Managing Openness: Trade and Outward-Oriented Growth after the Crisis

Page 41

Managing Openness: Lessons from the Crisis for Emerging Markets

19

Figure 2.6. Average Financial Credit Restrictions, 2005, versus Change in Growth, 2008–09, All Emerging/Developing Countries 5

CIV TGO YEM LBN PAK

ZMB KEN 0 UGA JAM EGY GTM MUS

change in growth (%)

MAR BGD CHN UZB IND TUN DOM SWZ TZA LKA PHL

IDN BFA KAZ BOL GHA

CRI NIC CHL BRA TUR –5 URY SLV KGZ GEO ECU HUN

SAU THA ZAF ARG MYS MEX

VEN PAN OMN PER –10 PRY

LVA ROM

RUS AGO MDA

–15

–20

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

average financial credit restrictions Source: World Economic Outlook (database), IMF, http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2010/01/weodata/index.aspx; Schindler 2009.

imports as well as U.S. goods, and unfairly so insofar as other countries did not respond with stimulus programs of their own. The evidence of protectionism in the past three years is broadly consistent with this pattern. To be sure, countries were much more successful now than 80 years ago in coordinating their policy responses to the crisis, which appears to be more evidence of their having learned from history. That increased coordination limited complaints about free riding and contained the protectionist impulse. Kee, Neagu, and Nicita (2010) conclude that only 2 percent of the decline in world trade in 2008 was attributable to increased protectionism. That number may be an underestimate, however; unlike other authors (Evenett 2010, for example) who consider trade restrictions broadly defined, Kee, Neagu, and Nicita (2010) look only at tariffs. A more encompassing measure would yield a somewhat higher number. Still, the conclusion that trade policy was not a major factor in the collapse of trade would probably still stand.

It is plausible that disruptions to the supply of trade finance might have been important in the collapse of trade. Trade, by virtue of its time-intensive nature, depends on finance, and this was, after all, a financial crisis. Iacovone and Zavacka (2009) show that the exports of firms more dependent on external finance fall by more in banking crises than those of firms that self-finance and that have more tangible assets and hence better collateral. On the other hand, Mora and Powers (2009) argue that this effect was quantitatively small because the disruption to flows of trade credit was limited in duration and extent. Although other credit markets froze up, trade finance declined to only a limited extent, a few exceptional cases notwithstanding. Because trade credit is collateralized, it was possible to keep credit flowing. Official export credit agencies, for their part, stepped in to help. Developing countries, then, need to put their central banks and national export credit agencies in a position where they can also help, rather than relying just on the multilaterals. To the extent that


Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.