaptures.71
Thissecondinstrumentdoesnothingeontheoreticalassumptions.Instead,this instrumentisvalidsolongasthecountry-specificdistributionoftrade-costs,inducedby theinteractionbetweenglobaloilpriceshocksandacountry’sfixedspatialconcentration, isnotcorrelatedwithcontemporaneouschangesinfactorincomesandeffectivetaxrates. First-stageresultsfor Zoil dist ct arepresentedinTableA2.
70Fortheformer,weretrievetheOPECReferenceBasketbenchmarkworldpriceofcrudeoil.Forthelatter, wemeasureroaddistancesfromthethreelargestcities(accordingtoUNpopulationstatistics)totheir nearestport,usingSeaRatesinternationalshippinglogisticscalculators.
71Alternatively,onecouldmeasurethevarianceindistanceandthenmultiplyitbytheglobaloilprice.The distributionofthevarianceinstrument Zoil dist ct acrosscountry-yearswouldnotchange;theonlyimpact wouldbealevel-shiftbytheprice.Weconsiderthemainapproachtomorecloselycapturethesensitivityof transportcoststospatialconcentration,butresultsbasedonthisalternativevariancemeasurearesimilar.
poil t × distance dk c acrosscities k incountry c inyear t: Zoil dist ct = 1 2 3 k=1 [(p oil t dk c p oil t dc)2]
23
O.3ComparisonwithPre-existing ETR Series
Wecompareourmethodologytopre-existing ETR series.Themaindifferencesare summarizedinTableB3.
In McDaniel(2020), updatedfrom McDaniel(2007), therearetwomaindifferences withourbenchmarkmethodology.First,theauthorassignsthecapital-shareinmixed incomebasedontheobservedfactorshareintherestoftheeconomy,whileourbenchmark assignsafixedshare(25%).Second,theauthorassumesthatlaborandcapitalinPITare taxedatthesamerate.Thisisthesameassumptionasin Mendozaetal.(1994), and differsfromourbenchmarkwherewecreateanallocationofPITtocapitalthatvariesby countryandyear, (1 λPIT,ct).Thesemethodologicaldifferencesarereasonablycaptured inourrobustnesschecks.Forthefirstdifference,notethatthischoiceeffectivelyamounts tousingtheobservedcapital-shareinthecorporatesectortoassignthecapitalsharein mixedincome(seeequation3in McDaniel(2007)).Thiscorrespondsdirectlytooneof ourrobustnesschecks(PanelBinFigure3).
Wecanrelatetheseconddifferencetoourrobustnesscheckwherewevarythecapital shareofPITfrom0%to30%(PanelAinFigure3).Iflaborandcapitalfacethesametax rate,thenthecapitalshareofPITincreasesinthecapitalfactorshareandintheshare ofcapitalthatistaxable.Usingtheempiricalmeasuresfortaxablesharesestablishedin theUS (Pikettyetal., 2018), andassumingbothfactorsfacethesamerate,thecapital shareofPITthatwouldresultatthe 99th percentileofobservedcapitalfactorshares inourfullsampleis 1 λPIT =0 305.Inotherwords,ourrobustnesscheckwhich implements 1 λPIT =0.30 constitutesameaningfulupperboundonthecapitalshare inPITthatwouldresultfromanyobservedfactorsharesinoursampleandassuming capitalandlaborpaythesamerateandhavetaxablesharesasmeasuredin Pikettyetal. (2018). Ofcourse,undertheassumptionthatbothfactorsarefullytaxable(unrealistic givenempiricalfindingsin Jensen(2022))andfacethesamerate,thecapitalshareofPIT wouldbeequaltotheobservedcapitalfactorshare.Ourbenchmarkmethodologytakesa steptowardstryingtomeasurethetaxablefactorsharesastheyvaryacrosscountriesand time,witha 1 λPIT,ct atthe 99th percentilethatequals0.32.Futureworkcouldimprove onthismeasurement,bycombiningadditionalinformationfromnationalaccountsand taxrecords.
The ETR seriesthatwouldresultfromapplyingthemethodologyin McDaniel(2020) tooursampleisthereforereasonablyboundedbyourrobustnesscheckswhichassign capital’sshareofmixedincomebasedonthecorporatecapitalshare,andwhichvarythe capitalshareinPITbetween0%and30%.
Inadditiontothesemaindifferences, McDaniel(2020) considerspropertytaxespaid byhouseholdsasconsumptiontaxesandpropertytaxespaidbybusinessesascapital taxes,whileourseriesconsidersallpropertytaxestobecapitaltaxes.Thisdifference isunlikelytobequantitativelysignificant.Finally, McDaniel(2020) usestaxdatafrom nationalaccounts,whilewerelyonvariouspublicfinancesources.
InPanelBofFigureB1,weuse McDaniel(2020)’sspecificsample.Thetrendsare similarbetweenseries.Whenweightsareapplied,ourbenchmarkseriesisonaverage 18.75%higherinlevelsthan McDaniel(2020). Thiswedgearisesfromthemethodological
24
differences(whichwecanaccountforinourrobustnesschecks),andpossiblyfromthe differencesintaxdata-sources.
In KostarakosandVarthalitis(2020), whichappliesthemethodologyin Careyand Rabesona(2004) todatafrommorerecentyears,thereisonemainmethodologicaldifferencewithourbenchmark.Inparticular,theauthorsestimaterelativelaborincomeof self-employedonthebasisofobservablecharacteristicsandacomparisonwiththewage ofemployees,whileourbenchmarkmethodassignsafixedlaborsharetomixedincome. However,thisalternativemethodcorrespondscloselytothemethodin ILO(2019), which weimplementasarobustnesscheck.Thus,thisrobustnesscheck(PanelBofFigure3) meaningfullycapturesthe ETR seriesthatwouldresultfromapplyingthemethodology in KostarakosandVarthalitis(2020) tooursample.
Oneadditionaldifferenceisthat KostarakosandVarthalitis(2020) assumesocialsecuritycontributionsaredeductiblefromthetaxableincomeofhouseholdswhileourmethod followsnationalaccountsconventionandassumestheyarenot.Weconfirmthatimplementingthischangeinourseriesdoesnotmeaningfullyaltertheresults(availableupon request).Finally, KostarakosandVarthalitis(2020) drawtheirtaxrevenuedatafroma differentsource(Eurostat)thanus.
InPanelAofFigureB1,weuse KostarakosandVarthalitis(2020)’sspecificsample. Thetrendsaresimilarbetweenseries.Whenweightsareapplied,ourbenchmarkseries isonaverage14.2%lowerinlevelsthan KostarakosandVarthalitis(2020). Thiswedge arisesfromthemethodologicaldifferences(whichwecanaccountforinourrobustness checks),andpossiblyfromthedifferentialtreatmentofsocialsecuritycontributionsand fromthedifferentdata-sourcefortaxrevenue.
O.4Discussionof ETRK C
Ourmeasureofthebackward-lookingaverageeffectivetaxrateoncorporateprofits, ETRK C ,isrelatedto,butalsodistinctfrom,theforward-lookingmeasuresofthestatutory taxburdeninthecorporatesectorindevelopingcountries(Section2).Therearetwomain reasonswhythesemeasuresdiffer.
Thefirstreasonisthatthemeasureofcorporateprofitsin ETRK C isbasedonnational accounts,whichdiffersbothempiricallyandconceptuallyfromhowcorporateprofitsmay bemeasuredusingtaxdata.Empirically,thedata-sourcesfornationalaccountsinclude corporatetaxreturnsbutalsonon-taxsourcessuchasindustrialcensusesandsurveys. Themeasureofcorporateprofitsbasedonnationalaccountsmaythereforeincludeprofits whicharenotreportedintaxreturns.Indeed,thenationalaccountguidelinesexplicitly trytoaccountformis-reportedprofitsandcorporateprofitsareusuallyfoundtobelarger invaluewhenmeasuredfromnationalaccountsthanfromtaxreturns(Lequiller&Blades, 2014).Forthissamereason,constructinganappropriately-weightedbackward-looking firm-leveleffectivetaxratebasedontaxespaidandprofitsreportedintaxreturnsmay notgivethesamevalueas ETRK C .Thisfirm-levelmeasureisanalyzedinSection6;see alsoDyrengetal.(2017)andEggeretal.(2009)forfirm-levelestimatesinlargesamples focusedondevelopedcountries.
25
Therearealsoconceptualdifferences,whicharediscussedindetailin IMF(2014), Lequiller&Blades(2014)andUeda(2018).Consumptionoffixedcapitalinnationalaccountsadjustsforinflationandisestimatedaccordingtophysicalandeconomiclawsof depreciation,whereascompaniessometimesmeasuredepreciationwithoutregardtoinflationandmayshortenorlengthenthetimeofamortizationaccordingtotaxadvantages. Inaddition,inventoryappreciation(thenetgainininventory)isusuallyaccountedfor incompanyprofitsbutnotinnationalaccounts.Moreover,expenditureonintellectual propertyiscountedasinvestmentinnationalaccounts,butmaybelistedasintermediate consumptionbycompaniesontheirtaxreturns.Finally,somesourcesofpropertyincome (e.g.investmentvaluationincreases;resourcerentspaidvs.received)andcapitalgains (e.g.saleofsubsidiariesorcurrencytransactions)arecountedincompanyprofitsbutnot innationalaccounts.
Thesecondreasonisthatthecorporatestatutorytaxburdenvariesacrossfirmsdueto economicvariables,includingsector,sizeandprofitability (R.Kumar&James, 2022,Devereux,GriffithandKlemm,2004). Changesintheseeconomicvariableswillbereflected in ETRK C ,butmaynotbefullycapturedinthestatutorymeasures.
Relationbetween ETRK C andCITefficiency Ourmeasureoftheaveragecorporate effectivetaxrate, ETRK C ,isrelatedtoempiricalworkdoneby IMF(2014) tomeasure CIT-efficiencyindevelopingcountries.IMFdefinesCIT-efficiencyasactualcorporate incometax(CIT)revenuesdividedbytheproductofthestandardCITrateandthegross operatingsurplusofcorporationsfromnationalaccounts, OSCORP .CIT-efficiencyis thereforerelatedto ETRK C asfollows:
CIT-efficiency = ETRK C · 1 CITrate
WehaveinformationontheCITrate,sowecancomputetheCIT-efficiencymeasure usingourdata.Inturn,wecanlimitthecomparisontothesampleofdevelopingcountries coveredintheIMFstudy(’Non-OECD’countries).Beforecomparingthetwoseries,we notetheremainingmethodologicaldifferences:
1. Ourmeasureof OSCORP isnetofcapitaldepreciation,whiletheIMFmeasureis not.Thislikelyleadsourvariabletobehigherinlevels,thoughitisnotclearhowit wouldaffecttrendsovertime(seeAppendixIVintheIMFstudy).
2. OursampledoesnotcontaindataforMalta,whichisoneofthedevelopingcountries (’Non-OECD’)includedintheIMFsample.Moreover,wecanlimitthecomparisonsampletotherangeofyearsindicatedintheIMFstudy(1989-2011),butwe cannotverifythatourcomparisonsamplecontainsexactlythesamecountry-year observations.
3. IntheIMFstudy,thedataforboththeCITrevenuecollectedandtheCITrateare takenfromtheIMF’sFiscalAffairsDepartment.OursourcesforbothCITrevenue andtheCITratediffer(seeSection3and6inpaperfordetails).
26
TheaverageunweightedCIT-efficiencyseriesthatresultsfromusingourdatabut restrictedtotheIMFsampleiscomparedtotheIMFseriesinFigureO10.Ourvaluesarea littlehigherinlevelsonaverage,whichmayreflectthedeductionofdepreciation.Despite this,aswellasdifferencesinunderlyingdata-sources,thetrendsmatchwellbetweenthe twoseries.
Inregressionresultsnotshown,wefindthattradehasapositiveimpactontheCITefficiencymeasure.Thisisconsistentwiththehypothesisinthemainpaperthattrade improveseffectivecorporatetaxationindevelopingcountries.
FigureO10:CITefficiency–ComparisonofOurDatawith IMF(2014)
Our dataIMF (2014)
Notes: Thisfigurecomparesthevaluesofcorporateincometax(CIT)efficiencybetweenthe seriesestimatedusingourdata(lightbluecircleline)andtheseriesestimatedin IMF(2014) (darkbluetriangleline).Werestrictourdatatothe’Non-OECD’sampleofdevelopingcountries usedintheIMFstudy,withtheexceptionthatMaltaisincludedintheIMFstudybutdoesnot existinourdata.Thereported IMF(2014) seriesisapproximate,asthenumbershavebeen extractedfromAppendixFigure1ofthestudybasedonvisualinspection.CITefficiencyis definedastheratioofCITrevenuescollecteddividedbytheproductofcorporations’operating surplusandtheCITrate.Formoredetails,seeSectionO.4.
.1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 CIT efficiency 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Year
27
EffectiveTaxRatesDatabase:CaseStudiesReport
PierreBachas∗ ,MatthewFisher-Post† ,AndersJensen‡ , XabierMoriana-Armendariz§ ,GabrielZucman¶
January2024
Abstract
Thisreportpresentsdetailedcountry-by-countryguidanceonthecreationoftimeseriesdatafrom1965 to2020ontaxrevenues,factorincomesharesandeffectivetaxratesforthecountriesshownintheAtlasof theOffshoreWorld(link).Originallybasedonthepaper Bachas,Fisher-Post,Jensen,andZucman (2022), theguidelinedetailsthedatasourcesofhistoricaltaxrevenuedataandexplainsthechoicesandadjustments made.Beyondthewell-knowninstitutionaldatasetsongovernmenttaxrevenue(OECD,ICTD,IMF),we havedigitizedandharmonizedthousandsofarchivalpublicfinancedocumentsfromdevelopingcountries,in ordertoconstructthelong-runtimeseries.Inthefollowingpages,wediscussthesesources,aswellasall relevantmethodologicalconsiderationsandacademicsourcestohelpproducereliabletimeseriesestimates foreachcountry.Indoingso,weprovideatransparentresourceontherationaleforourdatainput,while welcomingsuggestionsforfurtherimprovementandexpansionofthedatabase.
• MethodologyandHowtoReadthisDocument: clickhere
• CountryList: clickhere
Thisdocumentisworkinprogress.Atthemoment,wecovercountrieswithmorethan 15millioninhabitantsandsomeadditionalcountries(67intotal).Thesampleofcountriesis currentlybeingexpanded.
∗ ESSEC-BusinessSchoolandWorldBankResearch,pbachas@worldbank.org
† ParisSchoolofEconomics,mfp@psemail.eu
‡ HarvardKennedySchoolandNBER,anders jensen@hks.harvard.edu
§ ParisSchoolofEconomics,xabier.moriana@psemail.eu
¶ ParisSchoolofEconomics,UCBerkeleyandNBER,zucman@berkeley.edu
i
CountryList
Pleasefollowthe link toseethelistofcountriesincludedinthisdocument.Weemphasizethatthisisawork inprogress.Atthemoment,wecover67largestcountries(>15millioninhabitants)1 .Ourteamiscurrently workingtocompletethecasestudiesfortheremainingcountriesinthefullsample.
