WBGU Flagship Report: World in Transition – A Social Contract for Sustainability

Page 216

Transformation Impediments and Barriers: It’s Politics, Stupid!  5.3

ernance and life-worlds: democracy’s core element is the congruence between rulers and ruled – or, as Abra­ ham Lincoln so famously said, democracy is ‘govern­ ment of the people, by the people, for the people’. Its most important achievement is therefore the legiti­ mation requirement for all acts of governance, which in democratic systems is guaranteed by the political equality of all (inclusion). For 2500 years, democra­ cies have put their trust in the (political) ‘wisdom of crowds’. That is why they function according to differ­ ent variants of the majority rule, which must, however, not be construed as a ‘tyranny of the majority’, but must rather effectively and fairly allow minorities to have a say, to be involved, and to be protected. Moreo­ ver, democratic political systems are embedded in legal orders and the rule of law; fundamental constitutional standards are explicitly eliminated from revision by majority decision. Effective decision-making advantages such as the reversibility of decisions and effective stakeholder par­ ticipation on the part of the citizens, instigated through direct and indirect involvement in the decision-mak­ ing process and public multi-level communication, go hand in hand with these principles. Improved consoli­ dation of preferences and interests, best-possible use of widespread knowledge, and the highest level of ‘input legitimation’ of any political system therefore reflect the rationality and comparative advantage of democ­ racies. What this effectively means is that citizens do not merely receive services from an authoritarian state, but make a sovereign contribution to their composi­ tion and direction. In this respect, modern democracies respond to the general decoupling of modern societies from hierarchies and the proven ethical impact of pub­ lic discussion and deliberation; both ensure that each individual develops a relatively strong awareness for the (notional) common good whilst also enjoying the chance to pursue and assert their own individual inter­ ests. It is obvious that no democratic system has ever achieved this ideal, and the theory of a ‘post-demo­ cratic’ development of liberal systems with a long dem­ ocratic tradition is widely discussed in socio-scientific literature (Crouch, 2004; Jörke, 2010). Essentially, there are three problematic factors: (1) the growing social inequality in many developed societies, impact­ ing negatively on participation opportunities and will­ ingness; (2) the discouragement of civic activity caused by global economic imperatives undermining the civil culture of cooperation, responsibility and solidarity by providing incentives for individual competition; and (3) the empirical linking of welfare state systems with the paradigm of an economic growth that erodes the natu­ ral foundations of democratic societies through dispro­

portionate consumption of resources (Section 2.3; Box 5.2-1). Despite such by all means serious crises ten­ dencies, the general democratisation trend outlined in Section 1.2.2 continues worldwide beyond the western core countries. Democracy could, then, be considered as a system model for political order which has become globally established; it would therefore have to prove its effectiveness with a view to the forthcoming Great Transformation.

Democratic Performance At present, democracy has certainly not yet proven its future viability (Box 5.3-1). Time pressure and the complexity of the transformation inevitably lead to the question of the performance and suitability of dem­ ocratic systems. The quality and the performance of democracies are usually measured by their input, i.  e. by effective citizen participation and the willingness of policy-makers to respond to citizens’ interests and aspi­ rations, and by their output, i.  e. their political effec­ tiveness in the form of effective and efficient action by the executive powers (Brusis, 2008). The measures required by a transformative policy place the usual form of democratic governance under pressure, both in terms of time and space. Democratic processes gen­ erally need time, as they take many different inter­ ests into account. Moreover, they usually focus on the short-term achievement of political objectives, making the handling and resolution of long-term problems dif­ ficult (Section 5.3.1.1). Slowness is, however, not an inherent property of democratic systems and institu­ tions. As demonstrated by the handling of the finan­ cial and economic crisis in the autumn of 2008, democ­ racies are certainly able to react quickly to financial and economic crisis situations and to make far-reach­ ing reform decisions. Under the pressure of financial and economic crisis, multi-billion bank bailout and eco­ nomic stimulus packages were adopted within a very short time (Meyer-Ohlendorf et al., 2009). In summary proceedings, the passing of the German financial mar­ ket stabilisation act (FMStG) and the establishment of a € 480 billion fund were decided by the Bundestag and the Bundesrat, i.  e. the German parliament, and signed off by the German Federal President within a week (BMF, 2008). If the requisite legislative coalitions are in place, democratic systems also allow far-reach­ ing reform decisions to be made within a very short period of time. However, as far as a transformation policy is con­ cerned, there is no sign of any such blanket coalitions and rapid decision-making processes, despite aware­ ness of the grave consequences of global warming. This fuels the democracy scepticism mentioned earlier, and a belief in the allegedly greater efficiency of autocratic

193


Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.