(i)Introductorynote
Thepresentpaperprovidesacountry-by-countryguidelineontheconstructionoftheeffectivetaxrateson capitalandlaborincomes.Inaddition,itoffersinformationontheeffectivetaxratesoncorporateprofits,and ondis-aggregatedtaxrevenueasashareofnationaldomesticproduct.
Sincenationalaccountingstatisticsarecompiledfollowinginternationallystandardconceptsandmethods, effectivetaxrates(ETRs)areconceptuallycomparableovertimeandacrosscountries.Theseseriesprovidea pictureoftaxburdensoncapitalandlaborinthesecountries.Byconsideringthetaxrevenuesactuallycollected (ratherthanstatutoryrates),ETRsshowthenetpasteffectsofalltaxrules—basereductions,exemptions,tax credits—andoftaxavoidanceandtaxevasion.Loweffectivetaxratescanresultfromtaxavoidanceortax evasionpractices,butmayalsoresultfrompolicychoices.
(ii)Themethodologyinbrief
Theeffectivetaxrateonlabor(ETRL)isthetotalamountoftaxesactuallycollectedonlaborincome,divided bytotallaborincomeintheeconomy;similarly,theeffectivetaxrateforcapital(ETRK )isthetotalamount oftaxesactuallycollectedoncapitalincome,dividedbytotalcapitalincomeintheeconomy.Taxesandfactor incomesarerespectivelyallocatedtothenumeratoranddenominatorasfollows:
TaxRevenueAllocation:
• Corporateincometaxes,wealthtaxes,andpropertytaxesareallocatedtocapital.
• Payrolltaxesandsocialsecuritypaymentsareallocatedtolabor.
• Personalincometaxesareallocatedpartlytolaborandpartlytocapital(see Bachasetal. (2022)for details).
FactorIncomeAllocation
• Laborincomeequalscompensationofemployeesplusashareofmixedincome(operatingsurplusofprivate unincorporatedenterprises)–see Bachasetal. (2022)fordetails2
• Capitalincomeequalstheremainingshareofmixedincome,pluscorporateprofits(i.e.,operatingsurplus), plusrentalincome(i.e.,operatingsurplusofhouseholds).
1 Myanmar(54millioninhabitants)andVenezuela(28millioninhabitants)arenotincludedatthemomentduetothelackof qualitydataforthehistoricalperiod.
2 Notethatfactorincomes(bothcapitalandlabor)arebasedonadis-aggregationofthenetdomesticproduct(NDP).TheNDP subtractstheconsumptionoffixedcapital(capitaldepreciation)fromgrossdomesticproduct(GDP).NDPisthuslowerthanGDP by10%onaverage.
MethodologyandHowtoReadthisDocument
ii
1. TaxRevenue: whatshareofpersonalincometax(PIT)revenuesshouldbeallocatedtocapitalversus labor.Startingfromabaselinewhere15%ofPITrevenuesderivefromcapital(consistentwithUS measuresinPikettyetal.,2018),twoadjustmentsatthecountry-yearlevelareperformed.Theproportion ofcapitalrevenueswithinPITisincreasedincountrieswithahighPITexemptionthresholdintheincome distributionandtheproportionisloweredincountrieswheredividendsfacelowertaxratesthanwages. Wereporttherangeofvaluesforthecapitalshareineachcountry.Inthecompanionpaper(Bachaset al., 2022),twoboundingscenariosareconstructed.
2. Factorincome: whatshareofmixedincome(unincorporatedenterprises)shouldbeallocatedtocapital versuslaborincome.Forthiscase-study,a75%laborvs.25%capitalsplitisassumed.Inthecompanion paper(Bachasetal., 2022),twoboundingscenariosareconstructed. WerefertothepaperandtotheMethodologyNoteavailableinthewebsiteforfurthermethodologicalissues.
(iii)Thedatabaseinbrief
TaxRevenue: Thetaxrevenuedatadis-aggregatesrevenuesbytype,followingthe OECD RevenueStatistics classificationoftaxes.Werelyonthreesources:
1. Whenavailable, OECD RevenueStatisticsdataisthepreferredsource,asitcoversalltypesoftaxrevenues andgoesbackto1965forOECDcountries.
2. DatafromICTDisadded,whichincludesmostdevelopingcountries,andwithcoveragethatstartsinthe 1980s.
3. Tocomplementthesesources,theteamconductedanarchivaldatacollection.Withintheconceptof ‘HistoricalArchive’,weincludedatafrom:
• LamontLibraryatHarvardUniversity(Historicalpublicbudgetsandnationalstatisticalyearbooks)(websitelink).
• OfflineIMFGovernmentFinanceStatistics(1972-1989)(websitelink).
• AnnualReportsfromthecountry’sMinistryofFinance/NationalCentralBankforrecentyears.
Factorincome: Thefactorincomedatasetisbasedontheconstructionofapanelofnationalaccounts.It comesfromtwosources:
1. TheSNA2008-frameworkonlinerepository,whichhasglobalcoverageinrecentdecades.
2. TheSNA1968-frameworkofflinerepository,whichcovershistoricalobservationsfromthe1960sand1970s formostcountries.
3. Ifthereisnodataforasub-componentoffactorincomes,we:1)recoveritsvaluefromtheotherSNA datasetandusingnationalaccountingidentities;or,ifnotpossible,2)imputevaluesforthecomponent followingtheprocedurefrom Blanchet,Chancel,Flores,andMorgan (2021).
Intheconstructionofthe ETRs,weface twochallenges:
iii
Thefinalsamplecontains7070country-yearobservationsin154countries,overtheperiod1965-2020.Note thatthecompanionpaper(Bachasetal., 2022)consideredthe1965-2018rangeofyears.Thenumberof countriesstartsat75in1965andgrowsto105by1975(duetoindependenceorcountrycreation).Thekey jumpincoverage—from116to146countries—occursin1994andcorrespondstotheentryofex-communist3 countries,includingChinawhenitmodernizeditspublicfinances(seeNotesonpage 6).
Figure1showsgraphicallyhowthedatasetiseffectivelycomposedoftwoquasi-balancedpanels:thefirst covers1965-1993andexcludescommunistregimes,accountingfor85-90%ofworldGDP;thesecondcovers19942020andincludesformercommunistcountries,accountingfor98%ofworldGDP.Mostoftheex-communist countriesarelow-middleincomecountries,makingthejumpbiggerforthissubgroup.Thesmalldropin20192020,comingfromlowandmiddle-incomecountries,isexplainedbythelackofrecentdataforVenezuela,Syria andYemen.
3 Weuseex-communisttorefertobasicallyformersovietcountries,ChinaandVietnam.Wedonotincludeinthisgroup othercommunist/socialistregimesinotherpartsoftheworld,suchastheAfricansocialistcountriesincertainperiods(Ethiopia, MozambiqueorAngola).
0 50 100 150 # countries 0 25 50 75 100 coverage (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Global 0 10 20 30 40 # countries 0 25 50 75 100 coverage (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 High−Income Countries 0 25 50 75 100 125 # countries 0 25 50 75 100 coverage (%) 1965 1975 1985 1995 2005 2015 Low & Middle−Income Countries Population (% of total) GDP (% of total) # countries
Figure1.DataCoverage
iv
CountryList 0MethodologyandHowtoReadthisDocument LargeCountries(> 40millions) 1Afghanistan 1 2Algeria 2 3Argentina 3 4Bangladesh 4 5Brazil 5 6China 6 7Colombia 8 8DemocraticRepublicoftheCongo 9 9Egypt 11 10Ethiopia 12 11France 13 12Germany 14 13India 15 14Indonesia 17 15Italy 18 16Japan 19 17Kenya 20 18Korea(Republicof) 21 19Mexico 22 20Nigeria 23 21Pakistan 25 22Phillipines 26 23Poland 27 24Russia 28 25SouthAfrica 29 26Spain 30 27Sudan 31 28Tanzania 32 29Thailand 33 30Turkey 34 31Uganda 35 32UnitedKingdom 36 33UnitedStatesofAmerica 37 34Vietnam 38 v
40millions) *(Workinprogress) 35Australia 39 36Cameroon 40 37Canada 41 38Coted’Ivoire 42 39Ghana 43 40Madagascar 44 41Malaysia 45 42Morocco 46 43Mozambique 47 44Nepal 48 45Niger 49 46Peru 50 47SaudiArabia 51 48Ukraine 52 49Uzbekistan 53 50Venezuela 54 51Yemen 55 52Taiwan 56 53Mali 57 54BurkinaFaso 58 55SriLanka 59 56Malawi 60 57Chile 61 58Kazakhstan 62 59Zambia 63 60Romania 64 61Senegal 65 62Netherlands 66 63Guatemala 67 64Chad 68 65Cambodia 69 66Ecuador 70 67Zimbabwe 72 vi
SmallCountries(<
1Afghanistan
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
ICTD 2003 2020
Timeseries WestartthedataseriesforAfghanistanin2003.Wedohavedataforprioryears: historicalarchivedatafor1973-1978andICTDfor1982-1989.However,weexcludethisperiodbecause thesefiguresareeithertooshortintime(historicalarchive)ortheyarenotdisaggregatedwhilebeing quitevolatile(ICTD).
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforAfghanistanaremadeonincometaxation,socialcontributionsandproperty taxation.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITwithquestionablevaluesfor2006-2010andnotavailable after2017.Useinformationinadditionaldocuments,andinterpolation ofproportionalratiosfor2006-2010using2005and2011asreferences andextrapolationofproportionalratiosafter2017
• Smallunallocableincometaxrevenueduringthewholeperiod
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%;constant
Minusculebutnon-zerovaluesduringthewholeperiod.Extrapolationof valuesafter2017
Minusculebutnon-zerovaluesduringthewholeperiod.Extrapolationof valuesafter2017
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
1
2Algeria Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 2020 1967,1970-71,1974
Timeseries Weusearchivaldatafrom1965through2020.Years1967,1970-1971and1974areinterpolated.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemajoradjustmentsforAlgeriaareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITavailableallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
• AllunallocableincometaxrevenueisconsideredasPIT,basedoninformationinadditionaldocuments.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=20%; ↓ trend(25%to18%)
Minusculebutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod.Werelyonexternalsources (RPC data)
PropertyTaxation Notincluded
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
• OurarchivaldatadiffersfromIMFhistoricaldata.However,thisdifferenceiscompletelydrivenby theconsiderationofthetax“Taxessurlechiffred’affaires ”.TheIMFconsidersitasanindirect tax,whereasweincludeitasacorporateincometaxinourhistoricalarchivedata,basedon additionalpolicyreports.
2
3Argentina Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1989 OECD 1990 2020
Timeseries Weusearchivalsourcesfrom1965until1989,referringtoOECDfortheperiodsincethen.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemajoradjustmentsforArgentinaareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefor1961-69and1974-1989.Interpolationof proportionalratiosusingpriorandlateryearsforwhichwehavedisaggregateddata,aswellasinformationfromadditionalpolicydocuments.
• Smallunallocableincometaxrevenue(<0.4%)inOECDdata(19902020)
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=18%; ↓ trend(20%to15%)
WerelyonICTDforsocialcontributionsfor1985-1989,asitmatcheswith OECDin1990-2016(andourhistoricalarchive(Alvaredo, 2010)clearlyunderestimatessocialcontributionsinthisperiod).Priorto1985wetrusthistorical archivedataasitmatchesforoverlappingyears(1980s)withICTD
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
Notdeterminedforhistoricalarchivedata.Excludedlocalgovernmenttax revenuesbutincludedprovincialrevenuesforOECDdata
3
4Bangladesh
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1976 2000 1980-81
ICTD 2001 2020
Timeseries
Ourdatastartsin1976.Theseriesfollowshistoricalarchivedatafrom1976through 2000,thenusesICTDdatafrom2001through2020.Weinterpolateyears1980and1981.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforBangladeshareonincometaxationandonsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablein2017-2020.Extrapolationofproportional ratiosfrom2016
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• Unallocabletaxinhistoricaldatapriorto2001.Partofit(fromnoncorporateincometax)includedinPIT,basedonadditionalinformation inpolicydocuments.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%;constantpre-2010(30%), ↓ trend post-2010(30%to26%)
Minusculebutnon-zerolevels.Useof RPC dataforthewholeperiod,extrapolatingyears2014-2020.SSA(2017)indicatesthatthesocialsecuritypolicy beganin1971
Minusculebutnon-zeropropertytaxrevenueinarchivaldata(1965-2001) whilenotpresentinICTD(2001-2020).Nowealthtaxbutrealestatetaxes. Althoughwedonothavedataforpropertytaxrevenueafter2001,weexpect ittobeverysmall
Ourestimatesaremostlikelycentralgovernmentonly,asthereisnomentionof province-levelrevenues.However,externalsources’estimatesofthetax/GDP ratioalsoseemtoexcludedecentralizedrevenues
• Earlyliteratureshowssimilarvalues(Ghafur&Chowdhury, 1988)withthelikeliestsourceof variationbeingthedifferenceintheGDPdenominator.
• Themajorreformandpolicylandmarkswerein1984(anincometaxordinanceundermilitaryrule), 1991(institutingtheVAT)andmorerecentlyin2009(toreformtheVAT).However,tax/GDP ratiohasremainedinverylowvaluesuntilnowadays.
4
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1989 1968-1975(partial)
IDB-CIAT 1990 2020
Timeseries WeuseIDB-CIATdatafordetaileddataonthetaxstructurefrom1990-2018,andrefer tohistoricalarchivedatafortheyearsprior.Foryears2019and2020,weuseinformationfromthejoint publicationbytheOECDandIDB-CIAT,availableat OECD website.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforBrazilareonincometaxation,onsocialcontributionsandonproperty taxation.
Category Adjustment
• Interpolationofincometaxrevenuebetween1968and1975
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
• ExtrapolationofthePITvs.CITsplitbacktothe1960s,from1976
• Incometaxesonnon-residentsconsideredasacorporateincometax
• Unallocableincometaxrevenue2019-2020.ExtrapolationofproportionalratiosofthesplitofCIT/PITfrom2018
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=25%; ↓ trend(30%to22%)
Nodatapriorto1980.Weuse RPC data(RealPoliticalCapacitydatabase, alias‘RPC’)forsocialsecuritypre-1980,‘backcasted’byitsratioin1990with IDB-CIAT
• ThereisnonetwealthtaxonindividualsinBrazil,butthereisamunicipalrealestatetaxandafederaltaxonruralland
• Financialtransactionstax(IOF):consideredhereaspropertytax whereasinoriginalsource(Afonso,Araujo,andVianna (2004),usedfor 1980-1989)wasconsideredanindirecttax.Interpolationofthestructure ofthistaxholdingconstantits1980valuebackto1965andaddingitto theotherpropertytaxes(observedin Chelliah (1971))whilesubtracting itfromtheindirecttaxbill
IDB-CIATaccountsforbothcentralgovernmentrevenueanddecentralized localrevenues.Onthecontrary,thehistoricalarchivedataonlyrefersto thecentralgovernment.However,incometaxisonlyassessedatthecentral governmentlevel,sowecanatleastusethehistoricalarchivematerialforthis purpose
5Brazil
Notes 5
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1994 2007
OECD 2007 2020
Timeseries Inkeepingwithourruletonotincludecommunistcountriespriortotheirtransition,we donotincludeChinabeforeitsfirstyearofmoderntaxsystem,1994(seenotebelow).Foryearsprior to2007,ourChinesegovernmenttimeseriescomesprimarilyfromhistoricalarchivedataonline.We haveuseddigitizedstatisticsfromChina’sStatisticalYearbook(also online)andphysicalcopiesofthe CompendiumofStatisticsfromHarvardarchives,aswellaslong-runpublicfinancedataavailableonline fromtheNationalBureauofStatistics(see link).After2007weuseOECDdata.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforChinaareonsocialcontributionsbefore2019.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1994
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=21%; ↓ trend(27%to15%)
SocialContributions OECDdataisnotavailablebefore2019.Weusehistoricalarchivedatathat coversuntil2018
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues China’sfiscalpolicyhasbeenalwaysundertheoverallauthorityandobservationofthecentralgovernment.Whileitwouldbepossibletoexamine anddisaggregatefurtherthepatternsoftaxonadecentralized(province-byprovince)level,thereislittledoubtthatourestimatesarecapturingallpublic revenues
Notes
• ChineseModernTaxSystem: Inourbenchmarksetting,weonlyincludeformerlycommunist economiesintoourdatastartingin1994.GivenChina’sweightintheglobaleconomy,itisworth reviewingthereasonforthatchoice.ThetaxrevenuedataforChinacoversmostofoursample periodalthoughitsqualityimprovesmarkedlyinthe1980s.
6China
6
Priortothe1980s,Chinahadacommandeconomymodelof‘profitdelivery,’inwhichthestate directlyreceivedtherevenuesofprofitableSOEs,andsubsidizedunprofitableones.Acorporate incometaxfirstappearsinChinain1983-84,butthemajorityofthebasecontinuestobestateownedenterprises.In1985,thetaxsystemwasfurtherreformedintoa‘fiscalcontracting’system wherebyfirmsnegotiatedafixedlump-sumpayment(regardlessofeconomicoutcomes),which cannotbesplitintolaborversuscapitaltaxes(norintoconsumptiontaxes).Wethereforeexclude the‘pseudo’-CITrevenuedatingfrom1985through1993.
Rather,weconsiderthatChina’smoderntaxsystembeganin1994. LouandWang (2008)shows that,in1994,Chinaestablishedforthefirsttimeacentraltaxadministration;reformedthe‘fiscal contracting’system;unifiedthePIT;createdaVAT;andreduced‘extrabudgetary’(non-tax) revenues.Thusfrom1994onwardwecancategorizetaxrevenuepreciselybytype,assignthemto capitalorlabor,andestimateourETR.
• PriorLiteratureonChina: Itisworthhighlightingtwoimportant,externalsourcesofrevenue estimates:theICTDandthoseofUCSDprofessorBarry Naughton (2007).ICTDpatternsagree withoursonbroadordersofmagnitude,fortheyearsinwhichICTDrevenuedataforChinais available,butthesedodifferslightlyintheirclassificationsoftaxrevenues.4
Naughton,inturn,citedstatisticsfromanOECDstudy(Bouin,Coricelli,&Lemoine, 1998).He estimatestotalrevenuein1978(notincludedhereduetothereasonabove)at34percentofGDP,of which22percentagepointswereprofitsandtaxesfromstate-ownedenterprisesand11fromgeneral salestaxes.Ourdifferentglossonthebreakdownofpublicrevenuesatthattimeisactuallyfromtwo causes:(i)oursisahigherestimateofGDP(verifiedfromtheWorldBankandtheWorldInequality Database);and(ii)adifferenttreatmentofstate-ownedenterprises’corporate‘profits.’Therefore wedonottreatasentirely tax revenue,andweapplythegovernment’sownnomenclatureofrevenue categoriestodescribetaxrevenueasroughly40percentofoverallbudgetaryrevenues(andeven lesswhenoneincludesextrabudgetaryrevenues).Ourtotal(budgetary)revenuenumbers,inraw levels,arealwayswithin10percentoftheOECDestimatesfrom1978-94.By1994thediscrepancy intheirtreatmentofpublicrevenuedisappears; Bouinetal. (1998)’sestimateoftax(andtotal budgetary)revenuedropsbelow15percentofGDP—inaccordancewithourownestimates.
4 ItseemslikelythatICTDhasclassifiedthe‘unifiedbusinesstax’asaindirecttaxseriesrevenue(specifically,atypeof consumptiontax),whilewehaveinsteadcategorizedthisasacorporateincometax.Also,ICTDdoesincludesomepersonalincome taxrevenueinthelate1990s,morethan1percentofGDP.ItisunclearfromwherethisnumberisretrievedfortheArticleIV report,asourdatafromthenationalstatisticalbureaulistsminusculeamountsuntilafterthe1999reform.
7
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1989 OECD 1990 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafortheperiodsince1990,butrefertoarchivesourcesforthehistorical periodfrom1965.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforColombiaareonincometaxation.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablebefore1990.Extrapolatethesplitin1990 (firstOECDyear)backthroughthehistoricalperiod,whileusingthe totalincomerevenuelevelsofthehistoricaldata,andbasedonadditional informationinpolicydocuments.
• Unallocableincometaxrevenueafter1990.Weincludeallofitincorporateincometaxrevenuefollowingtheevidenceshowninthe W.Bank (2014)
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=14%; ↓ trend(15%to12%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Marginalimportancebeforeyear2000,showninbothdatasources DecentralizedRevenues Highlevelofcertaintythatthedataincludesbothcentralandlocalgovernment revenues
Notes
• Forthehistoricaldataperiod,ourestimationmatchespreviousliterature.Weshowasimilarraise intaxrevenueforthe1970sas Garc´ıa-Garc´ıaandGuterman-Bromberg (1988).Forthe1980s, ourestimationsarebelow McLureJr (1992)andabove Junguito,Rinc´on,etal. (2004).This discrepancyisexplainedbydifferentconsiderationsofsocialsecurityandindirecttaxes,supporting theideathatdecentralizedtaxationiseitheralreadyincludedimplicitly,ornotsignificantpriorto 1980.
7Colombia
8
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive
Timeseries
Weusehistoricalarchivedatafrom1968to1990,thenICTDdatafrom1991to2018. WerefertoICTDfortheoverallleveloftax/GDPinthe1980sbutrefertoarchivedataforitsdisaggregation(‘within’componentsharesrelativetothattotal).ICTDdataimprovesinqualityonlyafter 1996(whentheyrefertoIMFArticleIVreports),soweinterpolaterelativesharesoftaxes(withinthe overalltax/GDPlevel)fortheyears1992-95.Wealsointerpolateyear1973.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsfortheDemocraticRepublicoftheCongoareonincometaxation.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailableforyears1981and1982.Interpolationof theproportionsofPITvs.CITwithinoverallincometaxrevenueusing 1980and1983asreference
• Unallocableincometaxin1977-1990,andespeciallyrelevantduringthe firstpart(1977-1982).Itincludesadirecttaxcategorycalled’divers’ thatwedecidenottoallocateexclusivelytoCITorPIT,butinstead assignsharesbasedonadditionalpolicydocuments.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=24%; ↑ pre-2000(19%to30%)and ↓ post-2000(30%to26%)
MinusculevalueinICTD,missinginhistoricalarchive.Theverylowvalues inICTDindicatesthatitsabsenceinourarchivaldatadoesnotrepresenta significantgapintheTimeseries
Dataavailableonlyfor2010-2020.AccordingtoIBFD,thereisnowealthtax inDRC,butthereisapropertytax(forallbutagriculturalornon-profituses). However,itsvalueaccordingtoICTDisminusculeforrecentyears.Without havingthedatatoconfirmthat,weexpectthatpropertytaxdonotplaya significantrolefortotalrevenuecollectioninhistoricalperiods
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
• Theearly1990sdropinallrevenuecategoriesisgenuine,asthiswasaperiodofhyper-inflation. Themassivedeclineof(unindexed)taxrevenuecollectionduringhyperinflationisknownasthe Tanzi-Oliveraeffect.Thisisthecommonexplanationforthe1990sfortheDRCsuggestedinprior literature(DeHerdt, 2002; Nachega, 2005).
8DemocraticRepublicoftheCongo
1968 1990 1973 ICTD 1991 2020 1992-95
9
• Thevolatilityofbothdirectandindirecttaxation(andwithinproportionsofeach)arelikely genuine,asDRCwasaresource-dependenteconomyandsubjecttoshocksintheworldpriceof copper(cf. DeHerdt (2002)).
10
Source
Source
Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1989 1965-67,1970-71,1973-74
ICTD 1990 2001
OECD 2002 2020
Timeseries
Weusearchivaldatafortheperiod1965-89(includingIMFhistoricaldata1975-89),then ICTDfrom1990until2001,withOECDdatafrom2002until2020.Weinterpolateyears1965-67, 1970-71and1973-74.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforEgyptareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefor1998.Interpolationofproportionalratiosusing1997and1999
• UnallocableincometaxforOECD(2002-2008).Itisentirelyduetoa taxcalled‘TaxonmovablecapitalrevenuesfromC.B.E’[CentralBank ofEgypt]whichweallocatetocapitalbasedonadditionalpolicydocuments.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=20%; ↓ (25%to15%)
RPC databaseforsocialsecurityrevenuesintheperiods1960-1974and19902001,whenOECDdatabegins.Fortheperiod1975-89werelyonIMFhistoricaldata(historicalarchive)
Availableinthethreesources.Thereisbotharealestatetaxandanagriculturallandtax
WedonotobserveanydecentralizedrevenuesintheOECDdata,norinour archival(norhistoricalIMF)norICTDsource
• Intheoverlapperiods(1987-89and2001-2002)theseriesmatchalmostperfectlyacrosssources. Inaddition,ourseriesmatchthe WorldBank onlinedatabaseforrecentdecades(after1975)as wellastheymatchpriorliteratureforthelate1960sand1970s(Nyrop, 1976; Smith, 1970).
• Thesharpdropintaxrevenuesinthe1980safterthepreviousincreaseinthelate1970sisgenuine, perIMFhistoricaldata.
9Egypt
11
Source
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive
Timeseries Weusehistoricalarchivedatafrom1965through1992,thenturntoICTD(basedon IMFArticleIV)for1993to2019andwerelyagainonhistoricalarchive(basedonEthiopianCentral Bank’sAnnualreport)forthelastyear2020.Weinterpolateyears1989and2005.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforEthiopiaareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablepriorto1975andbetween2008and2019. Extrapolationofproportionalratiosbackfrom1975andinterpolation between2008and2019using2007and2020asareference,andcorroboratebasedonadditionalpolicydocuments.
• Smallunallocableincometaxrevenue(≈ 1%oftotalrevenue)after2001
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%;constant
RPC databaseforthewholeperiod,extrapolatedafter2014.Minusculebut non-zerovalues.AccordingtoSSA(2017),therehasbeenalawinplacesince 1963.Thus,thelittledatasuggestswearenotmissingamajorcomponentof government’staxcollection
AvailableforbothhistoricalarchiveandICTD.PerIBFD,thereisnowealth taxinEthiopia,norarealestatetaxatthefederallevel.Thefactthatwe observepropertytaxrevenue(thelandusefee)seemstoindicatethatweare observingstateandlocaltaxes
Evidencesupportingtheinclusionofstateandlocaltaxes(seePropertytaxation,above)
• Weshowaverygoodmatchonoveralllevelsforthewholeperiodcomparedwith Mascagni (2016).
• 1974markedacoup,aftertheworldoilcrisis,andbeginningasocialisterawhichlastedthrough 1991(notconsideredex-communist,seenoteinPreface, iii).Wedonotobserveanymarked differenceinourdatain1974,butthe1991-92transitioncorrespondstoaconsiderabledeclinein taxrevenuefrombusinesses(corporateincometax),althoughitsoonrecovered
10Ethiopia
1965 1992(2020*) 1989 ICTD 1993 2019 2005
12
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965to2020.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonFrancepresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow.Notwithstanding,theconsiderablyhighvaluesofthecapitalETRarecurrentlyunderrevision.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=13%;stabletrend(14%to12%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
11France Sources
13
12Germany
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965topresent.Thedatapriorto1990isonlyforWest Germany.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonGermanypresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow.There arenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=12%;stabletrend
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
Localtaxesarepresentfrom1973,representingaround9%oftotaltaxrevenue ineveryyear.Inmostcasesmorethan70%ofthesearefromlocalincome taxes,withtheremainderfrompropertyandseveraltypesofsalestaxes
14
Sources Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 2020
Timeseries
OurprimarysourceforIndiangovernmentrevenuestatisticsishistoricalarchivedata. Wecollectdatafromtwoofficialdatasources:priorto2018werelyonIndiastat(websitelink)andfor 2019-2020ontheReserveBankofIndia(websitelink).
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforIndiaareonincometaxation.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailableafter1991.
IncomeTaxation
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
–
Twomainincometaxeslistedinitspublicfinanceaccounting:the ‘corporationtax’andthe‘incometaxotherthancorporationtax.’ Thelatterisnotjustincometaxesonindividuals.However,prior to1991,publicfinancialrecordsweredisaggregatedwithinthis category.Foryearsafter1991,weextrapolatetheproportionof CIT/PITintherevenuecollectedfrom‘incometaxotherthancorporationtax’observedinyearspriorto1991,andcorroboratewith additionalinformationfrompolicydocuments. –
For2019and2020weonlyhaveinformationonCIT/PITsplitfor centralrevenues.Wecomputethe“ratioofratios”for2018:the ratiooftheCIT/PITsplitforcentralrevenuesovertheCIT/PIT splitfortotalrevenues(central+stateandlocal).Assumingaparalleltrendfrom2018to2020,weextrapolatethis“ratioofratios” foryears2019and2020
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=28%; ↓ trend(30%to22%)
ThedatasourcesuseddonotobservedataonsocialcontributionsforIndia. However,accordingtothe SSA(2018),Indiahashadasocialsecuritypolicy inplacesince1952,withawide-rangingsetofcontributionstopublicsocial insurancescheme.Nevertheless,thisrevenuecategoryisunobservedinofficial governmentaswellasUNdata,andlistedaszeroinICTD-IMFdatauntila verysmallamountfrom1998onward(lessthan0.05%ofGDP).Wesuspect itislikelyincludedwithintheincometaxcategory
Includedbutverysmallpriorto2018.Notincludedin2019-2020
Ourdatasetincludescomprehensivelyallsourcesoftaxandnon-taxrevenuefromcentralandstategovernmentspriorto2019.SeeIncomeTaxation (above)fortheadjustmentfor2019-2020
13India
SocialContributions
15
Notes 16
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1996 1968-1971,1994
OECD 1997 2020
Timeseries
Ourmaindatasourceishistoricalarchivedata,through1996,beforeOECDdatabegins in1997.Weinterpolateyears1968-71and1994.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforIndonesiaareonincometaxation.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefrom1985to2001(allunallocabletaxes). Interpolationofproportionalratiosusinginformationfromyearsprior to1985andlaterto2001,andcorroboratedwithadditionalinformation inpolicydocuments
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=29%; ↓ trend(30%to24%)
WedonotobservesocialcontributionsinIndonesia(nordid Amir,AsafuAdjaye,andDucpham (2013)).Accordingto SSA(2017),thefirstsocialsecuritylawwasimplementedin1977.However,thiswasaverysmallproportion ofgovernmentrevenue,astheOECDdatadoesnotbegintoincludeanysocial securityrevenueuntil2015,anditislessthan0.1%ofNDP
Propertytaxationisminusculeaccordingtothereporteddata
Withoutexplicitmentiononit,ourdatasourceseemstobefederal.Either localtaxeswereunimportantortheywerenotaccountedfor.However,OECD datadoesnotincludethemuntil2000,andtheydonotmakeupmorethan 1%ofthetotalrevenueuntil2013
• ItisworthhighlightinghownaturalresourcerevenueshavebeenimportantandsignificantinIndonesia. Gillis (1985)estimatedthatoilandgastaxrevenuesrosefrom1.2%in1968to16.0% ofGDPby1981,while Ribeiro,Villafuerte,Baunsgaard,andRichmond (2012)estimatecurrent (public)resourcerevenueat4.5%ofGDP.Resourcerevenueexplainsmostofthedifferencesobservedbetweenourestimationsandpriorliterature(suchas Gillis (1985)and Prasetyo (2018)). Forourpurpose,weattempttostitchtogetheraseriesonthestrictlytaxrevenueswithIndonesia’s publicfinance(agreeingalsowithestimationsfrom Amiretal. (2013)).
• TheVATwasintroducedin1984(replacingsalestaxandturnovertax).Afterthat,recentreforms havelargelybeenaimedatincreasingrevenueandcomplianceasIndonesiawasseenasalow-taxeffortcountry.
14Indonesia
17
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965topresent.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonItalypresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow.There arenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• Unallocableincometaxinsomeyearsfrom1980to2020
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=17%; ↓ trend(27%to12%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
Localgovernmentrevenueispresentinthedatasince1973,butrepresentsan increasing(andmorethan3%)shareoftotaltaxrevenueonlysincethemid1990s,andhasgrownto15%ofoveralltaxrevenue.Theincreaseislargely duetothepresenceoflocalsalestaxes,althoughthereisalsoamiscellaneous localbusinesstax
15Italy Sources
18
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965topresent.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonJapanpresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow.There arenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=11%; ↑ trendpre-2000(11%to14%)and ↓ trendpost-2000(14%to9%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation included
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
Localgovernmentrevenueispresentinthedatasince1973,andrepresentsa steady23-28%oftotaltaxrevenue.Incometaxesrepresentadecreasingshare oflocaltaxrevenue,butstillmorethanhalf(downfrom60%from1973-92). Propertytaxeshavegainedinimportancewhatincometaxeshavelost,up from20to30%oftotallocaltaxrevenuesincethe1970s
16Japan
19
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 2000
OECD 2001 2020
Timeseries Weusehistoricalarchivedatafortheyears1965-2000,andthenOECDdataforthe periodfrom2001to2020.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforKenyaareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitofCIT/PITavailablepre-1974reform(reviewedhistoricalinformationonPAYEvs.employer-surtaxregulations)andpost-2002(OECD). Interpolationofproportionalratiosforyears1973-2001,anduseadditionalinformationtoverifyinterpolatedshares.
• Unallocableincometaxafter2001.From2001to2014allocatedtotallytoPIT(withholdingtax),whereasfrom2015to2020allocatedto CIT/PITaccordingtoOECDsheets(partwithholdingtaxtoPITand partcapitalgainstoCIT)
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=28%; ↓ trend(30%to26%)
Reallysmallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod.Werelyonexternalsources fortheperiodpriortoOECDdata(2000): RPC datapre-1996andUNfor 1996-2000.
PerIBFDthereisnotacapitaltax,butthereisalocalgovernmenttaxon landvalue.Wedonotobservethesetaxesinourarchivematerial
Weareonlyabletocollectrevenuesofthecentralgovernment,withnoinformationatthesub-nationallevel
• Ourestimationmatcheswithpriorliterature,bothinlevelsandtrends(Karingi&Wanjala, 2005; Macha,Lado,&Nyansera, 2018).Littledivergences,especiallyatincometaxationfortheearliest period(Maina, 2014)arelikelyexplainedbythevalueofthedenominator(GDP).
• Thestructureofthekenyantaxsystemhasbeenstableovertime(Wawire, 1991)withsome taxreformsexpandingproductiontaxes(salesandVAT),especiallyduringthe1980s(Karingi& Wanjala, 2005).
17Kenya Sources
20
18Korea(Republicof)
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1971 1968-1971
OECD 1972 2020
Timeseries Weusehistoricalarchivedatafortheperiod1965-71,thenOECDfromitsdebutin1972. Weinterpolatefrom1968to1971,astherewereseveralmissingelementsintheavailablearchivaldata forthatperiod.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ForKorea,therearenotmajoradjustmentsspecificallyearmarkedforaparticulartaxcategory.The mainadjustmentcomesfromtheinterpolatedperiod1968-1971(seeNotes).
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=12%; ↓ trendpre-2000(17%to11%)and ↑ trendpost-2000(11%to14%)
Onlypresentafter1985.Accordingto SSA(2017),socialsecurityprograms didnotbeginuntil1973anddidnotincludeanationalpension(beyonda ‘welfare’pension)until1986–ahistorymatchingourOECDrevenuedata PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
Decentralizedrevenueisnotincludedinthearchivaldata.However,the1967 levels(finalyearofthisdatasource)arenotfarofffromthe1972levels(first yearofOECD).Inaddition,previousliteraturealsoshowverylowlevelof localrevenue(lessthan2%ofrevenue)(Kwack&Lee, 1992).
• Thelowlevelsofrevenueinthe1960saregenuine(andnotanartifactof,e.g.,incompletedata),as thegovernment’soveralldevelopmentstrategyfavoredtheinflowofforeigncapital,implementing majortaxreformsduringthisperiod(Yoo, 2000).Onlyafterthe1967taxreformwhena‘global incometax’wasintroducedforthefirsttimeiswhentaxrevenueincreasedinKorea(ibid.).This slightincreaseinpersonalandcorporateincometaxrevenuematcheswiththeinterpolatedperiod.
21
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
HistoricalArchive 1965 1979
OECD 1980 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1980,andrefertodatafromarchivesbefore1980.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforMexicoareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• NoCIT/PITsplitfrom1980to2001.Interpolationofratiosusing1979 archivedataand2002OECDdataasreferences,andadjustedbasedon informationinadditionalpolicydocuments.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=15%, ↑ trendpre-1985(23%to35%), ↓ trend1985-2013(35%to8%)and ↑ trendpost-2013(8%to16%)
Lackofsocialcontributionsfrom1970to1979.Interpolationfrom1969until 1980(whenOECDbeggins)
Negligiblevalue.ThereisapropertytaxinMexico(”impuestopredial”)but accountsforonly0.02%ofGDP.Thisestimationofpropertytaxrevenues matches Madrigal-Delgado (2021)
StateandlocaltaxrevenuescollectedinOECD.Ourhistoricalarchivedata (1965-1979)matchesthestitchyear(1980),butwecannotcorroboratethe inclusionofalldecentralizedrevenuesbefore1980
• Thereisaconsiderableriseinindirecttaxrevenuessince1980,thesameyearthatwestitchacross datasources.However,thejumpisgenuineandnotanartifactofstitching.Thisincreaseisthe resultofthecreationoftheVATin1980,leadingtohigherindirecttaxcompliance(Burgess& Stern, 1993).
19Mexico Sources
22
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1990
ICTD 1991 2009 2008-2009
OECD 2010 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatasince2010,andhistoricalarchivedatastartingfrom1965.Weuse ICTDdatafortheyears1991through2009.Weinterpolateyears2008and2009.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforNigeriaareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailable1987-1991.Interpolationofproportional ratiosrelyingon1986and1992andoverallincometaxrevenueobserved foreachyear,andinformationinadditionalpolicydocuments.
• Unallocableincometaxrevenuebetween1970and1986.Allocatedto CITbasedonhistoricalsources.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=27%; ↓ pre-1980(30%to26%), ↑ 1980-1985 (26%to30%)and ↓ post-1985(30%to24%)
RPC databasepriorto2010andOECDdatabaselaterto2010.Minuscule butnon-zero(RPC andOECDperiods)andzero(ICTDperiod).According toSSA(2017),therehasbeenasocialsecurity(pension)lawinplacesince 1961,althoughthemostrecentversiondatesto2014.Itispossiblethatthe levelsaretoolowtoappearinICTDdataandforthegovernmenttotrackin centralizedbudgetandrevenuestatistics
ThereisnotaxonnetworthinNigeria,andwedonotobserveanyproperty taxesinanyofourdatasources
Therevenuesinourarchivaldatasourcearefederalrevenues,ofthecentral government.Per IBFD(2019),somestateschargearealestatetax,butwe findnorecordoftheirmeasurementandmagnitude.Therearenoincome taxesatthesubnationallevel
• Competingsourcesofdatadonotalwayspreciselymatchonlevels,buttheydomatchontrends.
• Ourestimatespresentdifferencesfrom EkpoandNdebbio (1996).Itmightbeduetothetreatment ofvolatile non-tax revenue,anddifficultyclassifyingpublicrevenuestreams.
20Nigeria
23
• OilrevenuesarethemajorstoryinNigeria,especiallyasasourceofcapital(Ribeiroetal., 2012). Indeed,weobservethespikeincapitalincomeandrevenueduringthe1970soilpriceshocksand itssubsequentdropinthe1980scoincidentwiththecollapseinoilprices(Pinto, 1987).
24
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 2020
Timeseries
Amongarchivalsources,weusecentralgovernmentsourcesforfederalstatistics,with particularattentiontoparallelpublicationsforprovincialstatistics.Between2015and2020wecollect theshareoffederaltaxrevenuethatiscollectedattheprovinciallevel.Asthisrevenueisonlyavailable inaggregatedterms,weassumethattheshareofeachtaxcategoryisequalacrossthefederalrevenue andtheshareofitthatiscollectedattheprovinciallevel.Wecomplimentthatwith“pureprovincial” taxrevenue.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforPakistanareonincometaxationanddecentralizedrevenues.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITonlyavailablefor1965-1980(fromhistoricalarchive)and 1994-2004(fromICTD-IMF):i)interpolationofCIT/PITsplitratios from1980to1994andii)extrapolationofCIT/PITsplitratiosfrom 2004topresent,bothverifiedwithadditionalpolicydocuments.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=29%; ↓ trend(30%to26%)
Minisculebutnon-zerolevels.Accordingto SSA(2018),thefirstlawwas passedin1972,butfirstimplementedin1976,whichcorroboratesourarchival datathatbeginsin1973(alsoshownin Syeda (2015))
Taxesonassetsareminusculebutnon-zero,andlargerintheearlyperiod (especiallyatprovinciallevel).AccordingtotheIBFD,thereisatax(since 2013)on‘netmovablewealth’,a zakat wealthtaxonMuslimsandan ushr onagriculturalland.The10%propertytaxaswellasalandtaxonfarm holdingsgreaterthanfiveirrigatedacres(ortenunirrigated)areassessedat theprovincelevel
• Provincialtaxrevenuedatafor1947-2014,benchmarkingeveryfour yearsandeverytimeasignificanttypeoftaxcomesintooroutofthe long-rundataseries.Interpolationoftheinterveningyears
• For2015-2020wefollowtheprocessexplainedin‘Timeseries’
• Hasan,Kemal,andNaseem (1997)is0.2-0.3percentagepointshigherthanourestimations.
21Pakistan Sources
25
22Phillipines
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1993
OECD 1994 2020
Timeseries Weusehistoricalarchivedatafrom1965through1993,thenturntoOECDdataforthe periodsincethen.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemajoradjustmentsinPhillipinesareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefrom1978to1998.Interpolationofproportionalratiosusing1977and1999asreference,andcorroboratedwith additionalhistoricalsources.
• Someunallocableincometaxduringtheearly2000s
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=25%; ↓ trend(29%to20%)
Weuseexternaldatapriorto1994(UNSNA)andrelyonOECDforthe periodsincethen
OECDdataincludesacentralgovernmentwealthtax(onstocktransactions) andamuchmoresignificantlocalgovernmentpropertytaxestimate(0.5%of GDP).Wedonothavethisestimateinourarchivaldata
Wedonothavesub-nationalrevenuesfortheperiodweusearchivaldata(pre1994).However,thesmoothevolutionacrosssourcessuggeststhatonlysmall revenuecomesfromthestateandlocallevel(lessthan5%ofthetotaltax revenueforOECDperiod)
26
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation OECD 1994 2020
Timeseries Inkeepingwithourruletonotincludecommunistcountriespriortotheirtransition,we donotincludePolandbefore1994.WeuseOECDdatafrom1994to2020.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonPolandpresentdetailedinformationafter1994onallthetaxcategoriesshown below.Therearenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1994
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=11%; ↓ trendpre-2005(12%to10%)and ↑ trendpost-2005(10%to12%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
23Poland Sources
27
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1994 1999 1994-97
ICTD 2000 2020
Timeseries Inkeepingwithourruletonotincludecommunistcountriespriortotheirtransition,we neitherincludeSovietRussianoranySovietstates(intheeraoftheUSSR)inourcalculations.Forthe pre-2000period,weuseestimatesfrom Ivanova,Keen,andKlemm (2005).Forthepost-2000periodwe relyonICTDdata.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforRussiaareonalltaxcategoriesforthefirstyearsobserved(1994-1998)and onpropertytaxationforthewholesample.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1994
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=15%;constanttrend
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
LittleinformationonpropertytaxinRussiafromoursources,asitisfrequentlylumpedwith‘othertaxes’(caseofICTD). Preobragenskayaand McGee (2003)indicatethatitdoesnotexceed2%ofGDPand Owenand Robinson (2003)indicatethatpropertytaxwasalwaysbetweenapproximately 0.5and1.5%ofGDPfrom1994-99.Forsimplicitywesetitequalto1percent, intheabsenceofbetter(andmorerecent)data
Dethier (2000)notesthatthe1990swereaperiodofgrowingfiscaldecentralization.Comparingourestimatestotheirssupportstheideathatweare includingdecentralizedrevenuesinourestimatesofRussia’spublicfinance timeseries
• TheIMFdatafor1994-2003matcheswelltheICTDdatathatbeginsin2000.
24Russia
28
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1989
OECD 1990 2020
Timeseries Weusehistoricalarchivedatafor1965-89,thenOECDdatafortheperiodsincethen.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforSouthAfricaareonincometaxation.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITbefore1990onlyavailableatfive-yearintervals(1966, 1971,1976,1981,1986).Fortherestoftheyearsbefore1990:interpolationofthewithin-ratiosusingthefive-yearintervalsasreference.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=21%; ↓ trend(22%to19%)
Wedonotobservesocialcontributionsbefore2000eventhoughinprinciple thesocialsecuritypolicywasestablishedin1928(SSA2017).However,neither alternativesources(OECD,ICTD,IMF,historicalarchive)norotherprimary sources(S.A.R.Bank, 2016)includeanysocialsecurityrevenuepriorto2001
Small(especiallypre-2000)butnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod.Years19671972areinterpolated
OECDobserveszerostateandlocaltaxesuntil2002.Thepre-1990archive dataisdrawnsolelyfrom(andregarding)centralgovernmentfinancerecords. Weassumelocalandstatetaxeswerealsozerobefore1990
25SouthAfrica
29
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965topresent.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonSpainpresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow.There arenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• Negligibleunallocableincometaxpriorto1994derivedfromlocaltax
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=16%; ↓ trend(23%to12%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
Localgovernmentrevenue(mainlysalesandbusinesstax)ispresentinthe datasince1973,butrepresentsanincreasing(andmorethan3%)shareof totaltaxrevenueonlysincethemid-1990s,andhasgrownto15%ofoverall taxrevenue
• ThesharpdeclineincorporateincometaxrevenuescoincideswiththebeginningoftheGreat Recession.
Sources
26Spain
30
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1972 1980 ICTD 1981 2020
Timeseries
ThedataseriesforSudanstartsin1972.WeusedatafromtheIMFhistoricalsource from1972to1980,thenICTDdatafrom1981.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemajoradjustmentsforSudanareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• Totalincometaxationrevenuenotavailablefrom1981to1990.Interpolationoftheshareoftotalincometaxationovertotaltaxrevenueusing 1980and1991asreference,andconfirmedinadditionalsources.
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablebefore1994andafter2006withsomemissingyearsbetween1994and2006.For1980-1991interpolationofproportionalratiosusing1980and1991asreference,andcorroboratedwith historicalsources.FormissingyearsinICTDperiodpre-2006,interpolationofCIT-to-total-PITratios.Forperiodpre-1994andpost-2006, extrapolationofconstantCIT-to-total-PITratios.
• AllunallocableincometaxrevenueisallocatedtoPIT,basedonadditionalpolicydocuments.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=29%; ↓ trendpre-2005(30%to28%)and ↑ trendpost-2005(28%to30%)
Minusculebutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod.Werelyonexternalsources (RPC data)Assumedasconstantafter2014
Onlyavailableinhistoricalarchivedata(1970s),butnegligibleinquantity DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
27Sudan
31
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 2020 1972,1977,1993-95
Timeseries Weusehistoricalarchivedataforaunifiedseriesfrom1965to2020,interpolatingseveral yearsandstitchingacrosstwodatasources,wheretheseconddatasourcecameintoeffectin1996.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforTanzaniaareonincometaxation.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablebefore1974.Extrapolationbackfrom1974 to1965oftheproportionalratiosof1974withthetotalincomerevenue collectedforeachyear,verifiedwithhistoricalsources.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%;constantpre-2010(30%)and ↓ trend post-2010(30%to28%)
Minusculebutnon-zerovaluesoverthewholeperiod.AccordingtoSSA,there hasbeenalawinplacesince1964,whileaplethoraofregulationsgovernthe currentfundsfromsocialcontributions(IBFD)
Minusculebutnon-zerovaluebefore1990,andmissingafter1990.According toIBFD,thereisnowealthtax,butthereisarealestatetaxsince1974. However,alternativesources(ICTD,IMF)showhowthistaxdoesnotforma largepartofICTDorIMFestimates
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
• OurestimationsaresignificantlybelowpriorliteratureforTanzania(Fjeldstad, 1995; Nordetal., 2009; Osoro, 1993).However,wefindcorrespondenceinthe within-weightoftypesoftaxes,as aproportionoftotaltaxrevenue.ApotentialexplanationpointstodifferencesinGDP’svalues (checkforinstance WorldBank(2019)).Wesuspectthatscholarswereusingthesamepublic revenuenumbersasusbutasmallerGDPdenominator.Asaresult,withsamerevenuesources theywouldhavefoundahighertax-to-GDPratio.
• The1990srevenuetrendappearsgenuine(notanartifactofourdataconstruction),aftercomparing notesacrossthesesources.Itcorrespondswithaperiodofnotablereforms:anotablecivilservice reformintheearly1990s,theinstitutionoftheTanzaniaRevenueAuthority(TRA)inthemid1990s,andotherreformsinthelate1990s(includingimpositionoftheVATin1998).
28Tanzania
Sources
32
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1999 1972,980,1985, 1987,1994,1998
OECD 2000 2020
Timeseries
Weusehistoricalarchivedatafortheperiodthrough1999,thenOECDdatafrom2000 to2020.OurarchivaldataforThailandislessexhaustivethanforothercountriesandfeaturesmore interpolationthaninothercountries.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemajoradjustmentsinThailandaremainlyduetothelargeinterpolationduringthewholeperiod. Inaddition,somemodificationsaremadeonsocialcontributionsandpropertytax.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITavailablefortheyearsforwhichwehavedata
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• Verysmallunallocableincometaxduringthe1980s
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=22%; ↓ trend(30%to15%)
Lowbutdifferentfromzeroafter1980.Weuseexternaldatapriorto2000 (UNSNAdatabase,interpolating1997-1999)andOECDfortheperiodsince then
Lowbutdifferentfromzeroduringthewholeperiod.Forperiodpriorto2000 werelyonIMFdata.Thereisnowealthtaxbutthereisalocalpropertytax. WecapturethelatterinourOECDdatabutitisnotavailableinourarchival datasource
ItislikelythattheOECDdatacontainslocalgovernmenttaxrevenues,while ourarchivaldatadoesnot.However,thesmoothevolutionacrosssources suggestsasub-nationallevelofrevenuethatissmallbyordersofmagnitude
• Ourestimationmatchespreviousliteraturebothinlevelsandtrends(Bernardi,Fumagalli,& Gandullia, 2005; Jansen&Khannabha, 2012).
29Thailand Sources
33
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965to2020.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonTurkeypresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow.There arenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• Unallocableincometaxinthe1970s
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=16%; ↓ trend(22%to11%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
Localgovernmentdataispresentsince1980,andrepresentsusuallybetween near9or10%oftotaltaxrevenueperOECD,spikingat16%in1998
30Turkey Sources
34
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1991 1984,1991
OECD 1992 2020
Timeseries Weusearchivedataforthehistoricalperiodfrom1965,thenOECDdatafrom1992. Years1984and1991areinterpolated.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemajoradjustmentsforUgandaareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablepriorto1990forthehistoricalarchivedata. WeuseIMFhistoricaldatafor1972-1990.Weinterpolateproportional ratiospriorto1972andforyears1987and1989
• Verysmallunallocableincometaxrevenuesince1998
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=27%; ↑ trendpre-1990(27%to30%)and ↓ trendpost-1990(30%to23%)
Wedrawon RPC dataforsocialcontributions.Thevalueisrelativelysmall, anddoesnotappearinOECDdata.Weextrapolatefortheperiodfrom2014 topresentas RPC dataforsocialcontributionsismissingfortheseyears
Notincluded.Therearenonetwealth/worthtaxesinUganda.Property taxesareadministeredbythelocalauthoritiesannually.Theyarebasedon thevalueofthepropertyasassessedbythelocalauthorities
Notdetermined.Possiblynotincluded(atleastthepartderivedfromproperty taxes)
• ThematchbetweenarchivedatasourcesandOECDdataisveryclose.
31Uganda
35
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965to2020.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonUnitedKingdompresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshown below.Therearenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=14%; ↓ trendpre-1990(16%to11%)and ↑ trendpost-1990(11%to14%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
32UnitedKingdom
Sources
36
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965to2020.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonUnitedStatespresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow. Therearenomajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=16%; ↓ trend(22%to12%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
33UnitedStatesofAmerica
37
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
IMF 1994 2002
OECD 2003 2020
Timeseries Inkeepingwithourruletonotincludecommunistcountriespriortotheirtransition,we donotincludeVietnambefore1994.WerefertoIMFTimeseriesuntil2002andtoOECDrevenues seriesfrom2003to2020.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemajoradjustmentsinVietnamareonsocialcontributions.Socialcontributionsarenotincluded hereeventhoughweareawarethattheyrepresentaconsiderableshare(atleastafter2010).
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1994
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=26%; ↓ trend(30%to19%)
Wedonothavedataonsocialcontributionsuntil2010(theIMFdoesnot includeitandOECDonlyavailableafter2010).However,accordingtoSSA (2018),Vietnamhasalongstandingsocialsecuritypolicy(1961,pre-dating thewar).For2010-2020,socialcontributionsaccountsforaverysignificant partofthetotaltaxrevenue(4-6%ofGDP).Aswedonothavedatapriorto 2010,wedecidetotemporarilyexcludesocialcontributionshere.Thisdecision significantlyunderstatestheestimationsonrevenue/ETRonlaborincome,so weurgethereadertokeepthatinmindwheninterpretingthegraphs
PropertyTaxation
Verysmall(especiallyinOECDdata)butnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
• Thedropinindirecttaxationin2020isgenuine,asitisconfirmedbythesource,theOECD revenuestatistics.
34Vietnam Sources
38
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation OECD 1965 1998
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965to2020.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonAustraliapresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow.There arenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=13%; ↓ trendpre-1985(15%to8%)and
↑ trendpost-1985(8%to15%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
35Australia
39
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1992 1969-1970,1989
OECD 1993 2020
Timeseries
Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafortheinitialperiod1965-1992,andweuseOECDfor theperiodsincethen.Wehighlightthatforthehistoricalarchiveperiod,useinformationfrom Amin (1998)for1969-1992tohelpassigntaxestotax-typesinspecificyears.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThereareadjustmentsonCameroonforincometaxation,socialcontributionsandpropertytaxes.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailableforperiod1969-1992.Interpolationofproportionalratiosusing1968and1993asreference,andcorroboratedbased onhistoricalsources.
• SmallunallocableincometaxrevenueduringtheOECDperiod(19932020)
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=29%;fluctuatingbetween27%and30%
Useofexternalsource(RPC data)from1965to1993.Per SSA(2017) social securitypolicydatesto1969,while RPC hasdatafrom1960.However,itis asmalllevel(0.5%ofGDP)andonlyrisesabove1%ofGDPin1969.We adjustfortheperiod1989-1993byinterpolatinglevelsinsteadofrelyingon RPC (whichislowerthanOECDduringtheperiodoftheiroverlap)
Availableonlyintermittentlyfortheperiod1969-1992,thoughlimiteddecentralizedrevenuessuggestitmaynotbeamajorsourceoftaxcollection(but worthyoffurtherinvestigation).
Notdeterminedinhistoricalarchiveperiod(1965-1992),notincludedinOECD period(post-1993)
• The‘taxeunique’isatypeofindirecttax,replacingothers,asapreferentialtaxstatus(Gauthier, Soloaga,&Tybout, 2002),eventhoughitisnottheonlysourceofrevenueforCameroon(Gauthier &Gersovitz, 1997).Tradetaxesaccountedforupto50%oftotaltaxrevenueinthemid-1960s, butitfellto10%bythemid-1970sanddowntolessthan5%bythe1990s(shownin Amin (1998)).
36Cameroon
40
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WeuseOECDdatafrom1965to2020.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonCanadapresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow. Notwithstanding,theextremelyhighvaluesofthecapitalETRarecurrentlyunderrevision.See MethodologyNoteintheAtlaswebsiteforfurtherdetailsonthisissue.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=13%; ↓ trendpre-2008(14%to11%)and ↑ trendpost-2008(11%to13%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
37Canada Sources
41
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1989 1977-1979,1987-1989
OECD 1990 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivedatabefore1990andweuseOECDfortheperiodsince then.Years1977-1979and1987-1989areinterpolated.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforCoted’Ivoirearemadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablebefore1982.Interpolationofproportional ratiosbasedon1963and1986-1989(relyingforthatonICTDdata),and corroboratedinadditionalpolicysources.Inaddition,splitCIT/PIT fromOECDhasbeencorrected:allocationtoPIToftheconsistent ‘wedge’betweenthesocialcontributionsseriesaccordingtoOECDvs accordingtoICTD
• Unallocableincometaxrevenueinhistoricalarchivedata(allistaxon ‘b´en´efices’,allocatedasexplainedabove),verysmallinmagnitude,exists alsoinOECDdata
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=13%; ↓ trendpre-2008(14%to11%)and ↑ trendpost-2008(11%to13%)
RelyonICTDvaluesfor1980-2010.For2010-2020,OECDvaluesdividedby theratioOECD/ICTDfrom2010.Formissingyearspriorto1980,interpolationbasedonavailableobservations
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
38Coted’Ivoire
42
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1967 1999 OECD 2000 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafortheperiod1967-1999andweuseOECDdatafor theperiodsincethen.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforGhanaaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablepriorto1972.Backwardextrapolationfrom 1972to1965using1972asreference
• Smallbutnon-zerounallocableincometaxrevenueafter1989.Priorto 2000,historicalarchivehasverysmallrevenuefrom‘taxoninterestand dividends’thatisnotincludedassuchinOECDdata.Duetoitssmall magnitude,wedonotimplementanyfurtheradjustmenthere.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=28%; ↑ trendpre-1980s(28%to30%)and ↓ trendpost-1990(30%to24%)
Relyinexternalsources(RPC data)forthehistoricalarchiveperiodpriorto 2000
Localtax,verysmallbutnon-zeroinsomeyearsofhistoricalarchive.Not availableinOECDdata
Notfullydeterminedbefore2000(onlyavailablealocalpropertytaxforsome years).Notincludedafter2000(OECDdata)
• Ourestimationsmatchpriorliterature(Osei&Telli, 2017).Inaddition,thesameliterature corroboratesthestrangepatternsofthe1980sincludingthetwoconsecutiveperiodsoffiscal managementunderIMFrecoveryandstructuraladjustmentsprogramsduringthemiddleandend ofthedecade,intothe1990s.
39Ghana
Sources
43
40Madagascar
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1989 1969-1971,1974-1976,1981-1983
ICTD 1990 1998
OECD 1999 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivedataforyearspriorto1990,movetoICTDforthe1990sand useOECDfortheperiodsince1999.OurhistoricalarchivedatabaseforMadagascarislessexhaustive thanforothercountries.Indeed,weinterpolateasignificantnumberofyears.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforMadagascararemadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITavailablefortheyearsforwhichwehavedata(notfor interpolatedyears)
• Unallocableincometaxfor1965-1968includedinPIT,basedonadditionalpolicydocuments
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%;stablepre-1975(29%-30%)and constantpost-1975(30%)
Relyonexternalsources(RPC data)forthewholeperiod.Extrapolationof constantvaluesforyearspost-2014
Verysmallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod
Notdeterminedbefore1999(ICTDdata),andnotincludedafter1999(OECD data)
44
41Malaysia
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1989 1979-1980,1988
OECD 1990 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivefrom1965to1989andweuseOECDfortheperiodsince then.Weinterpolateyears1979,1980,and1988.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforMalaysiaaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablebefore1978.WeuseIMFhistoricaldatato assigntoPITandCIT.Extrapolatedbackwardsforyearspriorto1975 using1976asareference,andcorroboratedwithIMFinformation.
• Smallbutnon-zerounallocableincometaxrevenuesince1988
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=20%; ↓ trend(28%to15%)
Relyonexternaldata(RPC data)before1971.Extrapolatevaluesfor19721999using1971(from RPC data)and2000(fromfirstyearofOECDthat includessocialcontributions)asreference
Notincludedinhistoricalarchive(pre-1990)andincludedbutbarelyzeroin OECDdata(post-1990)
Notdetermined
• Thereisagapinthestitchingyear1990,betweenhistoricalarchiveandOECD,of0.7percentage pointsofGDPforspecifictaxtypes.Thisshortfallisanartifactofwhatisincludedin‘indirect taxes’andin‘othertaxes’.Itseemslikehistoricalarchiveisincludingstampdutiesinunallocable incometaxeswhereasOECDallocatesthemtoothertaxes.Ontheotherhand,theOECDincludes amotorvehicletaxnotcollectedinhistoricalarchive.
• Thelate1980sdropinrevenueiscorroboratedinICTDdata(referringtoIMFArticleIV).
45
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1999 19661971-19731995
OECD 2000 2020
Timeseries
Weusehistoricalarchivedatafrom1965to1999andrefertoOECDfortheperiodsince then.Weinterpolateyears1966,1971-1973and1995.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemajoradjustmentsforMoroccoareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefrom1988to1996.Interpolationofproportionalratiosusing1987and1997asreference,andusinginformation fromhistoricaldocuments
• Unallocableincometaxrevenuebefore1999.Allocatedcompletelyto PIT,basedonadditionalpolicydocuments.
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=28%;constantpre-1986(30%)and ↓ trend post-1986(30%to22%)
Externaldatapriorto2000(RPC data)
Weobservewealthtaxdataatafederallevelallthewaybackto1965.However,weincludelocalpropertytaxdataonlyafter2000(whenOECDbecomes available)
WeobservefederalandlocaltaxesintheOECDperiodbutwedonothave dataonsub-nationaltaxesinourarchivaldata
• Thelackofsub-nationalrevenuepriorto2000couldexplainthechangesobservedin1999-2000: i)thebumpinindirecttaxes(likelyrevenuethatwasincludedinnon-taxrevenueinourarchival data)andii)theincreaseinpropertytaxrevenue(localpropertytaxincludedafter1999).
• ThespikeinCITin1975aswellasthedipinindirecttaxesin1986aregenuine.
42Morocco
46
43Mozambique
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 2014 1991,2001
ICTD 2015 2020
Timeseries
Westarttheseriesin1975(firstpost-independenceyearwithconsistentdata).Werefer tohistoricalarchivefrom1965to2014andweuseICTDfortheperiodsincethen.Weinterpolateyears 1991and2001.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforMozambiqueareondirecttaxationandsocialcontributions.Additionally, theextremelyhighvaluesofthecapitalETRarecurrentlyunderrevision.SeeMethodologyNotein theAtlaswebsiteforfurtherdetailsonthisissue.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablebetween1994and2014.Weuse Castro, Junquera-Varela,Schenone,andTeixeira (2009)fortheperiod1994-2007 andextrapolateproportionalratiosfrom2007to2014
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%;constanttrendpre-2010(30%)and ↓ trendpost-2010(30%to28%)
Relyonexternalsources(RPC database),constantvalueforthewholeperiod (0.001%).Extrapolationofthatconstantvalueforperiodpost-2014
NotincludedinhistoricalarchiveandclosetozeroinICTDdata
Notdetermined
• 1980sdipinrevenueisgenuine,perICTDcorroboration.
• Thebigincreaseinrevenueafter2010issupportedbytheoverlappingperiodbetweenhistorical archiveandICTD(2014-2015).
47
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1976 2005
ICTD 2006 2020 2018-2020
Timeseries
Westarttheseriesin1976.Werefertohistoricalarchivefrom1976to2005andweuse ICTDfortheperiodsincethen(year2005reliesonICTDforindirecttaxation).Weinterpolateyears 2018,2019and2020.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforNepalaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailableforpre-1987,2006-2009andpost-2017.For pre-1987:extrapolationbackusing1987asreference,andcorroborated usinghistoricalsources.For2006-2009,interpolationusing2005and 2010asreferences.Forpost-2017,extrapolationusing2017asreference
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=29%;constanttrendpre-2005(30%)and ↓ trendpost-2005(30%to26%)
Relyonexternalsources(RPC data)forthehistoricalarchiveperiod,pre-2006 (andyears2010and2011)
Itevolvesfromsmall(0.2%ofGDP)inhistoricalarchive(2005)tozeroin ICTD(post-2005).Wehighlightthisissue,althoughitisnotsignificantfor ourpurposeduetothelimitedsizeofpropertytaxescollected
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
44Nepal
48
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1999 1969-1972
OECD 2000 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivefrom1965to1999andweuseOECDfortheperiodsince then.Weinterpolatetheperiod1969-1972.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforNigeraremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablebefore1975andin1999.Extrapolationback from1975to1965,confirmedinadditionaldocuments,andinterpolation ofyear1999usingOECDperiod
• UnallocableincometaxrevenueallocatedtoPITfortheperiod19751998(‘surunrˆole’and‘g´en´eral’areassignedtoPITinsteadofremaining unallocable,basedonpolicydocuments)
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=29%;constanttrendpre-2005(30%)and ↓ trendpost-2005(30%to26%)
Relyonexternalsource(RPC data)through1998,interpolationof1999(outliervalue).Accordingto SSA(2017) thefirstsocialsecuritylawwasin1967, sowedonotincludedatafrom RPC before1967(RPC estimatesitat0.2% ofGDP)
Verysmallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod(withsomediscrepancybetweenhistoricalarchiveandOECDestimatesofpropertytaxin1999)
Notdeterminedforhistoricalarchivedata(1965-1999),notincludedforthe OECDperiod(2000-2020)
45Niger
49
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1989 1965-1967
OECD 1990 2020
Timeseries
Werefertohistoricalarchivefrom1965to1989andweuseOECDfortheperiodsince then.Valuesforyears1965and1967areextrapolatedbackwards.Wecalculatetheratiosofeachtax category’s(fromhistoricalarchivedata)shareoftotalrevenue(from RPC data)in1968,andextrapolate thembackto1965usingaggregatedvaluesfrom RPC datafor1965to1967.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforPeruaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefrom1983to1989.Interpolationusing1982 and1990asreference
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• Unallocableincometaxsmallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod. AllocatedallofittoPITfortheinterpolatedperiod(1983-1989),based onhistoricalsources
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=27%; ↓ trend(30%to22%)
Externaldata(RPC data)forthehistoricalarchiveperiod(pre-1990)
OECDaccountsforthreetypesofwealthtaxes(individual,corporateandfinancialandcapitaltransactions),whereashistoricalarchivedataonlyaccounts foroneheading‘impuestoalpatrimonio’.Thereisagapbetweenhistorical archiveandOECDthatmightbeexplainedbythefactthatsomeofthelatter taxescollectedintheOECDwerelocal-level
OECDincludesinformationonsub-nationalleveltaxes(explicitelyafter2000, butthesmoothevolutionsuggesttheyareincludedintotalrevenuein19902000).Onthecontrary,theevidencefrompropertytaxes(above)indicatesa lackofinformationregardingdecentralizedrevenuesinhistoricalarchivedata. However,thematchingfortherestofthecategoriesintheoverlappingperiod (1990-1994)suggeststhatothersub-national-leveltaxesarenotsignificant
• Thereisasmalljumpin1990fromtheevolutionofpropertytaxesexplainedabove.However,we areconfidentthattherestoftheevolutionisgenuine,astherestoftaxcategoriesmatchperfectly betweenhistoricalarchivedataandOECDdatafortheoverlappingperiod(1990-1994)
46Peru
50
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation ICTD 1994 2020 2006-2008
Timeseries WestartthedataseriesforSaudiArabiain1994.WerefertoICTDforthewholeperiod. Weinterpolatefromyear2006to2008.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforSaudiArabiaaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• AssumeequalsplitforunallocatedincometaxrevenuesbetweenPIT andCIT,hardtocorroborateduetolimitedhistoricalsources,butnote thatsmallinmagnitude
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=15%;constant
Minusculebutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod.Werelyonexternaldata (RPC data).Extrapolationafter2014
Notincludedduringthewholeperiod
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
• Directnon-oiltaxrevenueisalmostinexistent.However,wehighlightthatnon-taxrevenueis alwaysmorethan25%andsometimesasmuchas50%ofGDP.
47SaudiArabia
Sources
51
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
ICTD 1994 2020
Timeseries Inkeepingwithourruletonotincludecommunistcountriespriortotheirtransition,we donotincludeUkraineinourcalculationspriorto1994.WerefertoICTDfortheperiodsincethen.
Harmonization Datapost-1994fromICTDonUkrainepresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshown below.Therearenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1994
IncomeTaxation
• Verysmallunallocableincometaxinthe2000s
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=25%; ↑ trendpre-2000(25%to29%)and ↓ trendpost-2000(29%to23%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Verysmallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
48Ukraine Sources
52
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation ICTD 1994 2020 2013-2014
Timeseries Inkeepingwithourruletonotincludecommunistcountriespriortotheirtransition,the dataseriesforUzbekistanstarts1994.WerefertoICTDforthewholeperiod.Years2013and2014are interpolated
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforUzbekistanareonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablesince2003.Extrapolationofproportional ratiosusing2002asreference,andcorroboratedwithrecentpolicydocuments
• Unallocableincometaxrevenue(especiallyrelevantsince2003),allallocatedtoPITtobasedonpolicydocuments
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=27%; ↓ trend(30%-22%)
SmallvaluesfromICTDintheearly1990s.Notavailablefrom1995-1998: interpolationusing1994and1999asreference.Othersources(IMF,WB) excludeitfromthedefinitionoftaxrevenueforUzbekistan
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
• OurestimationgivesveryclosevaluestopriorliteratureonUzbekistan.Thisisthecaseforthe wholeperiodanalysed:fortheendofthe1990s(slightlybelow DavoodiandGrigorian (2007)and derHoek (2008)),formid2010s(Mokhtari&Ashtari, 2012)andforrecentyears(check World Bank(2020) or IMF(2019)).
49Uzbekistan
53
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1979 1976-1978
ICTD 1980 1989
OECD 1990 2017
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivefrom1965to1979.WerelyonICTDfromthesubsequent decade(1980-1989)anduseOECDfortheperiodsince1990.Weinterpolateyears1976,1977and1978 (wehaveoveralltaxrevenuefortheseyears).Dataongovernmentrevenueisnotavailablebeyond2017.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforVenezuelaaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablepriorto1971,extrapolatetheshareofCIT oftotalincometaxrevenuebackfrom1971to1965andverifyusing historicalsources
• Unallocableincometaxrevenuecategory,useinformationfrom(Barreix, Ben´ıtez,&Pecho, 2017; McLureJr, 1992; Zolt&Bird, 2005),toassign allofittoPIT
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=23%;nocleartrend(fluctuatingbetween 22%and26%)
RelyonexternaldatapriortoOECDfirstyearofobservation( RPC database). Novaluespost-2012:assumed2013-2017valuesequaltothelevelofsocial contributionsin2012
WedonotcollectanywealthorpropertytaxpriortoOECDdata
TheOECD,doesincludeanylocaltaxes
• Thereisajumpinstitchingyear1980(historicalarchivetoICTD).Thisgapiswithinthenormal rangeofVenezuelayear-to-yearpatterns,andconsistentwiththepatternfrom1980-81.
• Intheearlyperiod,pre-1970,asignificantproportionofrevenuewascomingfromnon-taxsources, nationalizedminingandextractiveindustry.Whilesomerevenuefromextractiveindustryremainedpublicandnon-taxinthelatereras,perhapsthestrictly tax studyinVenezuelaisnot anentirelyrevealingpictureoftheirpublicfinances.Thismaybethecaseinmanypetroleumexportingstates.
50Venezuela
54
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1990 1997
OECD 1998 2012
Timeseries
Ourfirstyearobservationis1990(yearofunificationandcreationofthemodernRepublic ofYemen),andstopsin2012(sincetheYemeniCrisisbegan).Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafor theperiod1990-1997andweuseICTDdatafortheperiod1998-2012.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforYemenaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotreliablebefore1998andnotavailableafter2003(and inyear2001).Pre-1998:extrapolationbackwardofproportionalratios using1998asreference,confirmedwithhistoricalsource.Post-2003: extrapolationforwardofproportionalratiosusing2002asreference,and corroboratedwithrecentpolicydocuments
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%;constant
Relyonexternalsources(RPC database).Itisconstantataverysmall magnitude(0.1%ofGDP)
ICTDincludesaextremelysmallamountofpropertytaxduringtheyearsof itshighestprecision(1998-2002),butwehavethiscategorymissingbeforeand after DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
• Itisworthkeepinginmindthatnon-taxrevenue(presumablyalwaysoil/resourcerevenues)is alwaysimportantinYemen—from8%ofGDPin1990(historicalarchive)toahighof30%(ICTD) by2008.
51Yemen Sources
55
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 2020
Timeseries WerefertohistoricalarchivebasedonthereportsbytheMinistryofFinanceforthe wholeperiodfrom1965to2020.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere
Harmonization
HistoricalarchivedataonTaiwanpresentsdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow. Therearenomajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=16%; ↓ trendpre-1980(23to15%)and constantpost-1980(15%)
SocialContributions Notincluded
• The MinistryofFinance websitelistsitstaxcollectionsbyOECDclassification,andleavessocialcontributionseriesblank.However, thispolicy source includessocialcontributionrevenuefrom2002(andwecouldcalculateituntil2000)
• Per 2004StatisticalDataYearbook [seechapter16]itwouldseemthat thereareseveraldecentralizedsocialinsurancemechanisms,perhapsenforcedandcatalogedifnotcollectedatanationallevel.Unfortunately, thereseemstobenocentralizedcatalogofhistoricalstatisticsonthe sizeofthesecontributions,noracleardemarcationbetweenthepublic andprivatepartsofthesecontributions.
• Ifthesocialsecuritysystemisorganizedprivatelyinbothcontributions andexpenditures,thenitcouldberightlyexcludedfromrevenues.However,thiswouldblurthelinebetweenwhatisataxandwhatisarequired (private)expenditure
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Determined
Notes
52Taiwan
Sources
56
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1979
ICTD 1980 1999 OECD 2000 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivefrom1965until1979,weuseICTDforthetwosubsequent decades(1980-1999)andrelyonOECDfortheperiodsince2000.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforMaliaremadeonincometaxation,socialcontributionsandpropertytaxes.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotreliablebefore1980.Extrapolationbackofproportionalratiosfrom1980to1965,verifiedusingadditionalhistorical sources
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailableinyears1982-1983and2000-2001.Interpolationofproportionalratiosusingyearsforwhichwehavedata(before andaftermissingobservations)
• Smallbutnon-zerounallocableincometaxrevenueduringthewhole period
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%;constant
SocialContributions Relyonexternalsources(RPC database)before2000(firstyearofOECD)
PropertyTaxation Smallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod.Interpolationofyears1975-1983 DecentralizedRevenues Notdeterminedbefore1999,notincludedforOECDdata
Notes
• TherearelimitedhistoricaldocumentsonMali’shistoricalpublicfinance. Founou-Tchuigoua (1989)whodiscussedapurportedlong-runpublicfinancecrisis,didnotattempttomeasure tax/GDP.However,thedisaggregatedpresentationofindirecttaxrevenueasmorethantwice theamountofdirecttaxrevenuematcheswellourownfindings.
53Mali
Sources
57
54BurkinaFaso
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1999 1974,1980-1983,1987
OECD 2000 2020
TimeSeries
Werefertohistoricalarchivefrom1965to1999andweuseOECDfortheperiodsince then.Severalyearsinterpolated,coincidewithperiodsofpoliticalunrestandviolence.Fortheperiod 1993-99,weuse ICTD foroveralltax/GDPlevel5 andinterpolatecompositional‘within-tax’ratiosfrom 1992(historicalarchive)to2000(OECD).
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforBurkinaFasoaremadeonsocialcontributionsandpropertytaxes.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITavailableforthenon-interpolatedyears
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• Smallbutnon-zerounallocableincometaxduringtheOECDperiod (post-2000)
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%;constant
Relyonexternalsource(RPC database)fortheperiodpre-OECD(priorto 2000)
Smallbutnon-zeropropertytaxesduringthewholeperiod.Period1982-1999 isfullyinterpolated
Notdeterminedforhistoricalarchiveperiod,anddoesnotincludetaxrevenuescollectedbylocalauthoritiesbutincludesrevenuescollectedbycentral governmentonbehalfoflocalauthorities(inallperiods)
5 WealsointerpolateforwardthecomparisonratioofhistoricalarchivetaxleveltoICTDtaxlevelin1992.
58
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 2015 1998-1999
ICTD 2016 2020
Timeseries
Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafrom1965to2015,andweuseICTDfortheperiod sincethen.WescalethehistoricalarchivedatabyICTDfor2015-2020usingthe2014ratiosbetween thetwosourcesasreference.Years1998-1999areinterpolated.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforSriLankaaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITmissingornotreliablepriorto2001forhistoricalarchive data.WerelyonsplitCIT/PITaccordingto ICTD availablefrom1980, andextrapolatebackto1965corroboratedwithhistoricalsources
• Smallunallocableincometaxafter2002
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=25.5%; ↓ trend(30to16%)
Relyonexternalsource(RPC database)forthewholeperiod.Extrapolation forwardto2020usingtheratioRPCtoICTDfrom2013(lastyearavailable forRPC)
Verysmallbutnon-zerovaluesavailablefrom1982to1997.Notavailablefor therestoftheperiod
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
• Ravinthirakumaran (2011)corroboratesourarchivallong-runpublicfinanceseriesfortheyears 1977-2009,whichalsohelpsustrustthecontinuoustimeseriesfromtheearlierera.
55SriLanka
59
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 2004
OECD 2005 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafrom1965to2004,andweuseOECDfortheperiod sincethen.Wescalethehistoricalarchivedataby ICTD for1990-1993usingthe1989and1994ratios betweenthetwosourcesasreference.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforMalawiaremadeonsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%,constant
Relyonexternalsource(RPC database). SSA(2019) lists2011asthefirst yearforthepensionpolicy.
Notincluded,neitherinarchivaldatanorinOECD
Notdeterminedinhistoricalarchiveperiod,notavailableinOECDperiod
• Ourestimateinthehistoricalperiodisslightlylowerthanthatof,e.g., ShaliziandThirsk (1990) and Chipeta (1998),bothsourcedfromMalawigovernmentreports,butwematchthisseries ontrends.ItispossiblethattheGDPdenominatorfromMalawi’sgovernmentatthattimeis overestimated,vis-a-vistheWIDfigureweuse.Ourhistoricalarchivelevelsdomatchthoseofthe ICTDinthe1980s,aswell.
• Thespikeinpersonalincometaxrevenuein2000-01isgenuine,perrawdata,andrepresenteda sharpupturninthe‘actual’vs.budgeted(previouslypredicted)revenuesforthatyear.
56Malawi
60
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1965 1979 1978,1979
ICTD 1980 1989
IDB-CIAT 1990 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafrom1965to1979,thenuseICTDforthe1980sand finallyrelyonIDB-CIATfortheperiodsince1990.Years1978and1979areinterpolated.Werefine thehistoricalarchiveusing WorldBank(1980) forcentralgovernmentrevenuesfor1960-77.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforChilearemadeonincometaxation,socialcontributionsandpropertytaxes.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailableforyears1987-1989,interpolateusingendpointsasreferencesanddrawonadditionalhistoricalsources
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=21.6%, ↓ trend(26to14%)
RelyonexternalsourcesforperiodpriortoIDB-CIATdata(1990).For197085weuse Corbo (1989)andfor1965-1975wecomplementitwithofficial governmentpublications(consistentwithevidencefrom Cerda (2005))
Relyonexternalsourcesfortheperiodafter1990(UNdata).Interpolationof theperiod1980-1989using1979and1990asreference
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
57Chile Sources
61
58Kazakhstan
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
ICTD 1994 1998
OECD 1999 2020
Timeseries Inkeepingwithourruletonotincludecommunistcountriespriortotheirtransition,we donotincludeKazakhstanbefore1994.WerefertoICTDdatafrom1994to1998anduseOECDfor theperiodsincethen.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforKazakhstanaremadeonincometaxation,socialcontributionsandproperty taxes.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefrom1994to1998.Extrapolationofproportionalratiosbackusing1999asreference
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=16.9%, ↓ trend(22to15%)
Availablefrom1995.Extrapolationbackfor1994(consistentwith SSA(2019))
RelyonhistoricalarchivefortheperiodpriortoOECD(pre-1999) DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
• OilrevenueisenormouslyimportantforKazakhstan,butmuchofitisnon-taxrevenue
62
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
HistoricalArchive 1986,1990-1991
ICTD 2010 2020
Timeseries
Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafrom1965to2009.WeusetheevolvingratioofhistoricalarchivetoICTDtotaltaxtake(level)tointerpolatetheoverallleveloftax/GDPinmissingyears, andthenweinterpolatethevaluesof‘within’ratiosforthecomponenttaxes.Werelyonthetotaltax revenuefromICTDfortheperiodsince2010.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforZambiaaremadeonincometaxation,socialcontributionsandpropertytaxes.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITavailableforallthenon-interpolatedyears
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• Verysmallbutnon-zerounallocableincometaxrevenuesince1972
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=16.9%, ↓ trend(22to15%)
Relyonexternalsource(RPC database).Extrapolationofconstantvaluefrom 2014to2020
Verysmallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod
Notdetermined
• DiJohn (2010),citing WeeksandMcKinley (2009),corroboratethegeneraltrendsandlevelsof ourdatain1990-2004,althoughwehavetointerpolatebecausewearemissingmanyyears.
• Colclough (1988)hasahigherestimatethandoourHAdatafortheperiod1975-85,andmatches theICTDdatafromthe1980onward.However,examinationofourrawdatashowsthatwehave ‘miscellaneouscapitalreceipts’intherawdata,andthesearenotonlyhighlyvariantfromyear toyearinourdata,butwealsodonotwanttoclassifythemastaxrevenues.Itseemslikelythat thegapbetweenhistoricalarchiveandICTD-IMFin1975couldalsobewhatisdrivingthegap betweenhistoricalarchiveandRPCtotaltaxtakes.
59Zambia
63
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation ICTD 1994 2020
Timeseries Inkeepingwithourruletonotincludecommunistcountriespriortotheirtransition,we donotincludeRomaniabefore1994.WerefertoICTDdataforthewholeperiodsincethen.
Harmonization
DatafromICTDonRomaniapresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow.There arenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITavailableforallperiodssince1994
IncomeTaxation
• Verysmallbutnon-zerounallocableincometaxrevenue
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=21.2%, ↓ trend(25to17%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
60Romania Sources
64
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
HistoricalArchive 1965 1984
ICTD 1985 1998 OECD 1999 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafrom1965to1984.WeuseICTDfrom1985to1998, interpolatingtherelativeshareoftaxesuntil1990using1984and1991asreference.WerelyonOECD fortheperiodsince1999.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforSenegalaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITextrapolatedbackfrom1972to1965andinterpolatedfor 1991-1992,corroborateusinghistoricalsources
• Smallbutnon-zerounallocableincometaxrevenueinmultipleyears
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=29.5%,fluctuation(29-30%)
Relyonexternalsource(RPC database)fortheperiodpre-OECD(pre-1998)
Smallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod
NotdeterminedbeforeOECD,notincludedforOECDperiod
• Ourestimationforthehistoricalarchiveperiodmatches(withslightdifferences)previousliterature (Boye, 1990; Chelliah, 1971)
61Senegal Sources
65
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation OECD 1965 2020
Timeseries WerefertoOECDallthewaybackto1965.
Harmonization
DatafromOECDonNetherlandspresentdetailedinformationonallthetaxcategoriesshownbelow. Therearenotmajoradjustmentsmade.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITavailableforallperiods
IncomeTaxation
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=13.6%, ↓ trend(15to11%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation Included
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
62Netherlands
66
63Guatemala
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
HA 1965 1989 1984-1989*
OECD 1990 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafrom1965to1989andweuseOECDfortheperiod sincethen.Weinterpolatetheyears1986-1989using ICTD’soveralllevelsbutrelyingontheshareof eachtaxcategoriesusing1983and1990asreference.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforGuatemalaaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1965
IncomeTaxation
• TheunallocableincometaxrevenueinOECDsince1995isalwaysa ‘solidaritytax’,whichisapparentlyassessedoncorporations(per PwC 2020),sowere-assignitasaCIT
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=27.8%,fluctuation(30-25%)
SocialContributions Lackofdatafortheperiodpre-1990(andprobablystartsin1969or1977, per SSA2017).WeuseOECD’slevelfrom1990extrapolatedbackto1978 withoutre-scaletomatchthe RPC number,asitdoesnotappearthatthere isafixedproportionalgapbetweenthetwo
PropertyTaxation Reallysmallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod DecentralizedRevenues NotdeterminedbeforeOECD,includedforOECDperiod
Notes
• Ourestimationmatchespreviousliteraturefortheearlyhistoricalarchiveperiod(Newlyn, 1985).
67
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
HA 1965 1982
ICTD 1983 2009
OECD 2010 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivedatafrom1965to1982,weuseICTDfortheperiod19832009andrelyonOECDfortheperiodsincethen.Weinterpolatetheshareofeachtaxcategoryfor periods1978-1980and2006-2009.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforChadaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
DecentralizedRevenues
Notes
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefor1978-1993.Interpolationofproportional ratiosusing1977and1994,andcorroboratewithhistoricalsources
• Verysmallbutnon-zerounallocableincometaxrevenueduringthewhole period
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=30%,constant
Relyonexternalsource(RPC database)fortheperiod1976to2010
Verysmallbutnon-zeroafter1994
NotdeterminedbeforeOECD,notincludedforOECDperiod
• Thevolatilityinrecentyearsisnotablebutalsogenuine(corroboratedbothinourrawdataand inICTD).
64Chad Sources
68
Sources
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation ICTD 1994 2009
Timeseries Inkeepingwithourruletonotincludecommunistcountriespriortotheirtransition,we donotincludeCambodiabefore1994.WerefertoICTDforthewholeperiodsince1994.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforCambodiaaremadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
SocialContributions
PropertyTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefortheyears1994,2004-05,and2015.Interpolationofproportionalratiosusingyearsbeforeandafter
• Verysmallbutnon-zerounallocableincometaxrevenue
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=29%, ↓ trend(30to26%)
Relyonexternalsource(RPC database).Per SSA(2018),thefirstsocial securityprogrambeganin1997(ourdatastartsin1998)
Verysmallandinmostperiodszero
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
• The WorldBank(2020) doesshowasimilarpatterntotheoneweobserve,atleastinthemodern period(theirdatabeginsin2002).
65Cambodia
69
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
Historicalarchive 1973 1989
OECD 1990 1992
IDB-CIAT 1993 2020
Timeseries Werefertohistoricalarchivefrom1973(firstyearofobservation)until1989.Weuse OECDdatafortheperiod1990-1992,andweuseIDB-CIATdatafortheperiodsince1993.
Linktohistoricalarchivedata: clickhere.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforEcuadoraremadeonincometaxation.
Category Adjustment
IncomeTaxation
• SplitCIT/PITnotavailablefor1990-1992.Interpolationofproportional ratiosusing1989and1993asreferences
• UnallocableincometaxduringIDB-CIATperiod.Useadditionalinformationfrom SRI(2020),Ecuador’staxcollectionauthority,toassign portiontoPIT.
• Unallocableincometaxin2019-2020allocatedproportionallybasedon theobservedsplitCIT/PITin2018
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=28%, ↓ trend(30to27%)
SocialContributions Included
PropertyTaxation
Smallbutnon-zeroduringthewholeperiod
DecentralizedRevenues Included
Notes
• OilrevenueisthebiggeststoryinEcuador.Itrosefromzeroto20%ofpublicsectorrevenuefrom 1970-74,andto48%by1982,accordingto Bocco (2016).Meanwhilenon-oiltaxrevenuedecreased from10.1%ofGDPin1972to5.4%in1983(ibid.).However,differentdatasourcescategorized thisprominentsourceofrevenueaccordingtovaryingguidelinesaswellastheshareofpublic revenuetoggledbetweennon-taxexpropriatedandprivatizedCITrevenue.
66Ecuador
Sources
70
• Priorto1996,itisnotclearwhatpartofpublicrevenueisfromoilandwhatisnot.Wetherefore useIMFhistoricaldataandarriveataseriesfrom1973-89thatnearlyagreeswiththeOECD by1990(whenOECDbegins).However,thehistoricalarchivemayhaveerroneouslyclassifiedoil revenueasindirecttaxationinsteadofCIT.Ontheotherhand,wecorroborateOECDandoilvs. non-oilstatisticsbyreferencetotheMinistryofFinance(MFE).
• Eventhoughoilrevenuemakesthecomparisonhard,ourestimationsmatchesconsiderablywell withpreviousliterature.First, CEPAL(1991) corroboratesourlevelsforpre-OECDperiod(includingthe1985spike).Second,fortheperiod1989-1992, Garc´ıaandUquillas (1992)agreewith thevaluesfromOECD.Formorerecentdecades,differentsources(Bucheli(2014), Fretes-Cibils, Shankar,andCurrie (2008), MinisteriodeEconomiayFinanzas(2016))matchourestimation.
71
Source Firstyear Lastyear Interpolation
ICTD 1980 2020 1998
Timeseries WerefertoICTDforthewholeperiodsince1980(yearofindependence).Year1998is interpolated.
Harmonization
ThemainadjustmentsforZimbabwearemadeonincometaxationandsocialcontributions.
Category Adjustment
• SplitCIT/PITallthewaybackto1980
IncomeTaxation
• Unallocableincometaxcategoryduringthewholeperiod,mostrelevantbetween2010-2015(around1%ofGDP),useadditionalsourcesto allocatetofirmsversusworkers
• CapitalshareofPIT:mean=29.8%,smallfluctuations(30to29%)
SocialContributions Relyonexternalsource(RPC database)onlysince1989,following SSA(2017)
PropertyTaxation Verysmallduringthewholeperiod,andzeroafter1998
DecentralizedRevenues Notdetermined
Notes
• Thedropinrevenuesduringtheperiod2005-2009correspondswiththepeakofthehyperinflation crisisinthecountry.
67Zimbabwe Sources
72
References
Afonso,J.R.,Araujo,E.A.,&Vianna,S.T.W.(2004).Cargatribut´ariaindiretanobrasil:an´aliseda incidˆenciaefetivasobreasfam´ılias. Inter-AmericanDevelopmentBank
Alvaredo,F.(2010).Therichinargentinaoverthetwentiethcentury,1932–2004. Topincomes:Aglobal perspective, 2 .
Amin,A.A.(1998).Cameroon’sfiscalpolicyandeconomicgrowth. TheAfricanEconomicResearchConsortium
Amir,H.,Asafu-Adjaye,J.,&Ducpham,T.(2013).Theimpactoftheindonesianincometaxreform:Acge analysis. EconomicModelling, 31 ,492–501.
Bachas,P.,Fisher-Post,M.H.,Jensen,A.,&Zucman,G.(2022).Globalizationandfactorincometaxation. NationalBureauofEconomicResearch.(No.w29819)
Bank,S.A.R.(2016). Taxchronologyofsouthafrica:1979-2015. SupplementtotheSouthAfricanReserve BankQuarterlyBulletin.
Bank,W.(2014). Colombia’s2012taxreform:Povertyandsocialimpactanalysis.Author. Barreix,A.,Ben´ıtez,J.C.,&Pecho,M.(2017).Revisitingpersonalincometaxinlatinamerica:Evolution andimpact.
Bernardi,L.,Fumagalli,L.,&Gandullia,L.(2005).Taxsystemsandtaxreformsinsouthandeastasia: Overviewofthetaxsystemsandmainpolicytaxissues. MPRAPaperNo.18214 . Blanchet,T.,Chancel,L.,Flores,I.,&Morgan,M.(2021). Distributionalnationalaccountsguidelines:Methods andconceptsusedintheWorldInequalityDatabase.
Bocco,A.M.(2016).Ecuador:Thestate,publicpolicyandcapitalaccumulation,1970–83.In Thestateand capitalaccumulationinlatinamerica:Argentina,bolivia,colombia,ecuador,peru,uruguay,venezuela (pp.88–105).Springer.
Bouin,O.,Coricelli,F.,&Lemoine,F.(1998). Differentpathstoamarketeconomy.OrganizationforEconomic Co-OperationandDevelopment(OECD).
Boye,F.(1990). Aretrospectiveanalysisofthesenegaleseeconomy.CenterforEconomicResearchonAfrica, DepartmentofEconomics,Schoolof.... Burgess,R.,&Stern,N.(1993).Taxationanddevelopment. Journalofeconomicliterature, 31 (2),762–830. Castro,P.,Junquera-Varela,R.,Schenone,O.,&Teixeira,A.(2009).Evaluationofreformsintaxpolicyand administrationinmozambiqueandrelatedta–1994-2007. IMF/IFAD.September
Cerda,R.A.(2005).Doessocialsecurityaffectretirementandlaborsupply?evidencefromchile. The DevelopingEconomies, 43 (2),235–264.
Chelliah,R.J.(1971).Trendsintaxationindevelopingcountries. IMFStaffPapers, 1971 (002),A002.Retrieved from https://www.elibrary.imf.org/view/journals/024/1971/002/article-A002-en.xml doi:10 .5089/9781451947335.024.A002
Chipeta,C.(1998).Taxreformandtaxyieldinmalawi.
Colclough,C.(1988).Zambianadjustmentstrategy—withandwithouttheimf. Corbo,V.(1989). Publicfinance,trade,anddevelopment:thechileanexperience (Vol.218).WorldBank Publications.
Davoodi,H.R.,&Grigorian,D.(2007).Taxpotentialvs.taxeffort:across-countryanalysisofarmenia’s stubbornlylowtaxcollection.
DeHerdt,T.(2002).Democracy&themoneymachineinzaire. ReviewofAfricanPoliticalEconomy, 29 (93-94),445–462.
derHoek,M.P.v.(2008).Enlargingtheeuropeanunion:Taxationandcorruptioninthenewmemberstates. In Taxationandpublicfinanceintransitionanddevelopingeconomies (pp.11–23).Springer.
Dethier,J.-J.(2000). Governance,decentralizationandreforminchina,indiaandrussia.SpringerScience& BusinessMedia.
DiJohn,J.(2010).Stateresilienceagainsttheodds:ananalyticalnarrativeontheconstructionandmaintenance ofpoliticalorderinzambiasince1960.
73
Ekpo,A.H.,&Ndebbio,J.E.(1996).Fiscaloperationsinadepressedeconomy:Nigeria,1960-90. African EconomicResearchConsortium
Fisunoglu,A.,Kang,K.,Arbetman-Rabinowitz,M.,&Kugler,J.(2011). RelativePoliticalCapacityDataset (Version2.4). HarvardDataverse.Retrievedfrom https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/NRR7MB (Lastaccess: September2023)doi:10.7910/DVN/NRR7MB
Fjeldstad,O.-H.(1995).Taxationandtaxreformsintanzania:Asurvey. Chr.MichelsenInstitute
Founou-Tchuigoua,B.(1989).Lacrisedesfinancespubliquesetlad´enationalisationdel’etat:lecasdumali. AfricaDevelopment/AfriqueetD´eveloppement ,19–41.
Fretes-Cibils,V.,Shankar,R.,&Currie,E.(2008).Fiscalsustainabilityanddebtmanagementinecuador. Ecuador’s,43.
Garc´ıa,R.,&Uquillas,E.(1992).Evoluci´onyperspectivasdelaeconom´ıaecuatorianaen1992.
Garc´ıa-Garc´ıa,J.,&Guterman-Bromberg,L.(1988).Medici´ondeld´eficitdelsectorp´ublicocolombianoysu financiaci´on:1950-1986. RevistaEnsayosSobrePol´ıticaEcon´omica;Vol.7.No.14.Diciembre,1988. P´ag.:115-133..
Gauthier,B.,&Gersovitz,M.(1997).Revenueerosionthroughexemptionandevasionincameroon,1993. JournalofPubliceconomics, 64 (3),407–424.
Gauthier,B.,Soloaga,I.,&Tybout,J.(2002).Afirm’s-eyeviewofcommercialpolicyandfiscalreformsin cameroon. TheWorldBankEconomicReview , 16 (3),449–472.
Ghafur,A.,&Chowdhury,O.H.(1988). Bangladesh.EconomicsOffice,AsianDevelopmentBank. Gillis,M.(1985).Microandmacroeconomicsoftaxreform:Indonesia. JournalofDevelopmentEconomics, 19 (3),221–254.
Hasan,P.,Kemal,A.,&Naseem,S.(1997).Learningfromthepast:Afifty-yearperspectiveonpakistan’s development[withcomments]. ThePakistanDevelopmentReview , 36 (4),355–402. InteramericanDevelopmentBank(IDB)&Inter-AmericanCenterofTaxAdministration(CIAT).(2018). RevenueCollectiondatabase. Dataretrievedfrom https://www.ciat.org/idb-ciat-revenue-collection -database/?lang=en.(Lastaccess:September2023)
InternationalCentreforTaxandDevelopment.(2020). UNU-WIDERGovernmentRevenueDataset.Version 2023. Dataretrievedfrom https://doi.org/10.35188/UNU-WIDER/GRD-2023.(Lastaccess:September 2023)
Ivanova,A.,Keen,M.,&Klemm,A.(2005).Therussian‘flattax’reform. Economicpolicy, 20 (43),398–444. Jansen,K.,&Khannabha,C.(2012).Thefiscalspaceofthailand:Anhistoricalanalysis.In Fiscalspace (pp. 347–420).Routledge.
Junguito,R.,Rinc´on,H.,etal.(2004).Lapol´ıticafiscalenelsigloxxencolombia. Borradoresdeeconom´ıa, 318 . Karingi,S.N.,&Wanjala,B.(2005). Thetaxreformexperienceofkenya (No.2005/67).WIDERResearch Paper.
Kwack,T.,&Lee,K.-S.(1992).Taxreforminkorea.In Thepoliticaleconomyoftaxreform (pp.117–136). UniversityofChicagoPress. Lou,J.,&Wang,S.(2008). Publicfinanceinchina:reformandgrowthforaharmonioussociety.WorldBank Publications.
Macha,R.R.,Lado,E.P.Z.,&Nyansera,O.C.(2018).Anempiricalanalysisoftaxratiosandtaxeffortsfor kenyaandmalawi. AfricanJournalofEconomicReview , 6 (2),152–171.
Madrigal-Delgado,G.d.J.(2021).Recaudaci´ondelimpuestopredialenm´exico:desaf´ıodelfederalismofiscal. Investigaci´onadministrativa, 50 (127). Maina,A.W.(2014). Incometaxesandeconomicperformanceinkenya (Unpublisheddoctoraldissertation). Mascagni,G.(2016).Afiscalhistoryofethiopia:Taxationandaiddependence1960-2010. ICTDWorking Paper49 . McLureJr,C.E.(1992).Incometaxreformincolombiaandvenezuela:Acomparativehistory. World Development, 20 (3),351–367.
Mokhtari,M.,&Ashtari,M.(2012).Understandingtaxreforminthecentralasianrepublics. JournalofAsian Economics, 23 (2),168–178.
74
Nachega,J.-C.(2005).Fiscaldominanceandinflationinthedemocraticrepublicofthecongo. IMFworking paper Naughton,B.(2007). Thechineseeconomy.MITpressCambridge,MA. Newlyn,W.T.(1985).Measuringtaxeffortindevelopingcountries. TheJournalofDevelopmentStudies, 21 (3),390–405.
Nord,R.,Sobolev,Y.,Dunn,D.G.,Hajdenberg,A.,Hobdari,N.,Maziad,S.,&Roudet,S.(2009).Tanzania: thestoryofanafricantransition. InternationalMonetaryFund(IMF). Nyrop,R.F.(1976). Areahandbookforegypt.USDepartmentofDefense,DepartmentoftheArmy. OrganizationforEconomicCo-OperationandDevelopment.(2020). RevenueStatistics. Dataretrievedfrom OECD.stats, https://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?DataSetCode=REV.(Lastaccess:September2023) Osei,R.D.,&Telli,H.(2017).Sixtyyearsoffiscalpolicyinghana. TheEconomyofGhanaSixtyYearsafter Independence, 66 Osoro,N.E.(1993). Revenueproductivityimplicationsoftaxreformintanzania.CentrefortheStudyof AfricanEconomies,UniversityofOxford,Oxford,GB.
Owen,M.D.E.W.,&Robinson,M.D.O.(2003). Russiarebounds.InternationalMonetaryFund. Pinto,B.(1987).Nigeriaduringandaftertheoilboom:Apolicycomparisonwithindonesia. TheWorldBank EconomicReview , 1 (3),419–445. Prasetyo,K.A.(2018).Taxadministrationreformandthesocietyinindonesia:Somelessonlearnt. Working Paper .
Preobragenskaya,G.,&McGee,R.W.(2003).Taxationandpublicfinanceinatransitioneconomy:acase studyofrussia. AvailableatSSRN480862
Ravinthirakumaran,K.(2011).Therelationshipbetweengovernmentrevenueandexpenditureinsrilanka.In Internationalconferenceonbusinessandinformation.
Ribeiro,M.P.,Villafuerte,M.,Baunsgaard,T.,&Richmond,C.J.(2012).Fiscalframeworksforresourcerich developingcountries. StaffDiscussionNotes, 2012 (004).
Shalizi,Z.,&Thirsk,W.R.(1990). Taxreforminmalawi (Vol.493).WorldBankPublications. Smith,H.H.(1970). Areahandbookfortheunitedarabrepublic(egypt) (Vol.43).USGovernmentPrinting Office.
Syeda,M.H.(2015).Makinganimpactanalysisofsocialprotectionprogramsinpakistan. Journalofthe ResearchSocietyofPakistan, 52 (1). Wawire,N.H.(1991). Anempiricalassessmentoftaxperformanceinkenya:1958to1989 (Unpublished doctoraldissertation).KenyattaUniversity.
Weeks,J.,&McKinley,T.(2009).Doesdebtreliefincreasefiscalspaceinzambia?themdgimplications.In Economicalternativesforgrowth,employmentandpovertyreduction:Progressivepolicyrecommendations fordevelopingcountries (pp.180–208).Springer. Yoo,I.(2000).Experiencewithtaxreformintherepublicofkorea. AsiaPacificDevelopmentJournal , 7 (2), 75–104.
Zolt,E.M.,&Bird,R.M.(2005).Redistributionviataxation:Thelimitedroleofthepersonalincometaxin developingcountries. UCLALawReview , 52 ,05–22.
75